Dynamics of Price Sensitivity and Market Structure in an Evolutionary Economic Matching Model

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Dynamics of Price Sensitivity and Market Structure in an Evolutionary Economic Matching Model Complex Adaptive Systems and the Threshold Effect: Views from the Natural and Social Sciences: Papers from the AAAI Fall Symposium (FS-09-03) Dynamics of Price Sensitivity and Market Structure in an Evolutionary Economic Matching Model Griffin Vernor Drutchas and Péter Érdi Center for Complex Systems Studies (CCSS) Kalamazoo College 1200 Academy Street Kalamazoo, MI 49006 [email protected] [email protected] Abstract ward these related public and private ends, creating a simu- The relationship between equilibrium convergence to a uni- lated laboratory allows safe exploration of interdependency form quality distribution and price is investigated in the Q- and uncertainty, system dynamics, and potential policies model, a self-organizing, evolutionary computational for improving market outcomes. matching model of a fixed-price post-secondary higher edu- cation system created by Ortmann and Slobodyan (2006). Building on the Q-Model The Q-model is replicated with price equaling its Ortmann and Slobodyan (2006) value P*. Varying the fixed price be- The following model and simulation experiments build tween 0 and 2P* reveals thresholds at which the Q-model upon the self-organizing economic models of Nicholas reaches different market clustering configurations. Results Vriend (1995) and Andreas Ortmann and Sergey indicate structural market robustness to prices less than P* Slobodyan (2006) in creating a decentralized market “cul- and high sensitivity to prices greater than P*. ture-dish that allows [one] to explore how macro regulari- ties emerge through the repeated local interactions of boundedly rational, heterogenous agents” (Ortmann and Introduction (1) Slobodyan 2006). Vriend (1995) builds and explores the Over the past two decades, the American post-secondary baseline dynamics of an evolutionary economy where ho- education system—the collection of colleges, universities, mogenous firms and consumers seek transactions while and institutes that offer education beyond high school—has behaving based on the success of past choices. Ortmann expanded to accommodate growing student enrollment. and Slobodyan (2006) generalize Vriend (1995) into the Q- From 1985 to 2005, full-time attendance at post-secondary model: a firm-consumer matching model that includes het- institutions rose 33 percent (NCES 2007). Attendance erogenous agents stratified along a quality spectrum and is rates were higher still for historically underprivileged applied to the study of the post-secondary education sys- groups. Nonetheless, the universally rising cost of a post- tem. Using the market analogy in the context of education, secondary degree in America threatens to erode the future the terms firm, seller, school, institution, and university are socioeconomic gains of education. In the same twenty year used interchangeably. Likewise, consumer, buyer, and period as above, average tuition, room, and board rose by student are treated the same. 60 percent after adjustment for inflation, outpacing real Agents in the Q-model prefer to transact with other household income and the availability of financial aid agents in a similar quality range. Coupled with a Classifier (NCES 2008). Furthermore, education grants are increas- System (CS) and Genetic Algorithm (GA) for weighting ingly being displaced in favor of student loans (Baum et al. and creating behavioral rules, respectively, internal agent 2002). The latter trend raises the net cost of education, preferences give rise to an artificially learned equilibrium either pricing students out of pursuing a degree or creating convergence to uniform market structure and stable aggre- debt. Thus, the relationship between price and access to gate behavior. Ortmann and Slobodyan’s (2006) results education is explored here. are also robust to scale. Uncovering the systemic causes and effects of rising tui- However, price is fixed at P = 1 in Ortmann and Slo- tion and student debt on actors in the education system will bodyan (2006) and Vriend (1995), limiting either model’s be vital in developing policies for sustainable market power to simulate rising tuition and debt trends. Due in growth. Awareness of interrelated microeconomic and part to a firm’s quality being a weighted average of current market structural effects of admissions strategies and pric- attending consumer quality Qavg and its own profits π—a ing would likewise benefit an individual institution. To- relationship exactly described later—changing a firm’s 39 price affects firm quality. Changing a firm’s quality shifts the range of consumers a firm prefers to seek. In a recent undergraduate thesis, Drutchas and Érdi (2009) replicate and modify the Q-model to include endogenous price- setting with initial average market price equal to its Ort- mann and Slobodyan (2006) level P*. Average price con- verges to slightly less than P* and aggregate values remain stable. Yet market structure, the