8. Organization and Resistance 8.1. Mutualism

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

8. Organization and Resistance 8.1. Mutualism 8. Organization and Resistance Marcelvan der Linden 8.1. Mutualism “Mutualism” refers to all voluntary arrangements, in which people make contribu- tions to acollective fund, which is given, in whole or in part,toone or moreof the contributors accordingtospecific rules of allocation. The concept goes back to the nineteenth century and was probablycoined by the French social anarchist Pierre-Joseph Proudhon.The idea behind mutualism is simple: there are thingsinev- erydaylife people desire but cannot acquirefor themselvesasindividuals.Such thingscan consist of labour,ofgoods, or of money.There are two possiblereasons for the existence of such items.Onthe one hand, there are tasks that individuals can- not possiblyexecute on their own, within areasonable period of time. Forthese, they need other people to help them. Andonthe other hand,there are tasks which an individual could well execute him- or herself, but which would have significant neg- ative effects on the person involved, for example because workingtoobtain agood on one’sown is frighteningorstultifying. In both cases, individuals benefit by asking others for help. In compensation for this help, they can perform asimilar (reciprocal) task in return, or payfor it.Mutualist activities not onlyoccur among all kinds of workers,but also among other social classes. Mutualism is in this sense not class- specific, although it often is an important component of proletarian survival strat- egies. In agreat variety of circumstances workers have utilizedmutualist arrangements to make their livesmore liveable and less risky.Mutualism took agreat variety of forms in the past,and still does today. Yetpatterns and relations can be discerned. In general there are three kinds of mutualist arrangements, based on (i) scheduled demand and rotating allocation; (ii) scheduled demand and non-rotatingallocation; and (iii) contingent demand and non-rotatingallocation. Scheduled demand means that the people involved know in advancethatthey will have to perform acertain amount of labour,ortopay acertain sum of money or goods at some point in the future. There are two kinds of scheduled demand: one-off and recurring. Single expenses mayfor instance be refunded for ceremonies or parties, on the occasionofrites of passage, such as weddings or funerals. On such occasions,the individuals or households involved are in acute need of alarge amount of goods or money which they cannot supplybythemselvesinashortperiod of time. Among these single expenses, Iincludethe purchase of durables and invest- ments in capital goods. The second variety of scheduled demand is amatter of reg- ularly recurring expenses,such as the periodic strain on household resources at the end of the month. In these cases, mutualist associations can also provide asolution. DOI 10.1515/9783110424584-025 492 Marcel vander Linden Non-scheduled demand is unpredictable and unplanned, and usually comes as an unpleasant surprise (illness, unemployment,etc.). Rotating allocation means that all participants in amutualist arrangement will come in for their turn;there is then necessarilyalways amaximum number of par- ticipants (roughlybetween 10 and 200), because everyone wants to have his or her turn within areasonable period of time. Non-rotating arrangementsimplythat only some of the participants will receive money,labour or goods from the common fund. With non-rotation, there is no technical limit to the membership in these cases, and thereforesuch associations can contain large groups of people. Scheduled demand and rotating allocation In some cases mutualism revolvesaround the provision of labour;the participants in an arrangement can either rotatelabour,oruse labour for the production of one good, by which all can benefit.Inthe first case (rotation), one person first “con- sumes” the labour of the rest of the group, and after that another,etc. Such forms of labour rotation are known around the world.¹ Nicolaasvan Meeteren describes such an arrangement on Curaçao, which was popularthere until the first decades of the twentieth century: “Wheneverone needed to weed, plant or harvest,the cus- tom was implemented that was known as ‘saam.’ All neighborsthen agreed to work for each other once or twice in the week in the evening by moonlight.The beneficiary of the workprovided rum and refreshments. As the workers encouraged each other by singinginturns in ‘guenee’ or ‘Macamba,’ the work went smoothlyand everyone benefittedbyit.”² VanMeeteren thinks thatasaam had the advantage that the work was done much faster, because workers encouraged each other,which is very impor- tant,especiallyfor strenuous labour in the fields.³ Other writers confirm this con- jecture. David Ames offers twoexplanations:workinginagroup both stimulates friendlycompetition among workers,and is more agreeable: “Working with one’s companions,joking and singing, is obviouslyless tedious thansolitary labour.”⁴ In the second form of labour mutualism, the joint effort results in a shared prod- uct.The members of the collective gather once or several times to work together,for See e.g., T.S. Epstein, EconomicDevelopment and Social ChangeinSouth India (Manchester: Man- chester University Press, 1962),p.73; Alan Dawley, Class and Community.The Industrial Revolution in Lynn (Cambridge,MA, and London: HarvardUniversity Press, 1976), p. 57;Diana Wong, Peasants in the Making.Malaysia′sGreen Revolution (Singapore: InstituteofSoutheast AsianStudies,1987), p. 120. Nicolaasvan Meeteren, Volkskunde vanCuraçao (Willemstad: no publisher,1947), p. 35. Ibid. David W. Ames, “Wolof Co-operative Work Groups”,in: William R. Bascomand Melville J. Hersko- vits (eds), Continuity and ChangeinAfrican Cultures (Chicago [etc.]: Chicago University Press, 1959), pp. 224–237, at 231. 8.1. Mutualism 493 the production of agood from which they all hope to benefit when it is finished.Col- lectively building acommunity centre or achurch are good examples. Labour mutualism often becomes less important when the role of money increas- es in the local economy. The tendencytobuy labour tasks individuallywith money then usuallygrows.OnCuraçao,the saam seems to have disappeared from the 1920s or 1930s onwards.Similartrends are visible in manyplaces.⁵ But thereare alsoex- ceptions to this rule. In the case of the Maka in Southeastern Cameroon, the rise of the cash crop cultivation instead stimulated labour rotation, because the Maka re- fused to perform wagelabour for the other villagers.⁶ It is asmall step from labour mutuals to mutualist institutions, wherethe fund consists partlyorwhollyofgoods or money.Labour rotation corresponds exactlyto the simplest kind of the so—called rotating and credit savings association (rosca), in which, however,the labour input is replacedbyacontribution in kind or in money. Forexample, an anthropological studyinthe early1960s recorded that Indian mi- grants on the island of Mauritius operated a rosca called a cycle or cheet: “A man or awoman calls togetheragroup of friends and neighbours. Suppose there are tenofthem, and each puts in Rs. 10.They then draw lots and the winner takes the Rs. 100.(Sometimes the organizer automaticallytakes the first ‘pool’.) The following month each again puts in Rs. 10,and another member takes the result- ing Rs. 100;and so it continues for tenmonths until each member has had his Rs. 100.”⁷ In other words, sums of money weredeposited in the cheet,but for the rest the logic was the same as in labour rotation. It is thereforenot surprising that some scientists believe roscasoriginated in rotatinglabour pools.⁸ Whether this ex- planationiscorrect has yettobeestablished by empirical research. But roscascan also be much more complex than in the simple case outlined above. The allocation of the order of rotation is central to roscas. It can be deter- mined by acommon arrangement among participants; an allocation by the organiz- er; by auction; or by drawing lots. In an auction, participants can of course exert a stronginfluenceonthe order of allocation, and this method can thereforelead to complex relations of debt and credit within the arrangement.Inthe case of Mauri- Charles J. Erasmus, “Culture,Structureand Process:The Occurrence and Disappearance of Recip- rocalFarm Labor”, Southwestern Journal of Anthropology,12(1956), pp. 444–469; Paul F. Brown, “Population Growthand the Disappearance of Reciprocal Labor in aHighland Peruvian Community”, Research in Economic Anthropology,8(1987), pp. 225–245. Peter Geschiere, “WorkingGroups or Wage Labour?Cash-crops, Reciprocity and Money amongthe MakaofSoutheastern Cameroon”, Development and Change,26(1995), pp. 503–523. Burton Benedict, “Capital, Savingand CreditamongMauritian Indians”,in: Raymond Firth and B.S.Yamey (eds), Capital, Saving and Credit in Peasant Societies (London: George Allen and Unwin, 1964), pp. 330 – 346,at341. AnthonyI.Nwabughuogu, “The Isusu: An Instititution for Capital Formation amongthe Ngwa Igbo;its Origin and Development to 1951”, Africa,54, 4(1984), pp. 46–58, at 47;Mark W. Delancey, “Credit for the Common Man in Cameroon”, Journal of Modern African Studies,15, 3(1977), pp. 316– 322, at 319. 