Strategic Five-Year State Workforce Investment Plan 2012-2017

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Strategic Five-Year State Workforce Investment Plan 2012-2017 STRATEGIC FIVE-YEAR STATE WORKFORCE INVESTMENT PLAN FOR TITLE I OF THE WORKFORCE INVESTMENT ACT OF 1998 (WORKFORCE INVESTMENT SYSTEM) AND THE WAGNER-PEYSER ACT STATE OF CONNECTICUT for the period of July 1, 2012 to June 30, 2017 1 State of Connecticut Strategic Five-Year State Workforce Investment Plan July 1, 2012 – June 30, 2017 Table of Contents I. State Workforce Strategic Plan II. State Operational Plan III. Integrated Workforce Plan Assurances and Attachments 2 I. State Workforce Strategic Plan 3 WIA Strategic Five-Year State Workforce Investment Plan Section I. A. Governor’s Vision: This portion of the Integrated Workforce Plan must describe the governor’s strategic vision for the state’s economy and overarching goals for the state’s workforce system. This vision should provide the strategic direction for the state workforce system and guide investments in workforce preparation, skill development, education and training, and major initiatives supporting the governor’s vision. The plan also must specifically address the governor’s vision for aligning efforts among workforce development partners to achieve accessible, seamless, integrated, and comprehensive service, and how programs and activities described in the plan will support the state’s economic development needs and the employment and training needs of all working-age youth and adults in the state. The plan must include a description of the methods used for joint planning, and coordination of the programs and activities included in the plan. Shortly after taking office in January 2011 Governor Malloy asserted as a priority his expectation that, building on a proud heritage, CT would create and sustain the global economy‘s best-educated, most-skilled, most-productive workforce. The Governor embraced the fundamental importance of talent as the essential resource in state efforts to grow the economy and shared prosperity for all. In ensuing months, under the Governor‘s leadership, the General Assembly adopted several major, inter-connected, innovative, structural policy initiatives that, taken together, create the strong and necessary foundation in order to pursue the Governor‘s vision. Governor Malloy has provided essential leadership in championing several key policy initiatives to grow the economy and create new jobs, align higher education with economic priorities, prepare an educated future workforce, and integrate state efforts. These include: Passage of a $600,000,000 Jobs Bill which includes a comprehensive package of focused job growth/economic development investments intended to incentivize/stimulate job growth in several targeted industry sectors. Consolidation of previously disparate public higher-education institutions (community colleges and state universities) under a new Board of Regents for Higher Education/ConnSCU structure to align higher education policies, strategies, investments with State‘s economic development priorities, policies, strategies, investments. Reform of the state‘s K-12 public schools system, with a new emphasis on career exposure for all students as a core element of their total academic learning experience, and making high school diploma true credential for college and career readiness. In addition to these significant policy initiatives, the Governor has established through executive leadership and administrative action the expectation that the key state agencies significantly involved in developing and sustaining the talent of CT‘s people will cooperate and collaborate effectively to better align and integrate economic development, 4 education, human services and workforce development policy, investments, programs and services into a coherent state talent strategy. The Governor‘s key vehicle to accomplish this purposeful collaboration is the CT Employment and Training Commission (CETC). Under Governor Malloy‘s leadership CETC has been rebuilt and re-energized, charged to play the lead role in promoting efforts across multiple state agencies, programs, strategies and investments to meet the broad goal of developing and sustaining the best-educated, most-skilled, most-productive workforce in the world. CETC Planning Role and Focus Governor Malloy reorganized the Connecticut Employment and Training Commission (CETC) in 2011 to play a lead role in coordinating state efforts to meet the Governor‘s vision of building and sustaining in CT the global economy‘s best-educated, most-skilled, most-productive workforce. CETC membership includes leaders of each of the major agencies/institutions that collectively comprise the state‘s workforce/talent-development system. Overarching Goals To bring focus to that broad vision, CETC adopted four overarching goals as a broad framework for proposed policy and strategy, in each of four broad categories: Business Growth (Industry Sectors) – Connecticut businesses – particularly those in key industry sectors – will have access to the human resources and talent they need to compete effectively, prosper in Connecticut and create new jobs for Connecticut workers. Current Workforce – All Connecticut workers will have the skills and credentials they need to prosper and advance in careers that pay well and provide good benefits to support their families. Future Talent – All Connecticut youth will be ready for career and postsecondary success as productive contributors to a vibrant and competitive state economy. System Transformation – Connecticut‘s workforce/talent-development system will support a world-class workforce and competitive economy through aligned and integrated goals, strategies, policies, services and infrastructure whose performance is regularly monitored and results evaluated. For each of these goals CETC identified a set of indicators to monitor and assess how well CT is doing in comparison to relevant competitors. We need useful indicators to review on a regular basis to determine how well we are doing as a State in meeting these ambitious goals. What trends we see over time, the past 5-10 years, and what the trends suggest about future strategy. How we fare in comparison to other states, regions and nations against whom we compete. How well different segments of our population are doing, to ensure that we understand accurately the important underlying stories, to inform effective policy and strategy development. Performance Indicators CETC will use the following indicators to monitor and report on Connecticut‘s status in pursuing these overarching goals. 