distribution of firms across the quality spectrum, exhibits high instability and skewness regardless of profit weight calibrations of a firm’s quality update rule (Drutchas and Érdi 2009). Insta- bility is undesirable from the standpoint of a system mod- eler because it limits replicability of results. High skew- ness of firm quality is undesirable in the market for educa- tion because it limits consumer access. In an effort to move toward a model that has stability, extendability, and explanatory power, the effect of price on market structure in the Q-model is explored systematically. The replication of the Q-model and subsequent experimen- tal results indicate the existence of asymmetric thresholds around P* but beyond which market structure converges to TABLE 3: Summary of Q-model parameters. different equilibria. Model Structure (2) Though some gaps in Ortmann and Slobodyan’s (2006) Unlike consumers in the Q-model, whose initialized description of the Q-model are filled with facts from quality is fixed throughout simulation, firms update their Vriend’s (1995) decentralized economic matching model, quality at the end of each period according to Equation 2 the underlying system structure of the Q-model is repli- (Ortmann and Slobodyan 2006). Ortmann and Slobodyan cated here as closely as possible. Two types of boundedly (2006) calibrate the quality updating parameters α and α rational agents—firms and consumers—interact by seeking 1 2 to fixed values that result in a symmetric steady state transactions that satisfy internal agent preferences and market structure uniformly distributed across the quality making probabilistic stochastic choices. spectrum: All agents are initialized in the first period (semester) with a random quality Q from a uniform distribution to a ‘Symmetric steady state’ denotes situations where quality spectrum M, where Q M [0, 100]. In every time every firm shares the same number of agents, where period agents follow a multi-part economic protocol. every firm serves the same number of agents, where Firms choose both how many units to produce and how every firm has the same profit share . and where the many signals to send to eligible consumers about the units quality of the firm equals the average quality of its produced. In turn, consumers choose to apply to an eligi- consumers. We calibrate the model so that the ble firm from among their received signals. Following average firm quality . equals the average consumer evaluation of consumer applications, acceptance and atten- quality of 50 (which, given our assumption of uniform dance decisions are made. distribution of consumers along the quality spectrum Agents evaluate their success by income earned in the [0,100], is what we can expect on average). current time period. Each agent CS adjusts accordingly the likelihood of repeating their most recent decision if faced Agent Signal Preferences with a similar environment in the future. Consumer Both firms and consumers determine eligibility by check- income I equals a boolean value representing consumer C ing an agent’s quality (QC,F) against their own internal satisfaction: 1 if attending a firm, 0 if not. Firm income IF preferences. Firms randomly choose with replacement a equals the normalized value of profit π as a function of consumer and signal her only if her QC falls within that price P, production Y, demand D, the number of signals S, firm’s range of acceptable consumer quality the marginal production cost C , and the marginal C F Y [QF – Δ , QF + Δ ] (Ortmann and Slobodyan 2006). The signaling cost CS, all scaled by QF (Ortmann and lower bound is the firm’s own preference and allows firms Slobodyan (2006). to signal consumers who are of lesser quality but not be- C yond a low quality tolerance [Q – Δ ]. This reflects the π = [ P · min(Y, D) – CY · Y – CS · S ] · [ QF / 100 ] (1) F tendency of universities to admit applicants of lesser qual- Q = α · Q + α · π (2) t + 1 1 avg 2 ity because they at least generate revenue and at most IF = (π / πavg) · U [0, 1] (3) benefit from education by a higher quality school. A uni- 40 versity would not accept an applicant who would nega- possible actions, but are not subject to a GA and do not tively affect university quality beyond the benefit of mar- change throughout the simulation. As in Ortmann and ginal revenue from that applicant’s attendance. Slobodyan (2006): The upper bound is not a firm’s own preference but in- [Consumers’] behavioral rules each have a conditional stead knowledge of consumers’ preference for only those F part and an action part . The conditional part firms with quality greater than [Q – Δ ]. In other words, a C determines if a rule will be activated . given the consumer will only accept a signal from a firm with Q F current state of the world while the action part greater than a minimum acceptance threshold. Conse- F encodes possible actions. Specifically, rules have the quently, the upper firm preference bound [Q + Δ ] exists F following form: to avoid wasting a signal on an out-of-reach consumer who will only reject a firm’s signal because it is below their minimum acceptable quality.
