Studies in Econometric Method

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Studies in Econometric Method COWLES FOUNDATION For Research in Economics at Yale University Studies in The Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale Uni­ 'l:et·sity, established as an activity of the Department of Economics Econometric Method in 1955, has as its purpose the conduct and encouragement of research in economics, finance, commet·ce, industry, and tech­ nology, including problems of the organization of these activities. The Cowles Foundation seeks to foster the development of logical, mathematical, and statistical methods of analysis for application Edited by in economics and t·elated social sciences. The professional research Wm. C. Hood and staff are, as a rule, faculty membe1·s with appointments and teach­ Tjalling C. Koopmans ing responsibilities in the Department of Economics and other departments. The Cowles Foundation continues the work of the Cowles Com­ ( ~~~3) mission for Research in Economics founded in 1932 by Alfred Cowles at Colorado Springs, Colorado. The Commission moved to Chicago in 1939 and was ajjUiated with the University of Chicago until 1955. In 1955 the professional 1·esea1·ch staff of the Com­ mission accepted appointments at Yale and, along with other members of the Yale Department of Economics, formed the ?'e­ seat·ch staff of the newly established Cowles Foundation. A list of Cowles Foundation Monogmphs appears at the end of this volume. r:. -, ··-. ,,or~~"'~"'"'~... (, .. ~ff'JO.co t:•; r;c,,•,-,. \)J s"" '"~·.;.-t.a:/~·~~::~· ~:: t .,. ·: ··- .. -· I;'~:~ ~r Ia y ... ". ' . - r, E ·~ :·· ;· • ·.·. · [: i! ,,H ....... r-.1 .... ~.. ... C. ..: New Haven and London, Yale University Press CHAPTER I ECONOMIC MEASUREMENTS FOR POLICY AND PREDICTION BY .JACOB MARSCHAK Page 1. Useful Knowledge ..................................................... 1 2. Structure....................... ................. 3 3. Maintained Structure and Change of Structure ... 4 4. Controlled and Uncontrolled Changes ........................ 8 5. Some Definitions Extended ..... 8 6. The Technician and the Policy-Maker .. 10 7. Random Shocks and Errors ........ 12 8. The Need for Structural Estimation ............. 15 9. The Time Path of Economic Variables; Dynamic Structures.......... 17 10. "Steering Wheel" and Automatisms..................................... 24 11. Mathematics and Prediction. 25 12. Conclusion............................................................. 26 1. USEFUL KNOWLEDGE \..Knowledge is useful if it helps to make the best decisions. To illustrate useful knowledge we shall take an example from the century-old elementary economics of the firm and of taxation. Such examples are admittedly crude (or, if the reader prefers, neat) compared with the complex actual world since their very purpose is to isolate the essentials of a problem by "idealizing reality." Later sections (beginning with Section 5) will deal with ways of eliminating at least some of the legitimate realistic objections. What kinds of knowledge are useful (A) to guide a monopolistic firm in its choice of the most profitable output level and (B) to guide the government in its choice of the rate of excise tax on the firm's product? Let q represent quantity produced and sold per unit of time; p, price including tax; e, tax per unit of product; 'Y, total cost of producing and selling q units. To fix ideas, suppose that the demand for the product of the firm is known to be (approximately) a linear function of the price and that all costs are known to consist of fixed charges. (This is almost the case with hydroelectric plants.) Write for the demand curve (1) p =a- {3q ({3 > 0). The firm's profit (net revenue) per unit of time is (2) r = (p - e)q - 'Y, SEC. 2] MEASUREMENTS FOR POLICY AND PREDICTION 3 2 JACOB MARSCHAK [CHAP. 1 interested in high output, it will choose the smaller of the two real roots, or, using (1), say 01 < 02 • If T* exceeds a certain level To , the roots will be not real 2 (3) r = (a - 0 - {Jq)q - 'Y = -{Jq + (a - O)q - 'Y· (i.e., a tax revenue T* > To is unattainable). We thus conclude that if the government knows a and {3 it can choose the best value of 0 for any CASE A: If the firm knows a, {3, and 0, it can use equation (3) to com­ desired and attainable level T* of tax revenue. pute the difference between the profits that would be attained at any two alternative output levels. To choose the most profitable output of We can sum up as follows: all, it therefore suffices to know a, {3, and 0. It happens in our example, CAsE A: Desired: maximum r. Decision variable: q. Useful knowledge: as in most discussions of classical economies, that the functions inn>lved the form of relations (1) and (2) and the values of