The Two-Piece Normal, Binormal, Or Double Gaussian Distribution

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Two-Piece Normal, Binormal, Or Double Gaussian Distribution Statistical Science 2014, Vol. 29, No. 1, 106–112 DOI: 10.1214/13-STS417 c Institute of Mathematical Statistics, 2014 The Two-Piece Normal, Binormal, or Double Gaussian Distribution: Its Origin and Rediscoveries Kenneth F. Wallis Abstract. This paper traces the history of the two-piece normal distri- bution from its origin in the posthumous Kollektivmasslehre (1897) of Gustav Theodor Fechner to its rediscoveries and generalisations. The denial of Fechner’s originality by Karl Pearson, reiterated a century later by Oscar Sheynin, is shown to be without foundation. Key words and phrases: Gustav Theodor Fechner, Gottlob Friedrich Lipps, Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, Karl Pearson, Francis Galton, Oscar Sheynin. 1. INTRODUCTION tics (Johnson and Kotz (1970)), in which the two- piece normal distribution made no appearance, un- The two-piece normal distribution came to pub- der this or any other name. On the contrary, the lic attention in the late 1990s, when the Bank of distribution was originally introduced in Fechner’s England and the Sveriges Riksbank began to pub- Kollektivmasslehre (1897) as the Zweispaltiges or lish probability forecasts of future inflation, using Zweiseitige Gauss’sche Gesetz. In his monumental this distribution to represent the possibility that the history of statistics, Hald (1998) prefers the latter balance of risks around the central forecast might name, which translates as the “two-sided Gaussian not be symmetric. The forecast probabilities that law,” and refers to it as “the Fechner distribution” future inflation would fall in given intervals could (page 378). However Fechner’s claim to originality be conveniently calculated by scaling standard nor- had been disputed by Pearson (1905), whose denial mal probabilities, and the resulting density forecasts of Fechner’s originality has recently been repeated were visualised in the famous forecast fan charts. by Sheynin (2004). In this paper we reappraise the In both cases the authors of the supporting tech- source and nature of the various claims, and record arXiv:1405.4995v1 [stat.ME] 20 May 2014 nical documentation (Britton, Fisher and Whitley, several rediscoveries of the distribution and exten- 1998; Blix and Sellin (1998)) refer readers to John- sions of Fechner’s basic ideas. As a prelude to the son, Kotz and Balakrishnan (1994) for discussion of discussion, there follows a brief technical introduc- the distribution. These last authors state (page 173) tion to the distribution. that “the distribution was originally introduced by A random variable X has a two-piece normal Gibbons and Mylroie (1973),” a reference that post- distribution with parameters µ,σ1 and σ2 if it has dates the first edition of Distributions in Statis- probability density function (PDF) 2 2 Kenneth F. Wallis is Emeritus Professor of A exp[ (x µ) /2σ1], x µ, Econometrics, Department of Economics, University of (1) f(x)= − − 2 2 ≤ A exp[ (x µ) /2σ2], x µ, Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL, United Kingdom e-mail: − − ≥ −1 [email protected]. where A = (√2π(σ1 + σ2)/2) . The distribution is This is an electronic reprint of the original article formed by taking the left half of a normal distribu- published by the Institute of Mathematical Statistics in tion with parameters (µ,σ1) and the right half of Statistical Science, 2014, Vol. 29, No. 1, 106–112. This a normal distribution with parameters (µ,σ2), and reprint differs from the original in pagination and scaling them to give the common value f(µ)= A at typographic detail. the mode, µ, as in (1). The scaling factor applied to 1 2 K. F. WALLIS −1 −1 quantiles xp = F (p) and zp =Φ (p). Then in the left piece of the distribution we have xα = σ1zβ + µ, where β = α(σ1 + σ2)/2σ1. And in the right piece of the distribution, defining quantiles with reference to their upper tail probabilities, we have x1−α = σ2z1−δ + µ, where δ = α(σ1 + σ2)/2σ2. In particu- lar, with σ1 <σ2, as in Figure 1, the median of the −1 distribution is x0.5 = σ2Φ (1 (σ1 + σ2)/4σ2)+ µ. In this case the three central− values are ordered mean>median>mode; with negative skewness this order is reversed. Although the two-piece normal PDF is continuous at µ, its first derivative is not and the second deriva- Fig. 