Recommended publications
  • The Market Structure of Higher Learning
    The Park Place Economist Volume 4 Issue 1 Article 16 5-1996 The Market Structure of Higher Learning Brett Roush '97 Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/parkplace Recommended Citation Roush '97, Brett (1996) "The Market Structure of Higher Learning," The Park Place Economist: Vol. 4 Available at: https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/parkplace/vol4/iss1/16 This Article is protected by copyright and/or related rights. It has been brought to you by Digital Commons @ IWU with permission from the rights-holder(s). You are free to use this material in any way that is permitted by the copyright and related rights legislation that applies to your use. For other uses you need to obtain permission from the rights-holder(s) directly, unless additional rights are indicated by a Creative Commons license in the record and/ or on the work itself. This material has been accepted for inclusion by faculty at Illinois Wesleyan University. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ©Copyright is owned by the author of this document. The Market Structure of Higher Learning Abstract A student embarking on a college search is astounded at the number of higher learning institutions available -- an initial response may be to consider their market structure as one of perfect competition. Upon fkrther consideration, though, one sees this is inaccurate. In fact, the market structure of higher learning incorporates elements of monopolistic competition, oligopoly, and monopoly. An institution may not explicitly be a profit maximizer. However, treating it as such allows predictions of actions to be made by applying the above three market structures.
    [Show full text]
  • The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond
    Working Paper No. 822 The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond by Riccardo Bellofiore* University of Bergamo December 2014 * [email protected] This paper was prepared for the project “Financing Innovation: An Application of a Keynes-Schumpeter- Minsky Synthesis,” funded in part by the Institute for New Economic Thinking, INET grant no. IN012-00036, administered through the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Co-principal investigators: Mariana Mazzucato (Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex) and L. Randall Wray (Levy Institute). The author thanks INET and the Levy Institute for support of this research. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2014 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X Abstract An understanding of, and an intervention into, the present capitalist reality requires that we put together the insights of Karl Marx on labor, as well as those of Hyman Minsky on finance. The best way to do this is within a longer-term perspective, looking at the different stages through which capitalism evolves.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Exchange During Hyperinflation
    Economic Exchange during Hyperinflation Alessandra Casella Universityof California, Berkeley Jonathan S. Feinstein Stanford University Historical evidence indicates that hyperinflations can disrupt indi- viduals' normal trading patterns and impede the orderly functioning of markets. To explore these issues, we construct a theoretical model of hyperinflation that focuses on individuals and their process of economic exchange. In our model buyers must carry cash while shopping, and some transactions take place in a decentralized setting in which buyer and seller negotiate over the terms of trade of an indivisible good. Since buyers face the constant threat of incoming younger (hence richer) customers, their bargaining position is weak- ened by inflation, allowing sellers to extract a higher real price. How- ever, we show that higher inflation also reduces buyers' search, increasing sellers' wait for customers. As a result, the volume of transactions concluded in the decentralized sector falls. At high enough rates of inflation, all agents suffer a welfare loss. I. Introduction Since. Cagan (1956), economic analyses of hyperinflations have fo- cused attention on aggregate time-series data, especially exploding price levels and money stocks, lost output, and depreciating exchange rates. Work on the German hyperinflation of the twenties provides a We thank Olivier Blanchard, Peter Diamond, Rudi Dornbusch, Stanley Fischer, Bob Gibbons, the referee, and the editor of this Journal for helpful comments. Alessandra Casella thanks the Sloan Foundation
    [Show full text]
  • Market-Structure.Pdf