the parameters a, are differentiable/ so that the best output level, say q = q, ean be found {3, 0. by putting dr I dq = 0. Hence CASE B1. Desired: maximum T. Decision variable: 0. Useful knowledge: the fact that profits are maximized, the form of (1) and (2), and the (4) q = (a - 0)/2{3. value of a. CASE B2 • Desired: maximum q for given T = T*. Decision variable: CASE B: Assume that the government knows that the firm maximizes 0. Useful knowledge: same as in Case B 2 , plus the knowledge of {3. its profit. What other knowledge is useful to the government? This de­ pends on its aims: 2. STRUCTURE CASE B1 : Suppose, first, that the government, which collects from the In all of our examples so far, useful knowledge pertains to certain firm the ta.x revenue T, economic relations. In Case A the firm has to know something about relations (1) and (2). Relation (1), the demand equation, describes the (5) T = Oq, behavior of buyers. The form and the coefficients (a, {3) of this relation wants to maximize this revenue by the proper choice of the excise-tax depend on social and psychological facts, such as the frequency distri­ rate 8. Then, by equations (4) and (5), bution of consumers by tastes, family size, income, etc. Relation (2), the profit equation, registers the institutional fact that the tax rate is (6) T = O(a - 0)/"2 :i. fixed at 0, and the fact (reflecting the technology of the firm as well as the price and durability of its plant and the interests and rents stipulated Therefore, if the government knows a, it can compute the ratio between in its contracts) that the total cost consists of given fixed charges, 'Y· the tax revenues resulting from fixing any two alternative excise rates. With respect to the decision problem of Case A, relations (1) and (2) This ratio is independent of {3. Hence, to make the best decision (i.e., are called structural relations and are said to constitute the structure; to choose the value of 0 that will bring in the highest tax revenue) it they involve constants (a, {3, 0, 'Y) called structural parameters. In Case is sufficient for the government to know a. In fact, the best value of B the assumed structure includes, in addition to (1) and (2), the as­ 8 is b = a./2. sumption of profit maximization, which results in relation (4); and defi­ nition (5) may also be counted as part of the structure. If (1) or (2) or CASE ~: Suppose, on the other hand, that the government wants to both had included a definite pattern of change-say, a linear trend­ goad the monopolist into maximum production, provided that a fixed this would also be a part of the structure. tax revenue T = T* can be collected. The best tax rate is found by solv­ In each of the problems studied the form of the structural relations ing the (quadratic) equation (6) for 0 with T* substituted for 1'. The and the values of some (not necessarily all) of their parameters prove to equation will have two real roots, say 8 and 8 (which, in a limiting case, 1 2 constitute useful knowledge. However, we shall presently see that under may coincide), provided that T* is not too large. Since, by equation (4), certain conditions other kinds of knowledge, possibly more easily at­ q is larger the smaller 8 is, and since the government was assumed to be tained, are sufficient to make the choice of the best decision possible. 1 But see Section 5. 4 JACOB MARSCHAK (CHAP. I SEC. 3] MEASUREMENTS FOR POLICY AND PREDICTION 5 3. MAINTAINED STRUCTURE AND CHANGE OF STRUCTURE predicting r) is a quadratic equation, that the knowledge of structure is not necessary if the We shall show (7) r = Xl + M + "' structure is not expected to have changed by the time the decision takes its effect.2 Again consider Case A. Assume that the form of the struc­ say, whose coefficients are related to the coefficients of the structural equations as follows: tural relations (1) and (2) and the values of coefficients a, {3, 'Yare known to have been unchanged in the past and to continue unchanged in the (8) X = -{3, IJ. =a- 0, "= -"(. future, and make three alternative assumptions about the tax rate 0: If the structural relations (I) and (2) are assumed to retain in the fu­ ture the same (linear) form and the same values of parameters as in the CASE A': 0 has not changed in the past and is not expected to change. observed past, the firm can predict r for a given q by fitting a quadratic equation (7) to past observations on output and profit. It can thus CAsE A": 0 has not changed in the past but is expected to change in determine empirically the parameters X, IJ., " of the reduced form with­ a known way. out having to pay any attention to the manner [described by equations (8)] in which these parameters are related to the demand and cost con­ CASE A"': 0 has changed in the past.