5 Business Growth (Industry Sectors): Readiness for the ―new economy‖. Competitive ranking in the New Economy Index. State per capita GDP State rate/ranking of fastest growing businesses Current Workforce: Percent of young adults (recent HS grads) that advance to post-secondary education Completion rate of post-secondary degree/credential programs by young adults (define) Percent (and number) of middle-skill job openings going unfilled Talent Pipeline: Percent of 4th graders reaching proficiency in reading on the NAEP1 Percent of 8th graders taking high school level math (beginning algebra) On-time high school graduation rate (4 years) Students - recent HS grads - able to qualify for credit-bearing college-level courses without requiring remediation or developmental instruction System Transformation: Number and percent of agencies linking data to provide strategic insight for public policy Timeliness of refreshing data for CT‘s workforce dashboard Percent of workers earning a living wage ($40,000 a year or more) As a general proposition, CETC believes that: CT must be ranked in the top 10% on each of these indicators in comparison to relevant national/international competition. If already in that top echelon, the trajectory in our performance should be upward, our performance must continue to advance. Stability or decline is unacceptable. The performance of all segments of our population is critical. Broad, seemingly positive statewide results that mask underlying challenges among certain groups must be understood and addressed. Section I.B. Economic and Workforce Information Analysis: The Integrated Workforce Plan must describe the labor market and economic context in which the state's workforce system (including all the programs in the Integrated Workforce Plan) is operating, based on accurate and timely labor-market, demographic, and economic information, with particular attention given to high-need, under-served, under- employed, and/or low-skilled subpopulations. (WIA Sections 112(b)(4), 112(b)(17)(A)(iv), 112(b)(18), W-P Sections 8(b) and 15.) This description should include an assessment of the needs of constituents within the state who will become, or currently comprise, the state’s workforce, particularly those needs which can be addressed by the programs included in the Integrated Workforce Plan. The state’s analysis of the current economy and future trends of the economy forms the foundation for strategic planning. For its analysis, the state may use the workforce information produced by the state workforce agency as well as other data available 1 National Assessment of Educational Progress, administered by the US Department of Education 6 from Federal, State, and Private sector sources, and informed by the business representatives of the State Workforce Investment Board (SWIB). Section I.B. i. An assessment of the current situation and projected trends of the state’s economy, industries and occupations, including major economic regions and industrial and occupational sectors Current makeup and projected demand for
Recommended publications
  • The Principle of Effective Demand and the State of Post Keynesian Monetary Economics
    The University of Adelaide School of Economics Research Paper No. 2008-04 The Principle of Effective Demand and the State of Post Keynesian Monetary Economics Colin Rogers The principle of effective demand and the state of post Keynesian monetary economics Colin Rogers (Revised 20/08/08) School of Economics University of Adelaide Introduction Keynesians of all shades have generally misunderstood the theoretical structure of the General Theory. What is missing is an appreciation of the principle of effective demand. As Laidler (1999) has documented, Old Keynesians largely fabricated the theoretical basis of the Keynesian Revolution and retained the `classical' analysis of long-period equilibrium. Old Keynesians generally took Frank Knight's (1937) advice to ignore the claim to revolution in economic theory and interpreted the General Theory as another contribution to the theory of business cycles. This is most obvious from the Old Keynesian reliance on wage rigidity to generate involuntary unemployment. But for Keynes (1936, chapter 19), wage and price stickiness is the `classical' explanation for unemployment to be contrasted with his explanation, in terms of the principle of effective demand, where the flexibility of wages and prices cannot automatically shift long-period equilibrium to full employment. New Keynesians have continued the `classical' vision by providing the microeconomic foundations for the `ad hoc' rigidities employed by Old 1 Keynesians. Generally, New Keynesians do not question the underlying `classical' vision. Post Keynesians have always questioned the `classical' vision but have not succeeded as yet in agreeing on what the principle of effective demand is1. There should, however, be no grounds for misunderstanding of the principle of effective demand given Keynes's exposition in the General Theory and Dillard's (1948) synopsis.