1. The probability density function of the two-piece nor- tive has a break at µ, as first noted by Ranke and mal distribution. Dashed line: left half of N(µ, σ1) and right Greiner (1904). This has the disadvantage of making half of N(µ, σ2) distributions with µ = 2.5 and σ1 <σ2. Solid line: the two-piece normal distribution. standard asymptotic likelihood theory inapplicable, nevertheless standard asymptotic results are avail- able by direct proof for the specific example. the left half of the N(µ,σ1) PDF is 2σ1/(σ1 + σ2) The remainder of this paper is organised as fol- while that applied to the right half of N(µ,σ2) is lows. In Section 2 we revisit the distribution’s origin 2σ2/(σ1 + σ2), so the probability mass under the in Gustav Theodor Fechner’s Kollektivmasslehre, left or right piece is σ1/(σ1 + σ2) or σ2/(σ1 + σ2), edited by Gottlob Friedrich Lipps and published in respectively. An example with σ1 <σ2, in which the 1897, ten years after Fechner’s death. In Section 3 we two-piece normal distribution is positively skewed, note an early rediscovery, two years later, by Fran- is shown in Figure 1. The skewness becomes extreme cis Ysidro Edgeworth. In Section 4 we turn to the as σ1 0 and the distribution collapses to the half- normal→ distribution, while the skewness is reduced first discussion in the English language of Fechner’s contribution, in a characteristically long and argu- as σ1 σ2, reaching zero when σ1 = σ2 and the dis- tribution→ is again the normal distribution. mentative article by Karl Pearson (1905). Pearson The mean and variance of the distribution are derives some properties of “Fechner’s double Gaus- sian curve,” but asserts that it is “historically in- 2 (2) E(X)= µ + (σ2 σ1), correct to attribute [it] to Fechner.” We re-examine rπ − Pearson’s evidence in support of this position, in 2 2 particular having in mind its reappearance in Os- (3) var(X)= 1 (σ2 σ1) + σ1σ2. − π − car Sheynin’s (2004) appraisal of Fechner’s statis- tical work. Pearson also argues that “the curve is Expressions for the third and fourth moments about not general enough,” especially in comparison with the mean are increasingly complicated and unin- his family of curves. The overall result was that the formative. Skewness is more readily interpreted in Fechner distribution was overlooked for some time, terms of the ratio of the areas under the two pieces to the extent that there have been several indepen- of the PDF, which is σ1/σ2, or a monotone transfor- dent rediscoveries of the distribution in more recent mation thereof such as (σ2 σ1)/(σ2 + σ1), which is years; these are noted in Section 5, together with the value taken by the skewness− measure of Arnold some extensions. and Groeneveld (1995). With only three parameters there is a one-to-one relation between (the absolute 2. THE ORIGINATORS: FECHNER AND value of) skewness and kurtosis. The conventional LIPPS moment-based measure of kurtosis, β2, ranges from 3 (symmetry) to 3.8692 (the half-normal extreme Gustav Theodor Fechner (1801–1887) is known as asymmetry), hence the distribution is leptokurtic. the founder of psychophysics, the study of the re- Quantiles of the distribution can be conveniently lation between psychological sensation and physi- obtained by scaling the appropriate standard nor- cal stimulus, through his 1860 book Elemente der mal quantiles. For the respective cumulative distri- Psychophysik. Stigler’s (1986, pages 242–254) as- bution functions (CDFs) F (x) and Φ(z) we define sessment of this “landmark” contribution concludes THE TWO-PIECE NORMAL DISTRIBUTION 3 that “at a stroke, Fechner had created a method- the use of the Gaussian distribution to calculate the ology for a new quantitative psychology.” However, probability of an observation falling in a given inter- his final work, Kollektivmasslehre, is devoted more val. The measure of location is the arithmetic mean, generally to the study of mass phenomena and the A, and the measure of dispersion is the mean abso- search for empirical regularities therein, with ex- lute deviation, ε (related to the standard deviation, amples of frequency distributions taken from many in the Gaussian distribution, by ε = σ 2/π). Ta- fields, including aesthetics, anthropology, astron- bles of the standard normal distributionp are not yet omy, botany, meteorology and zoology. In his Fore- available, and his calculations proceed via the error word, Fechner mentions the