Recommended publications
  • Retail Inventory Behavior and Business Fluctuations
    ALAN S. BLINDER Princeton University Retail Inventory Behavior and Business Fluctuations THE enigmatic behavior of the U.S. economy during the 1980 recession makes it more imperative than ever that some of the mystery that sur- rounds inventory behavior be solved. On the surface, the economy seems to have reacted quite differently to what appear to be rather similar exter- nal shocks (principally, rapid increases in oil prices) in 1973-75 and in 1979-80. However, if one abstracts from inventory behavior and focuses on final sales, the two recessions look rather similar. Several observations confirm this. First, the briefest recession in U.S. history was also the first in which inventory investment did not swing sharply toward liquidation between the peak and the trough. Second, if one judges the contraction by real final sales instead of real GNP, the 1980 recession was actually far deeper than the "severe" 1973-75 recession.1 And third, the way the 1980 recession was concentrated into a single quarter seems less unusual if one looks at real final sales instead of real GNP. In the 1973-75 reces- I thank Danny Quah for exceptional research assistance. I also thank Gregory Mankiw and Leonard Nakamura for research assistance and Stephenie Sigall and Phyllis Durepos for quickly and efficiently typing the paper. I am grateful to mem- bers of the Brookingspanel and to a numberof colleagues for helpful discussions on this research. I apologize to those I leave out when I mention Angus S. Deaton, David Germany, Wayne Gray, F. Owen Irvine, Jr., Louis J.
    [Show full text]
  • An Interview with Franco Modigliani
    THE UNIVERSITY OF KANSAS WORKING PAPERS SERIES IN THEORETICAL AND APPLIED ECONOMICS AN INTERVIEW WITH FRANCO MODIGLIANI Interviewed by William A. Barnett University of Kansas Robert Solow MIT THE UNIVERSITY OF KANSAS WORKING PAPERS SERIES IN THEORETICAL AND APPLIED ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NUMBER 200407 Macroeconomic Dynamics, 4, 2000, 222–256. Printed in the United States of America. MD INTERVIEW AN INTERVIEW WITH FRANCO MODIGLIANI Interviewed by William A. Barnett Washington University in St. Louis and Robert Solow Massachusetts Institute of Technology November 5–6, 1999 Franco Modigliani’s contributions in economics and finance have transformed both fields. Although many other major contributions in those fields have come and gone, Modigliani’s contributions seem to grow in importance with time. His famous 1944 article on liquidity preference has not only remained required reading for generations of Keynesian economists but has become part of the vocabulary of all economists. The implications of the life-cycle hypothesis of consumption and saving provided the primary motivation for the incorporation of finite lifetime models into macroeconomics and had a seminal role in the growth in macroeconomics of the overlapping generations approach to modeling of Allais, Samuelson, and Diamond. Modigliani and Miller’s work on the cost of capital transformed corporate finance and deeply influenced subsequent research on investment, capital asset pricing, and recent research on derivatives. Modigliani received the Nobel Memorial Prize for Economics in 1985. In macroeconomic policy, Modigliani has remained influential on two continents. In the United States, he played a central role in the creation of a the Federal Re- serve System’s large-scale quarterly macroeconometric model, and he frequently participated in the semiannual meetings of academic consultants to the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D.C.