    [Show full text]
  • Dangers of Deflation Douglas H
    ERD POLICY BRIEF SERIES Economics and Research Department Number 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks Pilipinas F. Quising Asian Development Bank http://www.adb.org Asian Development Bank P.O. Box 789 0980 Manila Philippines 2002 by Asian Development Bank December 2002 ISSN 1655-5260 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ERD Policy Brief Series is based on papers or notes prepared by ADB staff and their resource persons. The series is designed to provide concise nontechnical accounts of policy issues of topical interest to ADB management, Board of Directors, and staff. Though prepared primarily for internal readership within the ADB, the series may be accessed by interested external readers. Feedback is welcome via e-mail ([email protected]). ERD POLICY BRIEF NO. 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks and Pilipinas F. Quising December 2002 ecently, there has been growing concern about deflation in some Rcountries and the possibility of deflation at the global level. Aggregate demand, output, and employment could stagnate or decline, particularly where debt levels are already high. Standard economic policy stimuli could become less effective, while few policymakers have experience in preventing or halting deflation with alternative means. Causes and Consequences of Deflation Deflation refers to a fall in prices, leading to a negative change in the price index over a sustained period. The fall in prices can result from improvements in productivity, advances in technology, changes in the policy environment (e.g., deregulation), a drop in prices of major inputs (e.g., oil), excess capacity, or weak demand.
    [Show full text]
  • The Living Wage in Iowa: the Effects on Families and Businesses
    Running Head: THE LIVING WAGE IN IOWA 1 The Living Wage in Iowa: the effects on families and businesses. Tracie Behr, Molly Driscoll, Hans Erickson, Tanya Kaenkumchorn, Jeff Pilz Drake University THE LIVING WAGE IN IOWA 2 Abstract This paper explores the cost of living in Iowa. The paper looks at nine communities throughout Iowa, both urban and rural, in calculating the cost of living in Iowa. This calculation is then used to determine what an average Iowan would need to be paid per hour to make a “living wage.” The paper then explores the effect of raising wages on businesses through looking at companies that currently pay minimum wage, companies that pay more than minimum wage but instead pay a “living wage”, and through a survey of the attitudes of small businesses in the nine Iowa communities. THE LIVING WAGE IN IOWA 3 The Living Wage in Iowa: The effects on families and businesses The Issue Currently there is debate going on at the local and national level related to raising the federal and state minimum wage. The President of the United States would like to raise the federal minimum wage to $10.10 per hour over a three-year period. Similarly, Iowa House Democrats recently introduced a bill to raise the state minimum wage to $10.10 per hour by January 2016 (Bulman, 2014). Proponents and opponents of raising the minimum wage vehemently defend their position as either a way that will bring people out of poverty and boost the economy or as a way to kill small business and raise the unemployment rate.
    [Show full text]
  • The National Living Wage and Falling Earnings Inequality
    The National Living Wage and falling earnings inequality Abigail McKnight and Kerris Cooper Contents Key findings Implications for policy and practice The National Minimum Wage and the National Living Wage Earnings inequality and the NMW/NLW Relationship between NMW/NLW and earnings at 10th percentile Minimum wages can reduce inequality when set high enough Data Appendix: Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings Acknowledgements About the publication and the authors CASEbrief 38 Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion March 2020 London School of Economics Houghton Street London WC2A 2AE CASE enquiries – tel: 020 7955 6679 Key findings • Inequality in weekly and hourly earnings has fallen since the introduction of the National Living Wage in April 2016. This is the first rapid fall since at least the late 1970s. • The replacement of the National Minimum Wage with the more generous National Living Wage for employees aged 25 and over has led to a compression in the lower half of the wage and weekly earnings distributions. • The National Living Wage now touches the 10th percentile of the wage distribution for all employees (which includes lower paid part- time employees) and the gap between the minimum wage rate and the 10th percentile of the wage distribution for full-time employees has narrowed markedly. Implications for policy and practice • Set high enough, with sufficient ‘bite’, minimum wages can be effective at reducing wage and earnings inequality. • Without a minimum wage (set either through collective bargaining or legislation), market set wages result in low paid workers being paid even lower rates. Increases in their wage rates, to rates approaching 60% of median pay, can be achieved without substantial loss of employment.