long gestation period function (see Stigler (1986), pages 246–248, e.g.), of the book, and states its main objective as the and prove to be remarkably accurate. establishment of a generalisation of the Gaussian In previous work Fechner had introduced other law of random errors, to overcome its limitations of “main values” of a frequency distribution, the Zen- symmetric probabilities and relatively small positive tralwert or “central value” C, and the Dichteste and negative deviations from the arithmetic mean. Wert or “densest value” D, subsequently known He also appeals to astronomical and statistical in- in English as the median and the mode. Arguing stitutes to use their mechanical calculation powers that the equality of A, C and D is the exception to produce accurate tables of the Gaussian distri- rather than the rule, he next introduces the Zweis- bution, which he had desperately missed during his paltiges Gauss’sche Gesetz to represent this asym- work on the book.
Recommended publications
  • F:\RSS\Me\Society's Mathemarica
    School of Social Sciences Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Mathematics in the Statistical Society 1883-1933 John Aldrich No. 0919 This paper is available on our website http://www.southampton.ac.uk/socsci/economics/research/papers ISSN 0966-4246 Mathematics in the Statistical Society 1883-1933* John Aldrich Economics Division School of Social Sciences University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ UK e-mail: [email protected] Abstract This paper considers the place of mathematical methods based on probability in the work of the London (later Royal) Statistical Society in the half-century 1883-1933. The end-points are chosen because mathematical work started to appear regularly in 1883 and 1933 saw the formation of the Industrial and Agricultural Research Section– to promote these particular applications was to encourage mathematical methods. In the period three movements are distinguished, associated with major figures in the history of mathematical statistics–F. Y. Edgeworth, Karl Pearson and R. A. Fisher. The first two movements were based on the conviction that the use of mathematical methods could transform the way the Society did its traditional work in economic/social statistics while the third movement was associated with an enlargement in the scope of statistics. The study tries to synthesise research based on the Society’s archives with research on the wider history of statistics. Key names : Arthur Bowley, F. Y. Edgeworth, R. A. Fisher, Egon Pearson, Karl Pearson, Ernest Snow, John Wishart, G. Udny Yule. Keywords : History of Statistics, Royal Statistical Society, mathematical methods.
    [Show full text]
  • MODES for Windows Print
    Marshall Library of Economics Marshall Papers Section 9 Autobiography and personal honours Identity code Marshall 9 Description level 3 Content Summary This diverse section contains the few remaining biographical notes by Alfred, longer notes on Alfred by Mary Marshall, lists of recipients of complimentary copies of Marshall's books and subscribers to his portrait fund, his academic honours, a large scrapbook of newspaper cuttings about Alfred's career kept by Mary and her album of watercolour paintings of places visited on European travels Identity code Marshall 9/1 Previous number Marshall LBB 34 (part) [uncertain attribution] Description level 4 Record creation Person Role writer Name Marshall, Alfred Date undated Document form Record type notes Specific type autobiographical Acquisition Summary Possibly a late accession as formerly in Large Brown Box Content Summary Single page annotated 'Reminiscences' down left side by Marshall. Recounts how when at school was told not to take account of accents in pronouncing Greek words and therefore decided to save time by not learning them or using them in written work. The result was he received the only very heavy punishment of his life. 'This suggested to me that classical studies do not induce an appreciation of the value of time; and I turned away from them as far as I could towards mathematics'. Summary In later years he has observed that fine students of science are greedy of time, whereas many classical men value it lightly. Is most grateful to his headmaster [Revd James Augustus Hessey] for making him think out essays in Latin. Person Name Hessey, James Augustus, Revd Subject keywords Physical descript Summary 1 p.