    [Show full text]
  • Texte Intégral
    Working Paper History as heresy: unlearning the lessons of economic orthodoxy O'SULLIVAN, Mary Abstract In spring 2020, in the face of the covid-19 pandemic, central bankers in rich countries made unprecedented liquidity injections to stave off an economic crisis. Such radical action by central banks gained legitimacy during the 2008-2009 global financial crisis and enjoys strong support from prominent economists and economic historians. Their certainty reflects a remarkable agreement on a specific interpretation of the Great Depression of the 1930s in the United States, an interpretation developed by Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz in A Monetary History of the United States (1963). In this article, I explore the origins, the influence and the limits of A Monetary History’s interpretation for the insights it offers on the relationship between theory and history in the study of economic life. I show how historical research has been mobilised to show the value of heretical ideas in order to challenge economic orthodoxies. Friedman and Schwartz understood the heretical potential of historical research and exploited it in A Monetary History to question dominant interpretations of the Great Depression in their time. Now that [...] Reference O'SULLIVAN, Mary. History as heresy: unlearning the lessons of economic orthodoxy. Geneva : Paul Bairoch Institute of Economic History, 2021, 38 p. Available at: http://archive-ouverte.unige.ch/unige:150852 Disclaimer: layout of this document may differ from the published version. 1 / 1 FACULTÉ DES SCIENCES DE LA SOCIÉTÉ Paul Bairoch Institute of Economic History Economic History Working Papers | No. 3/2021 History as Heresy: Unlearning the Lessons of Economic Orthodoxy The Tawney Memorial Lecture 2021 Mary O’Sullivan Paul Bairoch Institute of Economic History, University of Geneva, UniMail, bd du Pont-d'Arve 40, CH- 1211 Genève 4.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Equilibrium Enough and Was Stigler Wrong
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Herfeld, Catherine Working Paper Between mathematical formalism, normative choice rules, and the behavioral sciences: The emergence of rational choice theories in the late 1940s and early 1950s CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-14 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Herfeld, Catherine (2017) : Between mathematical formalism, normative choice rules, and the behavioral sciences: The emergence of rational choice theories in the late 1940s and early 1950s, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-14, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/172306 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Dynamics at the Cowles Commission from the 1930S to the 1950S
    Yale University EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers Cowles Foundation 9-1-2019 Macroeconomic Dynamics at the Cowles Commission from the 1930s to the 1950s Robert W. Dimand Follow this and additional works at: https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/cowles-discussion-paper-series Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Dimand, Robert W., "Macroeconomic Dynamics at the Cowles Commission from the 1930s to the 1950s" (2019). Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers. 56. https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/cowles-discussion-paper-series/56 This Discussion Paper is brought to you for free and open access by the Cowles Foundation at EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cowles Foundation Discussion Papers by an authorized administrator of EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale. For more information, please contact [email protected]. MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS AT THE COWLES COMMISSION FROM THE 1930S TO THE 1950S By Robert W. Dimand May 2019 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 2195 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 http://cowles.yale.edu/ Macroeconomic Dynamics at the Cowles Commission from the 1930s to the 1950s Robert W. Dimand Department of Economics Brock University 1812 Sir Isaac Brock Way St. Catharines, Ontario L2S 3A1 Canada Telephone: 1-905-688-5550 x. 3125 Fax: 1-905-688-6388 E-mail: [email protected] Keywords: macroeconomic dynamics, Cowles Commission, business cycles, Lawrence R. Klein, Tjalling C. Koopmans Abstract: This paper explores the development of dynamic modelling of macroeconomic fluctuations at the Cowles Commission from Roos, Dynamic Economics (Cowles Monograph No.