494 Marcel vander Linden tius, we find that, likethe Indian immigrants on the island, the Chinese also had ros- cas. But these functionedinadifferent way: “The Chinese on the island – as elsewhere – operateavariant of the cycle in which the ‘lenders’ (late drawers)ineffect receive interest payments fromthe ‘borrowers’ (earlydrawers). The par- ticipants bid for turns;aman in need of quick cash
Recommended publications
  • Fighting for France's Political Future in the Long Wake of the Commune, 1871-1880
    University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Publicly Accessible Penn Dissertations 2013 Long Live the Revolutions: Fighting for France's Political Future in the Long Wake of the Commune, 1871-1880 Heather Marlene Bennett University of Pennsylvania, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.upenn.edu/edissertations Part of the European History Commons Recommended Citation Bennett, Heather Marlene, "Long Live the Revolutions: Fighting for France's Political Future in the Long Wake of the Commune, 1871-1880" (2013). Publicly Accessible Penn Dissertations. 734. https://repository.upenn.edu/edissertations/734 This paper is posted at ScholarlyCommons. https://repository.upenn.edu/edissertations/734 For more information, please contact [email protected]. Long Live the Revolutions: Fighting for France's Political Future in the Long Wake of the Commune, 1871-1880 Abstract The traumatic legacies of the Paris Commune and its harsh suppression in 1871 had a significant impact on the identities and voter outreach efforts of each of the chief political blocs of the 1870s. The political and cultural developments of this phenomenal decade, which is frequently mislabeled as calm and stable, established the Republic's longevity and set its character. Yet the Commune's legacies have never been comprehensively examined in a way that synthesizes their political and cultural effects. This dissertation offers a compelling perspective of the 1870s through qualitative and quantitative analyses of the influence of these legacies, using sources as diverse as parliamentary debates, visual media, and scribbled sedition on city walls, to explicate the decade's most important political and cultural moments, their origins, and their impact.
    [Show full text]
  • SEWER SYNDICALISM: WORKER SELF- MANAGEMENT in PUBLIC SERVICES Eric M
    \\jciprod01\productn\N\NVJ\14-2\NVJ208.txt unknown Seq: 1 30-APR-14 10:47 SEWER SYNDICALISM: WORKER SELF- MANAGEMENT IN PUBLIC SERVICES Eric M. Fink* Staat ist ein Verh¨altnis, ist eine Beziehung zwischen den Menschen, ist eine Art, wie die Menschen sich zu einander verhalten; und man zerst¨ort ihn, indem man andere Beziehungen eingeht, indem man sich anders zu einander verh¨alt.1 I. INTRODUCTION In the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, municipal govern- ments in various US cities assumed responsibility for utilities and other ser- vices that previously had been privately operated. In the late twentieth century, prompted by fiscal crisis and encouraged by neo-liberal ideology, governments embraced the concept of “privatization,” shifting management and control over public services2 to private entities. Despite disagreements over the merits of privatization, both proponents and opponents accept the premise of a fundamental distinction between the “public” and “private” sectors, and between “state” and “market” institutions. A more skeptical view questions the analytical soundness and practical signifi- cance of these dichotomies. In this view, “privatization” is best understood as a rhetorical strategy, part of a broader neo-liberal ideology that relies on putative antinomies of “public” v. “private” and “state” v. “market” to obscure and rein- force social and economic power relations. While “privatization” may be an ideological definition of the situation, for public service workers the difference between employment in the “public” and “private” sectors can be real in its consequences3 for job security, compensa- * Associate Professor of Law, Elon University School of Law, Greensboro, North Carolina.