    This chapter covers the types of market such as perfect competition, monopoly, oligopoly and monopolistic competition, in which business firms operate. Basically, when we hear the word market, we think of a place where goods are being bought and sold. In economics, market is a place where buyers and sellers are exchanging goods and services with the following considerations such as: • Types of goods and services being traded • The number and size of buyers and sellers in the market • The degree to which information can flow freely Perfect or Pure Market Imperfect Market Perfect Market is a market situation which consists of a very large number of buyers and sellers offering a homogeneous product. Under such condition, no firm can affect the market price. Price is determined through the market demand and supply of the particular product, since no single buyer or seller has any control over the price. Perfect Competition is built on two critical assumptions: . The behavior of an individual firm . The nature of the industry in which it operates The firm is assumed to be a price taker The industry is characterized by freedom of entry and exit Industry • Normal demand and supply curves • More supply at higher price Firm • Price takers • Have to accept the industry price Perfect Competition cannot be found in the real world. For such to exist, the following conditions must be observed and required: A large number of sellers Selling a homogenous product No artificial restrictions placed upon price or quantity Easy entry and exit All buyers and sellers have perfect knowledge of market conditions and of any changes that occur in the market Firms are “price takers” There are very many small firms All producers of a good sell the same product There are no barriers to enter the market All consumers and producers have ‘perfect information’ Firms sell all they produce, but they cannot set a price.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis Joel P
    Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business Volume 17 Issue 1 Winter Winter 1997 The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis Joel P. Trachtman Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/njilb Part of the International Trade Commons Recommended Citation Joel P. Trachtman, The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis, 17 Nw. J. Int'l L. & Bus. 470 (1996-1997) This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business by an authorized administrator of Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis Joel P. Trachtman* Without a theory they had nothing to pass on except a mass of descriptive material waiting for a theory, or a fire. 1 While the kind of close comparative institutional analysis which Coase called for in The Nature of the Firm was once completely outside the universe of mainstream econo- mists, and remains still a foreign, if potentially productive enterrise for many, close com- parative analysis of institutions is home turf for law professors. Hierarchical arrangements are being examined by economic theorists studying the or- ganization of firms, but for less cosmic purposes than would be served3 by political and economic organization of the production of international public goods. I. INTRODUCrION: THE PROBLEM Debates regarding the competences and governance of interna- tional economic organizations such as the World Trade Organization * Associate Professor of International Law, The Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Tufts University.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulation, Market Structure and Performance in Telecommunications
    OECD Economic Studies No. 32, 2001/I REGULATION, MARKET STRUCTURE AND PERFORMANCE IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS By Olivier Boylaud and Giuseppe Nicoletti TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 100 Regulation and market structure in telecommunications: a cross-country perspective ... 102 Past trends in regulatory reform............................................................................................ 103 Summarising regulatory reform for empirical analysis ....................................................... 111 Evaluating the effects of regulatory reform on performance in telecommunications........ 117 The empirical approach taken here...................................................................................... 119 The performance data ............................................................................................................122 Empirical results...................................................................................................................... 124 Conclusions.................................................................................................................................. 133 Annex. Panel Data Estimation Techniques ......................................................................... 139 Bibliography ................................................................................................................................ 141 The authors wish
    [Show full text]
  • 0530 New Institutional Economics