    [Show full text]
  • Addressing Inequality Through Wage Policy
    Addressing inequality through wage policy Manuela Tomei Director, WORKQUALITY ILO Geneva 1 Why use wage policy to reduce inequality? • In high-income countries, growing wage inequality has been the most important factor in the increase in inequality since the 1980s • In emerging countries where inequality has fallen in the last 15 years, such as in Brazil or Argentina, this was in part a result of reduced wage inequality • Social transfers can correct inequalities in part but do not address the source of the problem • So, both types of policies need to be combined 2 Wages as a proportion of household income (households with at least one member of working age) Developed WAGES are usually between 60% and 80% of total household income Emerging & developing WAGES are between 30% and 60% of total household income, depending on level of self-employment 3 The ILO has long regarded wage policy as an important tool for social justice • The ILO Constitution calls for “policies in regard to wages and earnings … designed to ensure a just share of the fruits of progress to all and a minimum living wage to all employed and in need of such protection”. This call was repeated in the 2008 Declaration on Social Justice for a Fair Globalization • The new report of the Global Commission on the Future of Work calls for the establishment of a “Universal Labour Guarantee”, which would include fundamental rights, maximum limits on working hours, protection of safety and health at work, and an “adequate living wage” 4 An adequate minimum wage • Minimum wages have contributed to reducing wage inequality in countries, from Brazil, to China, Turkey or the Russian Federation.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 19 the Theory of Effective Demand
    Chapter 19 The theory of effective demand In essence, the “Keynesian revolution” was a shift of emphasis from one type of short-run equilibrium to another type as providing the appropriate theory for actual unemployment situations. Edmund Malinvaud (1977), p. 29. In this and the following chapters the focus is shifted from long-run macro- economics to short-run macroeconomics. The long-run models concentrated on factors of importance for the economic evolution over a time horizon of at least 10-15 years. With such a horizon the supply side (think of capital accumulation, population growth, and technological progress) is the primary determinant of cumulative changes in output and consumption the trend. Mainstream macro- economists see the demand side and monetary factors as of key importance for the fluctuations of output and employment about the trend. In a long-run perspective these fluctuations are of only secondary quantitative importance. The preceding chapters have chieflyignored them. But within shorter horizons, fluctuations are the focal point and this brings the demand-side, monetary factors, market imper- fections, nominal rigidities, and expectation errors to the fore. The present and subsequent chapters deal with the role of these short- and medium-run factors for the failure of the laissez-faire market economy to ensure full employment and for the possibilities of active macro policies as a means to improve outcomes. This chapter introduces building blocks of Keynesian theory of the short run. By “Keynesian theory”we mean a macroeconomic framework that (a) aims at un- derstanding “what determines the actual employment of the available resources”,1 including understanding why mass unemployment arises from time to time, and (b) in this endeavor ascribes a primary role to aggregate demand.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman 1) Suppose the Fed
    Problem Set 7 – Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman 1) Suppose the Fed reduces the money supply by 5 percent. a) What happens to the aggregate demand curve? If the Fed reduces the money supply, the aggregate demand curve shifts down. This result is based on the quantity equation MV = PY, which tells us that a decrease in money M leads to a proportionate decrease in nominal output PY (assuming of course that velocity V is fixed). For any given price level P, the level of output Y is lower, and for any given Y, P is lower. b) What happens to the level of output and the price level in the short run and in the long run? In the short run, we assume that the price level is fixed and that the aggregate supply curve is flat. In the short run, output falls but the price level doesn’t change. In the long-run, prices are flexible, and as prices fall over time, the economy returns to full employment. If we assume that velocity is constant, we can quantify the effect of the 5% reduction in the money supply. Recall from Chapter 4 that we can express the quantity equation in terms of percent changes: ΔM/M + ΔV/V = ΔP/P + ΔY/Y We know that in the short run, the price level is fixed. This implies that the percentage change in prices is zero and thus ΔM/M = ΔY/Y. Thus in the short run a 5 percent reduction in the money supply leads to a 5 percent reduction in output.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflationary Expectations and the Costs of Disinflation: a Case for Costless Disinflation in Turkey?