    [Show full text]
  • Biblical Holism and Agriculture: Cultivating Our Roots
    Book Manuscript Final Draft Title: Biblical Holism and Agriculture: Cultivating our Roots Submitted to: William Carey Library Publishing Office Submitted by Editors: David J. Evans, Ronald J. Vos, and Keith P. Wright On 03 October 2003 CONTENTS Editors and Contributors Forward Introduction Building Consensus for Biblical Holism in Agriculture David J. Evans and Keith Wright The Agriculturist and God Chapter 1: Reclaiming a Biblical Vision for Agriculture Wayne A. Kobes Chapter 2: The Worship of God through Agriculture Jesse T. Njoka The Agriculturist and Humanity Chapter 3: Social Principles for ‘Good’ Agriculture Ronald J. Vos Chapter 4: Behold I Give You: A Christian Perspective on Farming James Ball The Agriculturist and Creation Chapter 5: Production Principles for ‘Good’ Agriculture Robert De Haan Chapter 6: Enabling Creation’s Praise: Lessons in Agricultural Stewardship from Africa Harry Spaling The Agriculturist and Knowledge Chapter 7: Affinity, Dominion, and the Poverty of our Day: Calling and Task of Agri- Culture in a World That Belongs to God John H. Kok i The Agriculturist and Purpose Chapter 8: Agriculture and the Kingdom of God Darrow Miller Chapter 9: On Dams, Demons, Wells and Witches: Managing the Message of Transformational Development Bruce Bradshaw The Agriculturist and Ethics Chapter 10: The Bible as Ethical Standard for Appraising Modern Agricultural Practices Michael Oye Chapter 11: Integration Towards Ethical Agriculture: Challenges, Principles and Practice in International Perspective E. John Wibberley The Agriculturist and Economics Chapter 12: Is Our Agricultural House Built on Sand? Biblical Holism in Agriculture and the Assumption of Monotonicity in the Utility Function Kara Unger Ball Chapter 13: Redeeming Agriculture and Economics through Worldview Transformation Greg De Haan Conclusion Give Us this Day our Daily Bread: A Prayer to the First Farmer David J.
    [Show full text]
  • The Third Way and the Governance of the Social in Britain Jérôme Tournadre
    The Third Way and the governance of the social in Britain Jérôme Tournadre To cite this version: Jérôme Tournadre. The Third Way and the governance of the social in Britain. A city of one’s own, Ashgate, pp.201-212, 2008. halshs-00649541 HAL Id: halshs-00649541 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00649541 Submitted on 9 Dec 2011 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. CHAPTER TWELVE The ‘Third Way’ and the Governance of the Social in Britain Jérôme Tournadre-Plancq Regardless of the ‘world of Welfare’ in which it functions - to use the term coined by Gøsta Esping-Andersen (Esping-Andersen 1990) - the State has, during a large part of the twentieth century, come to play an essential role in the handling of welfare in liberal democracies. This does not mean that its role amounts to exercising a monopoly. Providing a counterweight to the market in the social-democratic ‘compromise’, the Welfare State often emerges, in the political reflection of the majority of the post-war centre-left, as the most reliable guarantor for the common good. The Social (Donzelot 1984) is then considered as the best way to reinforce this idea.