    [Show full text]
  • THE HISTORY and DEVELOPMENT of STATISTICS in BELGIUM by Dr
    THE HISTORY AND DEVELOPMENT OF STATISTICS IN BELGIUM By Dr. Armand Julin Director-General of the Belgian Labor Bureau, Member of the International Statistical Institute Chapter I. Historical Survey A vigorous interest in statistical researches has been both created and facilitated in Belgium by her restricted terri- tory, very dense population, prosperous agriculture, and the variety and vitality of her manufacturing interests. Nor need it surprise us that the successive governments of Bel- gium have given statistics a prominent place in their affairs. Baron de Reiffenberg, who published a bibliography of the ancient statistics of Belgium,* has given a long list of docu- ments relating to the population, agriculture, industry, commerce, transportation facilities, finance, army, etc. It was, however, chiefly the Austrian government which in- creased the number of such investigations and reports. The royal archives are filled to overflowing with documents from that period of our history and their very over-abun- dance forms even for the historian a most diflScult task.f With the French domination (1794-1814), the interest for statistics did not diminish. Lucien Bonaparte, Minister of the Interior from 1799-1800, organized in France the first Bureau of Statistics, while his successor, Chaptal, undertook to compile the statistics of the departments. As far as Belgium is concerned, there were published in Paris seven statistical memoirs prepared under the direction of the prefects. An eighth issue was not finished and a ninth one * Nouveaux mimoires de I'Acadimie royale des sciences et belles lettres de Bruxelles, t. VII. t The Archives of the kingdom and the catalogue of the van Hulthem library, preserved in the Biblioth^que Royale at Brussells, offer valuable information on this head.
    [Show full text]
  • This History of Modern Mathematical Statistics Retraces Their Development
    BOOK REVIEWS GORROOCHURN Prakash, 2016, Classic Topics on the History of Modern Mathematical Statistics: From Laplace to More Recent Times, Hoboken, NJ, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 754 p. This history of modern mathematical statistics retraces their development from the “Laplacean revolution,” as the author so rightly calls it (though the beginnings are to be found in Bayes’ 1763 essay(1)), through the mid-twentieth century and Fisher’s major contribution. Up to the nineteenth century the book covers the same ground as Stigler’s history of statistics(2), though with notable differences (see infra). It then discusses developments through the first half of the twentieth century: Fisher’s synthesis but also the renewal of Bayesian methods, which implied a return to Laplace. Part I offers an in-depth, chronological account of Laplace’s approach to probability, with all the mathematical detail and deductions he drew from it. It begins with his first innovative articles and concludes with his philosophical synthesis showing that all fields of human knowledge are connected to the theory of probabilities. Here Gorrouchurn raises a problem that Stigler does not, that of induction (pp. 102-113), a notion that gives us a better understanding of probability according to Laplace. The term induction has two meanings, the first put forward by Bacon(3) in 1620, the second by Hume(4) in 1748. Gorroochurn discusses only the second. For Bacon, induction meant discovering the principles of a system by studying its properties through observation and experimentation. For Hume, induction was mere enumeration and could not lead to certainty. Laplace followed Bacon: “The surest method which can guide us in the search for truth, consists in rising by induction from phenomena to laws and from laws to forces”(5).