    [Show full text]
  • Curriculum Vitae for James J. Heckman
    September 13, 2021 James Joseph Heckman Department of Economics University of Chicago 1126 East 59th Street Chicago, Illinois 60637 Telephone: (773) 702-0634 Fax: (773) 702-8490 Email: [email protected] Personal Date of Birth: April 19, 1944 Place of Birth: Chicago, Illinois Education B.A. 1965 (Math) Colorado College (summa cum laude) M.A. 1968 (Econ) Princeton University Ph.D. 1971 (Econ) Princeton University Dissertation “Three Essays on Household Labor Supply and the Demand for Market Goods.” Sponsors: S. Black, H. Kelejian, A. Rees Graduate and Undergraduate Academic Honors Phi Beta Kappa Woodrow Wilson Fellow NDEA Fellow NIH Fellow Harold Willis Dodds Fellow Post-Graduate Honors Honorary Degrees and Professorships Doctor Honoris Causa, Vienna University of Economics and Business, Vienna, Austria. Jan- uary, 2017. Doctor of Social Sciences Honoris Causa, Lignan University, Hong Kong, China. November, 2015. Honorary Doctorate of Science (Economics), University College London. September, 2013. Doctor Honoris Causis, Pontifical University, Santiago, Chile. August, 2009. Doctor Honoris Causis, University of Montreal.´ May 2004. 1 September 13, 2021 Doctor Honoris Causis, Bard College, May 2004. Doctor Honoris Causis, UAEM, Mexico. January 2003. Doctor Honoris Causis, University of Chile, Fall 2002. Honorary Doctor of Laws, Colorado College, 2001. Honorary Professor, Jinan University, Guangzhou, China, June, 2014. Honorary Professor, Renmin University, P. R. China, June, 2010. Honorary Professor, Beijing Normal University, P. R. China, June, 2010. Honorary Professor, Harbin Institute of Technology, P. R. China, October, 2007. Honorary Professor, Wuhan University, Wuhan, China, 2003. Honorary Professor, Huazhong University of Science and Technology, Wuhan, China, 2001. Honorary Professor, University of Tucuman, October, 1998.
    [Show full text]
  • Cowles Commission Structural Models, Causal Effects And
    Intro Questions/Criteria Counterfactuals Identification problems Summary Cowles Commission Structural Models, Causal Effects and Treatment Effects: A Synthesis James Heckman University of Chicago University College Dublin Econometric Policy Evaluation, Lecture I Koopmans Memorial Lectures Cowles Foundation Yale University September 26, 2006 1 / 121 Intro Questions/Criteria Counterfactuals Identification problems Summary Staff List (University of Chicago) Report of Research Activities, July 1, 1952-June 30, 1954 President Alfred Cowles Executive Director Rosson L. Cardwell Research Director Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Associates Stephen G. Allen I.N. Herstein Richard F. Muth Martin J. Beckmann Clifford Hildreth Roy Radner Rosson L. Cardwell H.S. Houthakker Leo T¨ornqvist Gerard Debreu Tjalling C. Koopmans Daniel Waterman John Gurland Jacob Marschak Christopher Winstein Arnold C. Harberger C. Bartlett McGuire Research Assistants Gary Becker Thomas A. Goldman Lester G. Telser Francis Bobkoski Edwin Goldstein Alan L. Tritter William L. Dunaway Mark Nerlove Jagna Zahl Research Consultants Stephen G. Allen Harold T. Davis Leonid Hurwicz Theodore W. Anderson Trygve Haavelmo Lawrence R. Klein Kenneth J. Arrow Clifford Hildreth Theodore S. Motzkin Herman Chernoff William C. Hood Herman Rubin Carl F. Christ H.S. Houthakker Herbert A. Simon Guests Pierre F.J. Baichere Jose Gil-Pelaez Rene F. Montjoie Karl Henrik Borch William Hamburger Sigbert J. Prais Jacques Dreze Herman F. Karreman Bertram E. Rifas Atle Harald Elsas William E. Krelle Ciro Tognetti Masao
    [Show full text]
  • Leontief and His German Period✩ Harald Hagemann*