    [Show full text]
  • Senior Cohousing: an Organizational Model for Elderly Care
    Senior Cohousing: An Organizational Model for Elderly Care. A Trentino Case Study Annamaria Perinoa, Marilena Restab a Department of Sociology and Social Research, University of Trento (Italy) b Freelance Social worker, Bari (Italy) Abstract. Senior Cohousing is an innovative practice of cohabitation for elder people. This model if on the one hand is oriented to build and maintain relationships of social solidarity, on the other, it supports families in caring for elderly people. Cohousing is based on the active involvement of each member and on cooperation between people. For these reasons it could represent a new organization model for the care of people and could promote their active ageing. To testify the positive effects of Senior Cohousing the paper presents the results of a research carried out in Trentino during 2017. The case study analyzed the practices of cohabitation realized by “The Homes of SAD”. These experiences turn out to be innovative both because they are rather far from the traditional models of assistance, and because they value the abilities of individuals, promoting their self-determination and empowerment. Keywords: active ageing, care, cohabitation, family, welfare policies. Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to Annamaria Perino, Department of Sociology and Social Research, University of Trento, Italy, [email protected] Received: 26.06.2019 – Revision: 15.09.2019– Accepted: 10.12.2019 Interdisciplinary Journal of Family Studies, XXIV, 2/2019 Introduction During the past fifty years various phenomena have altered the significance and approach to care for the elderly both in Italy and abroad. The most important changes affecting the need for and fulfillment of care roles include: the increased life expectancy of individuals; the improved living conditions of the elderly; and the shifts in the social and familial structures (as with the collapse of the patriarchal family model and the entry of women in the job market).
    [Show full text]
  • Support for Farmers' Cooperatives Country Report Spain
    Support for Farmers' Cooperatives Country Report Spain Cynthia Giagnocavo Carlos Vargas-Vasserot The 2011-2012 project „Support for Farmers‘ Cooperatives“ is commissioned and funded by the European Commission, DG Agriculture and Rural Development. Contract Number: 30-CE-0395921/00-42. The project is managed by Wageningen UR’s Agricultural Economics Research Institute LEI and Wageningen University. Project managers: Krijn J. Poppe and Jos Bijman. Other members of the consortium are: • Pellervo Economic Research PTT, Finland: Perttu Pyykkönen • University of Helsinki, Finland: Petri Ollila • Agricultural Economics Research Institute, Greece: Constantine Iliopoulos • Justus Liebig University Giessen, Germany: Rainer Kühl • Humboldt University Berlin, Germany: Konrad Hagedorn, Markus Hanisch and Renate Judis • HIVA Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium: Caroline Gijselinckx • Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, The Netherlands: George Hendrikse and Tony Hak How to cite this report: Giagnocavo, C., C. Vargas-Vasserot (2012). Support for Farmers’ Cooperatives; Country Report Spain. Wageningen: Wageningen UR. Disclaimer: This study, financed by the European Commission, was carried out by a consortium under the management of LEI Wageningen UR. The conclusions and recommendations presented in this report are the sole responsibility of the research consortium and do not necessarily reflect the opinion of the Commission or anticipate its future policies. Support for Farmers' Cooperatives Country Report Spain Cynthia Giagnocavo
    [Show full text]
  • Mutualism As Market Practice: an Examination of Market Performativity in the Context of Anarchism and Its Implications for Post-Capitalist Politics
    Mutualism as market practice: An examination of market performativity in the context of anarchism and its implications for post-capitalist politics Lloveras, J., Warnaby, G. & Quinn, L. Author post-print (accepted) deposited by Coventry University’s Repository Original citation & hyperlink: Lloveras, J, Warnaby, G & Quinn, L 2019, 'Mutualism as market practice: An examination of market performativity in the context of anarchism and its implications for post-capitalist politics' Marketing Theory, vol. (In-Press), pp. (In-Press). https://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1470593119885172 DOI 10.1177/1470593119885172 ISSN 1470-5931 ESSN 1741-301X Publisher: SAGE Publications Copyright © and Moral Rights are retained by the author(s) and/ or other copyright owners. A copy can be downloaded for personal non-commercial research or study, without prior permission or charge. This item cannot be reproduced or quoted extensively from without first obtaining permission in writing from the copyright holder(s). The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any format or medium without the formal permission of the copyright holders. This document is the author’s post-print version, incorporating any revisions agreed during the peer-review process. Some differences between the published version and this version may remain and you are advised to consult the published version if you wish to cite from it. Mutualism as market practice: An examination of market performativity in the context of anarchism and its implications for post-capitalist politics Javier Lloveras (Faculty of Business and Law, Manchester Metropolitan University, UK) Gary Warnaby (Faculty of Business and Law, Manchester Metropolitan University, UK) Lee Quinn (Faculty Research Centre for Business in Society, Coventry University, UK) Javier Lloveras is a Senior Lecturer in Marketing and Consumer Behaviour based at the Manchester Metropolitan University Business School, where he is affiliated to the Business Transformations Research Center and the Institute of Place Management.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Mutualism?