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 1: What Is Statistics? Christopher J
    Chapter 1: What is Statistics? Christopher J. Wild, Jessica M. Utts, and Nicholas J. Horton Christopher J. Wild University of Auckland, New Zealand President, American Statistical Association Jessica M. Utts University of California, Irvine, United States Chair, Statistical Education Section, ASA Nicholas J. Horton Amherst College, United States e-mail: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] Abstract What is Statistics? We attempt to answer this question as it relates to grounding research in statistics education. We discuss the nature of statistics (the science of learning from data), its history and traditions, what characterises statistical thinking and how it differs from mathematics, connections with computing and data science, why learning statistics is essential, and what is most important. Finally, we attempt to gaze into the future, drawing upon what is known about the fast-growing demand for statistical skills and the portents of where the discipline is heading, especially those arising from data science and the promises and problems of big data. Key Words Discipline of statistics; Statistical thinking; Value of statistics; Statistical fundamentals; Decision making; Trends in statistical practice; Data science; Computational thinking 1.1 Introduction In this, the opening chapter of the International Handbook of Research in Statistics Education, we ask the question, “What is statistics?” This question is not considered in isolation, however, but in the context of grounding research in statistics education. Educational endeavour in statistics can be divided very broadly into “What?” and “How?” The “What?” deals with the nature and extent of the discipline to be conveyed, whereas any consideration of “How?” (including “When?”) brings into play a host of additional factors, such as cognition and learning theories, audience and readiness, attitudes, social interactions with teachers and other students, and learning and assessment strategies and systems.
    [Show full text]
  • A Complete Bibliography of Publications in Biometrika for the Decade 1960–1969
    A Complete Bibliography of Publications in Biometrika for the decade 1960{1969 Nelson H. F. Beebe University of Utah Department of Mathematics, 110 LCB 155 S 1400 E RM 233 Salt Lake City, UT 84112-0090 USA Tel: +1 801 581 5254 FAX: +1 801 581 4148 E-mail: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] (Internet) WWW URL: http://www.math.utah.edu/~beebe/ 19 May 2021 Version 1.02 Title word cross-reference #4315 [Har79]. 0 · 1 [dVW66]. 2 × 2 [BH60a, BH61a, OI61a, OI61b, Pla64]. 50 [Bar66d]. k [Bur60b]. A [Hol66, Mar63]. A + B [Mar63]. b2 [Pea65b]. β [Mos62]. β2 [JNAP63, JNAP65]. χ [JP69, JP70]. χ2 2 [Hit62, MA65, Put64, Tik65b, Wis63a, Wis63b, You62]. χr [Sen67]. d [dVW66]. Ek=M=1 [Bur60c]. [RK69a]. exp(−a)+ka = 1 [BDM60]. exp(b) − b=(1 − p) = 1 [BDM63]. F [Ati62, BDO60, CB63, CB66, GS62b, PB61, Pri64a, SZ60, Tik65b, Tik66]. GI=G=1 [Kin62]. GI=M=1 [Fin60a]. k [DG68a, Kor69, Maa66]. M [Har69a, Pea69, Cro61, Lin60]. M=M=1 [GS65]. X2 [Wis63a, Wis63b]. N [Gil65, Hai65b, ST66, Arc62, Arc64, Hof63]. p [Rao68b, Rao69]. Q [Gow66a]. 3 2 2 R [Mil65a]. ρ [Sno63]. S [Bur60a, Bar66d].p s = 1 [Bar66d].p smax=s0 2 2 [Cha67a]. SU [Joh65b]. σB/σ [Sis68]. b1 [Pea65b]. β1 [JNAP63]. 1 2 P m p 0 f(Yt) [Con65]. β1 [JNAP65]. t [Amo64, FKM67, GJ68, Haj61, HPW61, Joh61, MSA66, Owe65, SA62a, Sis64]. 2 2 2 2 T0 [IS64]. U [Maa66]. UM;N [Ste65b]. UN [PS62b, Ste63a, Ste64, Tik65a]. (s) 2 2 V1 [Bar66d]. VN [Ste65a].