    Russian Journal of Economics 7 (2021) 67–90 DOI 10.32609/j.ruje.7.58034 Publication date: 31 March 2021 www.rujec.org Leontief and his German period✩ Harald Hagemann* University of Hohenheim, Stuttgart, Germany Abstract Wassily Leontief jun. (1905–1999) moved to Berlin in April 1925 after getting his first academic degree from the University of Leningrad. In Berlin he mainly studied with Werner Sombart and Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz who were the referees of his Ph.D. thesis “The economy as a circular flow” (1928). From spring 1927 until April 1931 Leontief was a member of the research staff at the Kiel Institute of World Economics, interrupted by the period from April 1929 to March 1930 when he was an advisor to the Chinese Ministry of Railroads. In the journal of the Kiel Institute, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Leontief had already published his first article “Die Bilanz der russischen Volkswirtschaft. Eine methodologische Untersuchung” [The balance of the Russian economy. A methodo­ logical investigation] in 1925. In Kiel Leontief primarily worked on the statistical analysis of supply and demand curves. Leontief’s method triggered a fierce critique by Ragnar Frisch, which launched a heavy debate on “pitfalls” in the construction of supply and demand curves. The debate started in Germany but was continued in the USA where Leontief became a researcher at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) in summer 1931. The Leontief–Frisch controversy culminated in the Quarterly Journal of Economics (1934), published by Harvard University, where Leontief made his sub­ sequent career from 1932–1975. His later analysis of the employment consequences of technological change in the 1980s had some roots in his Kiel period.
    [Show full text]
  • Jacob Marschak and the Cowles Approaches to the Theory of Money and Assets Robert W
    Jacob Marschak and the Cowles Approaches to the Theory of Money and Assets Robert W. Dimand and Harald Hagemann Dimand: Department of Economics, Brock University, 1812 Sir Isaac Brock Way, St. Catharines, Ontario L2S 3A1, Canada; e-mail: [email protected] Hagemann (corresponding author): Universität Hohenheim, 70593 Stuttgart, Germany; e-mail: [email protected] JEL classifications: B22 History of Economic Thought since 1925: Macroeconomics; B31 History of Economic Thought: Individuals, E Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics Keywords: Jacob Marschak, money in a theory of assets, Cowles Commission, Harry Markowitz, James Tobin Abstract: Jacob Marschak shaped the emergence of monetary theory and portfolio choice at the Cowles Commission (which he directed from 1943 to 1948, but with which he was involved already from 1937) at the University of Chicago, where he was the doctoral teacher of Leonid Hurwicz, Harry Markowitz and Don Patinkin, and then from 1955 at the Cowles Foundation at Yale University, where he was a senior colleague of James Tobin until moving to UCLA in 1960. Marschak’s later attempts to clarify the concept of liquidity and to emphasize the role of new information for economic behavior date back as far as to his early experiences with hyperinflationary processes in the Northern Caucasus during the Russian Revolution. Marschak came to monetary theory with his 1922 Heidelberg doctoral dissertation on the quantity theory equation of exchange (published in 1924 as “Die Verkehrsgleichung”), and embedded monetary theory in a wider theory of asset market equilibrium in studies of “Money and the Theory of Assets” (1938), “Assets, Prices, and Monetary Theory” (with Helen Makower, 1938), “Role of Liquidity under Complete and Incomplete Information” (1949), “The Rationale of the Demand for Money and of ‘Money Illusion’” (1950), and “Monnaie et liquidité dans les modèles macroéconomiques et microéconomiques” (1955), as well as in Income, Employment and the Price Level (lectures Marschak gave at Chicago, edited by Fand and Markowitz, 1951).