    Inflationary Expectations and the Costs of Disinflation: A Case for Costless Disinflation in Turkey? $0,,993 -44 : Abstract: This paper explores the output costs of a credible disinflationary program in Turkey. It is shown that a necessary condition for a costless disinflationary path is that the weight attached to future inflation in the formation of inflationary expectations exceeds 50 percent. Using quarterly data from 1980 - 2000, the estimate of the weight attached to future inflation is found to be consistent with a costless disinflation path. The paper also uses structural Vector Autoregressions (VAR) to explore the implications of stabilizing aggregate demand. The results of the structural VAR corroborate minimum output losses associated with disinflation. 1. INTRODUCTION Inflationary expectations and aggregate demand pressure are two important variables that influence inflation. It is recognized that reducing inflation through contractionary demand policies can involve significant reductions in output and employment relative to potential output. The empirical macroeconomics literature is replete with estimates of the so- called “sacrifice ratio,” the percentage cumulative loss of output due to a 1 percent reduction in inflation. It is well known that inflationary expectations play a significant role in any disinflation program. If inflationary expectations are adaptive (backward-looking), wage contracts would be set accordingly. If inflation drops unexpectedly, real wages rise increasing employment costs for employers. Employers would then cut back employment and production disrupting economic activity. If expectations are formed rationally (forward- 1 2 looking), any momentum in inflation must be due to the underlying macroeconomic policies. Sargent (1982) contends that the seeming inflation- output trade-off disappears when one adopts the rational expectations framework.
    [Show full text]
  • Living Wage & Income Position Statement
    Living Wage & Income Position Statement INTRODUCTION We believe that all individuals deserve the opportunity to earn a living wage & income including the remarkable and diverse group of people who work at The Hershey Company and the many individuals who make their living within our broader supply chain. Hershey recognizes the concepts of living wage and living income as human rights and that mandated minimum wages are not always sufficient to allow workers a basic, but decent, standard of living including; but not limited to adequate housing, food, access to education, childcare and savings for unexpected events. Furthermore, within our extended supply chain, lack of income for smallholder farmers is a root cause of poverty, which increases the risk of other human rights violations such as child or forced labor as well as deforestation. Lastly, we note the clear linkages between wages & income and achieving many of the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals. As a result, we are taking action to maintain our strong pay practices within our Hershey operations including continuing to pay a living wage to full-time Hershey employees across our global locations. We are also establishing new partnerships and programming in our cocoa supply chain that will allow us to: • Directly measure farmer incomes on Cocoa For Good Farms in Ghana and Cote d’Ivoire to better target our programs and investments focused on improving incomes • Strengthen our engagement in the pre-competitive platforms and multi-stakeholder collaborations we feel are critical to enable an environment ultimately needed to promote a living income for cocoa farmers We will revisit the focus of our commitments in 2023 to assess our progress as well as the opportunity for new programming in other parts of our operations and extended supply chain.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • A Classical View of the Business Cycle
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A CLASSICAL VIEW OF THE BUSINESS CYCLE Michael T. Belongia Peter N. Ireland Working Paper 26056 http://www.nber.org/papers/w26056 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2019 We are especially grateful to David Laidler for his encouragement during the development of this paper and to John Taylor, Kenneth West, two referees, and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta for helpful comments on previous drafts. All errors that remain are our own. Neither of us received any external support for, or has any financial interest that relates to, the research described in this paper. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2019 by Michael T. Belongia and Peter N. Ireland. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. A Classical View of the Business Cycle Michael T. Belongia and Peter N. Ireland NBER Working Paper No. 26056 July 2019 JEL No. B12,E31,E32,E41,E43,E52 ABSTRACT In the 1920s, Irving Fisher extended his previous work on the Quantity Theory to describe, through an early version of the Phillips Curve, how changes in the money stock could be associated with cyclical movements in output, employment, and inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8Th Edition N
    Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1 1. Introduction a. We now turn to a short term view of fluctuations in the economy. b. This is the chapter that made this book controversial as Mankiw tends to ignore the Keynesian framework contained in most Principles textbooks. c. I personally find that to be a substantial improvement over those earlier books. d. Here we use the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model to explain short term economic fluctuations around the long term trend of the economy. e. On average over the past 50 years, the production of the US economy as measured by real GDP has grown by about 3 percent per year. i. While this has to be adjusted for population growth, one has to wonder why people tend to view their economic position so negatively. ii. Recession is a period of declining real incomes and rising unemployment. P. 702. iii. A depression is a severe recession. P. 702. 2. Three Key Facts about Economic Fluctuations a. Fact 1: Economic fluctuations are irregular and unpredictable i. They are called the business cycle, which can be misleading. ii. Figure 1: A Look at Short-run Economic Fluctuations. P. 703. iii. Every time that you hear depressing economic news–and they are reported often, remember Figure 1(a). iv. The last 25 years has observed steady real growth with only minor reversals. b. Fact 2: Most macroeconomic quantities fluctuate together c. Fact 3: As output falls, unemployment rises 3. Explaining Short Run Economic Fluctuations a.
    [Show full text]