    [Show full text]
  • 1 the MAKING of INDEX NUMBERS in the EARLY 1920S
    THE MAKING OF INDEX NUMBERS IN THE EARLY 1920s: A CLOSER LOOK AT THE FISHER–MITCHELL DEBATE Felipe Almeida Victor Cruz e Silva Universidade Federal do Paraná Universidade Estadual de Ponta Grossa Área 1 - História do Pensamento Econômico e Metodologia RESUMO O surgimento sistemático da abordagem axiomática dos números de índice ocorreu no início dos anos 1920, um período marcado pelo pluralismo na academia econômic estadunidense. Promovida por Irving Fisher, a abordagem axiomática dos números de índice teve como objetivo selecionar uma fórmula ideal universalmente válida para números de índice, empregando uma série de testes estatísticos. No entanto, desde a primeira apresentação da abordagem de Fisher, no Encontro Anual da Associação Estadunidense de Estatística em 1920, até a publicação de seu livro “The Making of Index Numbers” em 1922, Fisher enfrentou uma série de críticas, não endereçadas à sua fórmula ideal propriamente dita, mas à própria idéia de uma fórmula universal para números de índice. Os principais indivíduos envolvidos nesse debate foram Wesley Mitchell, Warren Persons, Correa Walsh (que foi o único que apoiou a proposta de Fisher) e Allyn Young. Entre eles, o principal representante dos antagonistas de Fisher era Mitchell. Este estudo argumenta que as divergências entre Fisher e Mitchell resultam de seus distintos entendimentos da economia como uma "ciência". Portanto, o objetivo deste estudo é ilustrar como Fisher, como economista matemático, privilegiou a universalidade das teorias econômicas, enquanto Mitchell, como institucionalista, entendeu a economia como uma disciplina contextual e histórica e como essas preconcepções estão presentes no debate sobre números de índice. Para ilustrar suas posições, este estudo explora evidências baseadas em arquivo.
    [Show full text]
  • AN INVESTIGATION INTO the FORMATION of CONSENSUS AROUND NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS in the 1950S
    THE ECLIPSE OF INSTITUTIONALISM? AN INVESTIGATION INTO THE FORMATION OF CONSENSUS AROUND NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS IN THE 1950s A Dissertation Submitted to the Temple University Graduate Board In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy By Julie Ragatz May, 2019 Committee Members: Dr. Miriam Solomon, Department of Philosophy Dr. David Wolfsdorf, Department of Philosophy Dr. Dimitrios Diamantaras, Department of Economics Dr. Matthew Lund, Department of Philosophy, Rowan University, External Reader © Copyright 2019 by Julie Ragatz Norton All Rights Reserved ii ABSTRACT The Eclipse of Institutionalism? An Investigation into the Formation of Consensus Around Neoclassical Economics in the 1950s Julie Ragatz Norton Temple University, 2019 Doctoral Advisory Committee Chair: Dr. Miriam Solomon As the discipline of economics professionalized during the interwar period, two schools of thought emerged: institutionalism and neoclassical economics. By 1954, after the publication of Arrow and Debreu’s landmark article on general equilibrium theory, consensus formed around neoclassical economics. This outcome was significantly influenced by trends in the philosophy of science, notably the transformation from the logical empiricism of the Vienna Circle to an ‘Americanized’ version of logical empiricism that was dominant through the 1950s. This version of logical empiricism provided a powerful ally to neoclassical economics by affirming its philosophical and methodological commitments as examples of “good science”. This dissertation explores this process of consensus formation by considering whether consensus would be judged normatively appropriate from the perspective of three distinct approaches to the philosophy of science; Carl Hempel’s logical empiricism, Thomas Kuhn’s account of theory change and Helen Longino’s critical contextual empiricism.