    What is Mutualism? MUTUALISM A Social System Based on Equal Freedom, Reciprocity, and the Sovereignty of the Individual Over Himself, His Affairs, and His Products, Realized Through Individual Initiative, Free Contract, Cooperation, Competition, and Clarence Lee Swartz Voluntary Association for Defence Against the Invasive and for the Protection of Life, Liberty and Property of the Non-invasive. ANARCHISM What is Mutualism? Clarence Lee Swartz was an American individualist anarchist, a mutualist on economic matters, a devotee of Benjamin Tucker and even more harshly critical of anarcho­communism than him. He edited an anarchist journal called Voice of the People and was an assistant editor for Moses Harman's journal entitled Lucifer, the Light­Bearer. He was arrested in Kansas City, MO for distributing a newspaper called Sunday Sun in 1891. The charges were dropped when the prosecutor failed to show in court. Clarence Lee Swartz Vanguard Press April, 1927 2nd ed. 1945 cost principle, so that society may at last move in the right direction. For the inauguration and successful operation of the Mutual Bank, a considerable number of representatives of diversified industries would be essential. The organization of such a group must be the first task of those who wish to put that I phase of Mutualism into practice. The co-operatives have such an aggregation already at hand, organized and trained in associative effort. Here, then, a beginning PRIVILEGE AND AUTHORITY can be made, if such associations can be brought to perceive the immense benefits to all society to be derived from this extension of their principles. These associations have the psychological foundation and the mechanism for the purpose.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Nature of the Paris Commune of 1871 and Manifestations of Marxist Ideology in the Official Publications of the Central Committee
    Virginia Commonwealth University VCU Scholars Compass Theses and Dissertations Graduate School 2018 The Political Nature of the Paris Commune of 1871 and Manifestations of Marxist Ideology in the Official Publications of the Central Committee Emily M. Jones Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarscompass.vcu.edu/etd Part of the European History Commons, Intellectual History Commons, Labor History Commons, Political History Commons, and the Social History Commons © The Author Downloaded from https://scholarscompass.vcu.edu/etd/5417 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at VCU Scholars Compass. It has been accepted for inclusion in Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of VCU Scholars Compass. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Political Nature of the Paris Commune of 1871 and Manifestations of Marxist Ideology in the Official Publications of the Central Committee A thesis submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts at Virginia Commonwealth University by Emily Marshall Jones Bachelor of Arts, Randolph-Macon College, 2010 Director: Joseph W. Bendersky, PhD Department of History Virginia Commonwealth University Richmond, Virginia May, 2018 ii Acknowledgements I would like to thank Dr. Joseph Bendersky for his guidance and encouragement. His direction and excellent advising made both my research and this written work possible. I would also like to thank my readers, Dr. John Herman and Dr. Robert Godwin-Jones for their efforts, advice, and input. I want to thank my parents for their love, support, enthusiasm, and, most of all, their faith in me.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Workers' Self-Directed Enterprises' *Accepted Version of an A
    ORE Open Research Exeter TITLE Beyond Co-optation: Revisiting the Transformative Function of "Workers’ Self-Directed Enterprises" AUTHORS Masquelier, CAD JOURNAL Socialism and Democracy DEPOSITED IN ORE 03 July 2017 This version available at http://hdl.handle.net/10871/28276 COPYRIGHT AND REUSE Open Research Exeter makes this work available in accordance with publisher policies. A NOTE ON VERSIONS The version presented here may differ from the published version. If citing, you are advised to consult the published version for pagination, volume/issue and date of publication Beyond co-option: revisiting the transformative function of ‘workers’ self-directed enterprises’ *Accepted version of an article to be published by Socialism and Democracy* Introduction In several recent accounts on the prospects for social change, commentators have sought to assign a transformative role to enterprises owned and managed by workers. According to Gar Alperovitz (2011; 2013), for example, these economic organisational forms – among others – not only offer solutions to the problems generated by capitalism, but are also said to have initiated a gradual process of social transformation or ‘evolutionary reconstruction.’ Such views are echoed in Richard Wolff’s work, in which ‘workers’ self directed enterprises’ (WSDEs) are presented as both a ‘superior way to organize production’ and one of the ‘contemporary programs for progressive social change’ (2012: 2). Belief in the transformative capacity of cooperative enterprises, however, is not new. In the UK, a large proportion of the Rochdale Pioneers identified with the socialist cause, and shared Robert Owen’s optimism regarding the possibility for cooperatives to lead the development of a new social (and ‘moral’) order.