    0530 NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS Peter G. Klein Department of Economics, University of Georgia © Copyright 1999 Peter G. Klein Abstract This chapter surveys the new institutional economics, a rapidly growing literature combining economics, law, organization theory, political science, sociology and anthropology to understand social, political and commercial institutions. This literature tries to explain what institutions are, how they arise, what purposes they serve, how they change and how they may be reformed. Following convention, I distinguish between the institutional environment (the background constraints, or ‘rules of the game’, that guide individuals’ behavior) and institutional arrangements (specific guidelines designed by trading partners to facilitate particular exchanges). In both cases, the discussion here focuses on applications, evidence and policy implications. JEL classification: D23, D72, L22, L42, O17 Keywords: Institutions, Firms, Transaction Costs, Specific Assets, Governance Structures 1. Introduction The new institutional economics (NIE) is an interdisciplinary enterprise combining economics, law, organization theory, political science, sociology and anthropology to understand the institutions of social, political and commercial life. It borrows liberally from various social-science disciplines, but its primary language is economics. Its goal is to explain what institutions are, how they arise, what purposes they serve, how they change and how - if at all - they should be reformed. This essay surveys the wide-ranging and rapidly growing literature on the economics of institutions, with an emphasis on applications and evidence. The survey is divided into eight sections: the institutional environment; institutional arrangements and the theory of the firm; moral hazard and agency; transaction cost economics; capabilities and the core competence of the firm; evidence on contracts, organizations and institutions; public policy implications and influence; and a brief summary.
    [Show full text]
  • Market Structures
    Market Structures Lesson Goal: In this lesson, you will learn the characteristics of the 4 types of market ​ structures: perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly. You ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ will also learn how the government intervenes in the market to protect competition. Directions: Read the notes below CLOSELY for understanding, and follow the prompts ​ given to you throughout the lesson. For example, if I ask you to pause and watch a video and take notes, pause and watch the video. Open a Google Doc and take notes as you work. WHEN the whole lesson is finished, share your completed Google Doc with me. NOTES #1 Perfect Competition The simplest market structure is known as perfect competition. It is also called pure ​ ​ competition. A perfectly competitive market is one with a large number of firms all producing essentially the same product. Pure competition assumes that the market is in equilibrium and that all firms sell the same product for the same price. However, each firm produces so little of the product compared to the total supply that no single firm can hope to influence prices. The only decision such producers can make is how much to produce, given their production costs and the market price. Four Conditions for Perfect Competition While very few industries meet all of the conditions for perfect competition, some come close. For example, markets for many farm products and the stocks traded on the New York Stock Exchange meet the conditions for perfect competition. The 4 conditions are: 1. Many buyers and sellers participate in the market. 2. Sellers offer identical products.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding and Maximizing America's Evolutionary Economy
    UNDERSTANDING AND MAXIMIZING AMERICA’S EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMY ITIF The Information Technology & Innovation Foundation DR. ROBERT D. ATKINSON i UNDERSTANDING AND MAXIMIZING AMERICA’S EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMY DR. ROBERT D. ATKINSON OCTOBER 2014 DR. ROBERT D. ATKINSON ITIF The Information Technology & Innovation Foundation In the conventional view, the U.S. economy is a static entity, changing principally only in size (growing in normal times and contracting during recessions). But in reality, our economy is a constantly evolving complex ecosystem. The U.S. economy of 2014 is different, not just larger, than the economy of 2013. Understanding that we are dealing with an evolutionary rather than static economy has significant implications for the conceptu- alization of both economics and economic policy. Unfortunately, the two major economic doctrines that guide U.S. policymakers’ thinking—neoclassical economics and neo-Keynesian economics—are rooted in overly simplistic models of how the economy works and therefore generate flawed policy solutions. Because these doctrines emphasize the “economy as machine” model, policymakers have developed a mechanical view of policy; if they pull a lever (e.g., implement a regulation, program, or tax policy), they will get an expected result. In actuality, economies are complex evolutionary systems, which means en- abling and ensuring robust rates of evolution requires much more than the standard menu of favored options blessed by the prevailing doctrines: limiting government (for conservatives), protecting worker and “consumer” welfare (for liberals), and smoothing business cycles (for both). As economies evolve, so too do doctrines Any new economic and governing systems. After WWII when the framework for America’s United States was shifting from what Michael “fourth republic” needs Lind calls the second republic (the post-Civil War governance system) to the third republic to be grounded in an (the post-New-Deal, Great Society governance evolutionary understanding.