    [Show full text]
  • Francis Ysidro Edgeworth
    Francis Ysidro Edgeworth Previous (Francis Xavier) (/entry/Francis_Xavier) Next (Francis of Assisi) (/entry/Francis_of_Assisi) Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (February 8, 1845 – February 13, 1926) was an Irish (/entry/Ireland) polymath, a highly influential figure in the development of neo­ classical economics, and contributor to the development of statistical theory. He was the first to apply certain formal mathematical techniques to individual decision making in economics. Edgeworth developed utility theory, introducing the indifference curve and the famous "Edgeworth box," which have become standards in economic theory. He is also known for the "Edgeworth conjecture" which states that the core of an economy shrinks to the set of competitive equilibria as the number of agents in the economy gets large. The high degree of originality demonstrated in his most important book on economics, Mathematical Psychics, was matched only by the difficulty in reading it. A deep thinker, his contributions were far ahead of his time and continue to inform the fields of (/entry/File:Edgeworth.jpeg) microeconomics (/entry/Microeconomics) and areas such as welfare economics. Francis Y. Edgeworth Thus, Edgeworth's work has advanced our understanding of economic relationships among traders, and thus contributes to the establishment of a better society for all. Life Contents Ysidro Francis Edgeworth (the order of his given names was later reversed) 1 Life was born on February 8, 1845 in Edgeworthstown, Ireland (/entry/Ireland), into 2 Work a large and wealthy landowning family. His aunt was the famous novelist Maria 2.1 Edgeworth conjecture Edgeworth, who wrote the Castle Rackrent. He was educated by private tutors 2.2 Edgeworth Box until 1862, when he went on to study classics and languages at Trinity College, 2.3 Edgeworth limit theorem Dublin.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of the Design of Experiments
    The Theory of the Design of Experiments D.R. COX Honorary Fellow Nuffield College Oxford, UK AND N. REID Professor of Statistics University of Toronto, Canada CHAPMAN & HALL/CRC Boca Raton London New York Washington, D.C. C195X/disclaimer Page 1 Friday, April 28, 2000 10:59 AM Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Cox, D. R. (David Roxbee) The theory of the design of experiments / D. R. Cox, N. Reid. p. cm. — (Monographs on statistics and applied probability ; 86) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 1-58488-195-X (alk. paper) 1. Experimental design. I. Reid, N. II.Title. III. Series. QA279 .C73 2000 001.4 '34 —dc21 00-029529 CIP This book contains information obtained from authentic and highly regarded sources. Reprinted material is quoted with permission, and sources are indicated. A wide variety of references are listed. Reasonable efforts have been made to publish reliable data and information, but the author and the publisher cannot assume responsibility for the validity of all materials or for the consequences of their use. Neither this book nor any part may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, microfilming, and recording, or by any information storage or retrieval system, without prior permission in writing from the publisher. The consent of CRC Press LLC does not extend to copying for general distribution, for promotion, for creating new works, or for resale. Specific permission must be obtained in writing from CRC Press LLC for such copying. Direct all inquiries to CRC Press LLC, 2000 N.W.
    [Show full text]
  • INFORMATION to USERS the Most Advanced Technology Has Been Used to Photo­ Graph and Reproduce This Manuscript from the Microfilm Master
    INFORMATION TO USERS The most advanced technology has been used to photo­ graph and reproduce this manuscript from the microfilm master. UMI films the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, some thesis and dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of computer printer. The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are re­ produced by sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left-hand comer and continuing from left to right in equal sections with small overlaps. Each original is also photographed in one exposure and is included in reduced form at the back of the book. These are also available as one exposure on a standard 35mm slide or as a 17" x 23" black and white photographic print for an additional charge. Photographs included in the original manuscript have been reproduced xerographically in this copy. Higher quality 6" x 9" black and white photographic prints are available for any photographs or illustrations appearing in this copy for an additional charge. Contact UMI directly to order. UMI University Microfilms International A Bell & Howell Information Company 3 00 Nortfi Z eeb Road, Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 USA 313/761-4700 800/521-0600 Order Number 9011133 Sudden leaps: The young Alfred Marshall Butler, Robert William, Ph.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources
    Yale University EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers Cowles Foundation 1-1-2018 Who Gets What, When, How? Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources Martin Shubik Follow this and additional works at: https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/cowles-discussion-paper-series Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Shubik, Martin, "Who Gets What, When, How? Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources" (2018). Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers. 158. https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/cowles-discussion-paper-series/158 This Discussion Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Cowles Foundation at EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers by an authorized administrator of EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale. For more information, please contact [email protected]. WHO GETS WHAT, WHEN, HOW? POWER, ORGANIZATION, MARKETS, MONEY AND THE ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES By Martin Shubik January 2018 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 2118 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 http://cowles.yale.edu/ WHO GETS WHAT, WHEN, HOW? Power, Organization, Markets, Money and the Allocation of Resources Martin Shubik © Copyright Martin Shubik, 2015 1 Contents Preface Acknowledgments 1 The Emergence of Civilization with Money and Financial Institutions
    [Show full text]