    [Show full text]
  • Practical Anarchism: Peer Mutualism, Market Power, and the Fallible State
    Practical Anarchism: Peer Mutualism, Market Power, and the Fallible State “The most significant difference between political thought inside the digirati and outside it is that in the network society, anarchism (or more properly, anti-possessive individualism) is a viable political philosophy.” Eben Moglen, Anarchism Triumphant, FIRST MONDAY 1999. Commons-based peer production has come to play a large role in the construction of the networked environment, networked culture, and the networked social order. Non-proprietary, voluntaristic, self-organized practices account for standard setting for the Internet itself, development of some of the core software utilities that run the Web, as well as, increasingly, operating systems of servers, smartphones, and embedded computing; enterprise software; content management systems, and even statistics packages rely on free and open source software. The basic infrastructure for our synthesized “state of knowledge,” our age's Encyclopedia, is some combination of Wikipedia and the Google search, itself an amalgamation of information produced by both traditional models and new, distributed, nonprorietary models of cooperation. Over the course of the first decade of the 21st century, commons-based peer production has moved from being ignored, through being mocked, feared, regarded as an exception or intellectual quirk, to finally becoming a normal and indispensable part of life. The experience of the last two decades with networked peer models moderates one doubt, and raises two major questions. The doubt alleviated concerns the feasibility of sustained, large-scale cooperation in the absence of property or hierarchy. The experience of the last decade offers substantial existence proof that non-proprietary voluntaristic cooperation can create outputs whose production was previously thought to require hierarchical state or corporate organization, anchored in proprietary control over the resources necessary for, and products of, human action.
    [Show full text]
  • Worker Mutualism in an Age of Entrepreneurial Capitalism
    Labour & Industry: a journal of the social and economic relations of work ISSN: 1030-1763 (Print) 2325-5676 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rlab20 Worker mutualism in an age of entrepreneurial capitalism Dorothy Sue Cobble To cite this article: Dorothy Sue Cobble (2016) Worker mutualism in an age of entrepreneurial capitalism, Labour & Industry: a journal of the social and economic relations of work, 26:3, 179-189, DOI: 10.1080/10301763.2016.1205939 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10301763.2016.1205939 Published online: 26 Sep 2016. Submit your article to this journal View related articles View Crossmark data Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rlab20 Download by: [Stockholm University Library], [Dorothy Sue Cobble] Date: 26 September 2016, At: 02:35 LABOUR AND INDUSTRY, 2016 VOL. 26, NO. 3, 179–189 http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10301763.2016.1205939 Worker mutualism in an age of entrepreneurial capitalism Dorothy Sue Cobble School of Management and Labor Relations, Rutgers, State University of New Jersey, New Brunswick, NJ, USA ABSTRACT ARTICLE HISTORY In this Keynote Address to the 30th AIRAANZ Conference in Received 3 May 2016 Sydney, the author identifies three vital and promising models of Accepted 22 June 2016 worker mutualism. These models show that worker mutualism is KEYWORDS thriving, even in an era of entrepreneurial and hyper-individualistic Worker mutualism; capitalism. Indeed, we are at a moment of recovery and reconfi- entrepreneurial capitalism; guration for labour and labour movements globally.
    [Show full text]