    [Show full text]
  • Fintech and Market Structure in Financial Services
    FinTech and market structure in financial services: Market developments and potential financial stability implications 14 February 2019 The Financial Stability Board (FSB) is established to coordinate at the international level the work of national financial authorities and international standard-setting bodies in order to develop and promote the implementation of effective regulatory, supervisory and other financial sector policies. Its mandate is set out in the FSB Charter, which governs the policymaking and related activities of the FSB. These activities, including any decisions reached in their context, shall not be binding or give rise to any legal rights or obligations under the FSB’s Articles of Association. Contacting the Financial Stability Board Sign up for e-mail alerts: www.fsb.org/emailalert Follow the FSB on Twitter: @FinStbBoard E-mail the FSB at: [email protected] Copyright © 2019 Financial Stability Board. Please refer to: www.fsb.org/terms_conditions/ Table of Contents Page Executive summary .................................................................................................................... 1 1. Background and definitions ............................................................................................... 3 2. Financial innovation and links to market structure ............................................................ 5 2.1 Supply factors – technological developments ............................................................ 6 2.2 Supply factors – regulation .......................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • New Institutional Economics
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by University of Missouri: MOspace 0530 NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS Peter G. Klein Department of Economics, University of Georgia © Copyright 1999 Peter G. Klein Abstract This chapter surveys the new institutional economics, a rapidly growing literature combining economics, law, organization theory, political science, sociology and anthropology to understand social, political and commercial institutions. This literature tries to explain what institutions are, how they arise, what purposes they serve, how they change and how they may be reformed. Following convention, I distinguish between the institutional environment (the background constraints, or ‘rules of the game’, that guide individuals’ behavior) and institutional arrangements (specific guidelines designed by trading partners to facilitate particular exchanges). In both cases, the discussion here focuses on applications, evidence and policy implications. JEL classification: D23, D72, L22, L42, O17 Keywords: Institutions, Firms, Transaction Costs, Specific Assets, Governance Structures 1. Introduction The new institutional economics (NIE) is an interdisciplinary enterprise combining economics, law, organization theory, political science, sociology and anthropology to understand the institutions of social, political and commercial life. It borrows liberally from various social-science disciplines, but its primary language is economics. Its goal is to explain what institutions are, how they arise,
    [Show full text]
  • Ans. Meaning of Market: Ordinarily, the Term ―Market‖ Refers to a Particular Place Where Goods Are Purchased and Sold
    MODULE=III Q.1.Explain different market structure & their characterstics. Ans. Meaning of Market: Ordinarily, the term ―market‖ refers to a particular place where goods are purchased and sold. But, in economics, market is used in a wide perspective. In economics, the term ―market‖ does not mean a particular place but the whole area where the buyers and sellers of a product are spread. This is because in the present age the sale and purchase of goods are with the help of agents and samples. Hence, the sellers and buyers of a particular commodity are spread over a large area. The transactions for commodities may be also through letters, telegrams, telephones, internet, etc. Thus, market in economics does not refer to a particular market place but the entire region in which goods are bought and sold. In these transactions, the price of a commodity is the same in the whole market. According to Prof. R. Chapman, ―The term market refers not necessarily to a place but always to a commodity and the buyers and sellers who are in direct competition with one another.‖ In the words of A.A. Cournot, ―Economists understand by the term ‗market‘, not any particular place in which things are bought and sold but the whole of any region in which buyers and sellers are in such free intercourse with one another that the price of the same goods tends to equality, easily and quickly.‖ Prof. Cournot‘s definition is wider and appropriate in which all the features of a market are found. Contents : 1. Meaning of Market 2.
    [Show full text]