    [Show full text]
  • Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (Born 1921)
    K000067 Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (born 1921) Kenneth Arrow is the author of key post-Second World War innovations in economics that have made economic theory a mathematical science. The Arrow Possibility Theorem created the field of social choice theory. Arrow extended and proved the relationship of Pareto efficiency with economic general equilibrium to include corner solutions and non-differentiable pro- duction and utility functions. With Gerard Debreu, he created the Ar- row–Debreu mathematical model of economic general competitive equilibrium including sufficient conditions for the existence of market-clear- ing prices. Arrow securities and contingent commodities extend the model to cover uncertainty and provide a cornerstone of the modern theory of finance. Kenneth Arrow is a legendary figure, with an enormous range of contribu- tions to 20th-century economics, responsible for the key post-Second World War innovations in economic theory that allowed economics to become a mathematical science. His impact is suggested by the number of major ideas that bear his name: Arrow’s Theorem, the Arrow–Debreu model, the Ar- row–Pratt index of risk aversion, and Arrow securities. Four of his most distinctive achievements, all published in the brief period 1951–54, are as follows: Arrow Possibility Theorem. Social Choice and Individual Values (1951a) created the field of social choice theory, a fundamental construct in theo- retical welfare economics and theoretical political science. Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics. ‘An extension of the basic theorems of classical welfare economics’ (1951b) presents the First and Sec- ond Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics and their proofs without requiring differentiability of utility, consumption, or technology, and in- cluding corner solutions (zeroes in quantities of inputs or outputs).
    [Show full text]
  • The Cowles Commission and Foundation for Research in Economics
    THE COWLES COMMISSION AND FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS By Robert W. Dimand November 2019 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 2207 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 http://cowles.yale.edu/ The Cowles Commission and Foundation for Research in Economics Robert W. Dimand Department of Economics Brock University 1812 Sir Isaac Brock Way St. Catharines, Ontario L2S 3A1 Canada Telephone: 1-905-688-5550 x. 3125 Fax: 1-905-688-6388 E-mail: [email protected] Keywords: Cowles Commission, formalism in economics, mathematics in economics, Cowles approach to econometrics JEL classifications: B23 History of Economic Thought since 1925: Econometrics, Quantitative and Mathematical Studies, B41 Economic Methodology, C01 Econometrics, C02 Mathematical Methods Abstract: Founded in 1932 by a newspaper heir disillusioned by the failure of forecasters to predict the Great Crash, the Cowles Commission promoted the use of formal mathematical and statistical methods in economics, initially through summer research conferences in Colorado and through support of the Econometric Society (of which Alfred Cowles was secretary-treasurer for decades). After moving to the University of Chicago in 1939, the Cowles Commission sponsored works, many later honored with Nobel Prizes but at the time out of the mainstream of economics, by Haavelmo, Hurwicz and Koopmans on econometrics, Arrow and Debreu on general equilibrium, Yntema and Mosak on general equilibrium in international trade theory, Arrow on social choice, Koopmans on activity analysis, Klein on macroeconometric modelling, Lange, Marschak and Patinkin on macroeconomic theory, and Markowitz on portfolio choice, but came into intense methodological, ideological and personal conflict with the emerging “Chicago school.” This conflict led the Cowles Commission to move to Yale in 1955 as the Cowles Foundation, directed by James Tobin (who had declined to move to Chicago to direct it).
    [Show full text]
  • Kenneth J. Arrow, Theodore Harris and Jacob Marschak Source: Econometrica, Vol
    Optimal Inventory Policy Author(s): Kenneth J. Arrow, Theodore Harris and Jacob Marschak Source: Econometrica, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Jul., 1951), pp. 250-272 Published by: The Econometric Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1906813 Accessed: 20-04-2015 04:26 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The Econometric Society is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Econometrica. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 133.11.138.166 on Mon, 20 Apr 2015 04:26:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions OPTIMAL INVENTORY POLICY' By KENNETH J. ARROW, THEODORE HARRIS, AND JACOB MARSCHAK2 Optimal inventory policy is first derived for a simple model in which the future (and constant) demand flow and other relevant quantities are known in advance. This is followed by the study of uncertainty models- a static and a dynamic one-in which the demand flow is a random vari- able with a known probability distribution. The best maximum stock and the best reordering point are determined as functions of the demand distribution, the cost of making an order, and the penalty of stock de- pletion.
    [Show full text]