A Theory of Divided Government

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Theory of Divided Government A Theory of Divided Government The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Alesina, Alberto, and Howard Rosenthal. 1996. “A Theory of Divided Government.” Econometrica 64 (6) (November): 1311. doi:10.2307/2171833. Published Version doi:10.2307/2171833 Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:34222831 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA Econometnica, Vol. 64, No. 6 (November, 1996), 1311-1341 A THEORY OF DIVIDED GOVERNMENT1 BY ALBERTOALESINA AND HOWARDROSENTHAL This paper extends the spatial theory of voting to an institutionalstructure in which policy choices depend upon not only the executive but also the compositionof the legislature.Voters have incentivesto be strategicsince policy reflects the outcome of a simultaneouselection of the legislature and the executive and since the legislature's impact on policy depends upon relative plurality.To analyze equilibriumin this game between voters, we apply "coalition proof' type refinements.The model has several testable implicationswhich are consistentwith voting behaviorin the United States. For instance,the model predicts:(a) split-ticketswhere some voters vote for one party for presidentand the other for congress;(b) for some parametervalues, a dividedgovernment with differentparties controlling the executiveand the majorityof the legislature;and (c) the midtermelectoral cycle with the partyholding the presidencyalways losing votes in midtermcongressional elections. KEYWORDS: Voting theory,checks and balances,conditional sincerity, midterm cycle, coalitionproof Nash equilibria. 1. INTRODUCTION NATIONALPOLICIES TYPICALLY REFLECT the composition of both the executive and the legislature. In the United States, for instance, the administration's influence on policy is affected by the compositionof congress. Traditionalspatial models of elections ignore this institutionalcomplexity and assume that the winner of a two-partyrace fully controlspolicy.2 These models focus on the strategicinteraction between the candidatesand treat each voter as a passive player,voting for the candidateoffering the more preferredpolicy. In our model, instead,the voters face two partieswith preferencesdefined on policy outcomes(Wittman (1977, 1990),Calvert (1985), Alesina (1988)).Without "checks"by the legislature,the executivesrepresenting the two parties pursue distinct and polarizedpolicies.3 However, policy outcomes in our model are a functionnot only of which partyholds the executivebut also of the composition of the legislature. The ideal policies of the two parties are identified by two points on an interval;voters to the left of the left party'spolicy alwaysvote for this party in both the legislative and presidentialelections; similarly,voters on the right of 1 This work was supportedby National Science FoundationGrant SES-8821441.Alesina also gratefullyacknowledges support from the Sloan Foundation.An earlierversion of this paper was circulatedwith the title "ModeratingElections." We thank Geir Asheim, Michael Whinston,a co-editor, and the referees for extremelyhelpful comments.The manuscriptwas revised while Rosenthalwas a fellow of the Centerfor AdvancedStudy in the BehavioralSciences. 2 For example,see Kramer(1973). For surveysof this literature,see Enelow and Hinich (1984) and Ordeshook(1986). 3The existenceof "polarization"in Americanpolitics has been widelydocumented by Poole and Rosenthal(1984a,b; 1991). This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Sat, 7 Jun 2014 15:22:45 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 1312 A. ALESINA AND H. ROSENTHAL the right partyhave a dominantstrategy to vote for the right party.In contrast, voters with ideal policies intermediatebetween the positionsof the parties take advantageof the institutionalstructure of "checks and balances"to moderate the executive and achieve a policy outcome closer to their ideal. This realistic feature of the model implies strategic voting. Unlike the traditional spatial model, the decisionof each "middle-of-the-road"voter dependsupon his beliefs about the behavior of other voters. Thus we examine strategic voting in the context of the "new institutionalism's"concern about the executive-legislative interaction(Shepsle (1986), Hammondand Miller (1988),Fiorina (1990, 1991)).4 Our model of "moderatingbehavior" has implicationsconsistent with three observationsconcerning American politics: split-ticket voting, the midtermcycle, and dividedgovernment. The model predictssplit-ticket voting when the execu- tive and the legislatureare elected simultaneously.That is, some voters support differentparties in the two elections to, say, counterbalancea presidenton the right with a legislature on the left. The model also captures the persistent phenomenonof the "midtermvoting cycle."In midtermcongressional elections, the president's party loses plurality relative to the preceding congressional elections held simultaneouslywith the presidential election. Our explanation relies upon the fact that in presidential election years the electorate faces uncertaintyabout who will win the presidency.Moderate voters want neither a left-dominatedcongress for fear that the presidentmay turn out to be left, nor a right-dominatedcongress lest the presidentbe right.Their uncertaintyabout the outcome of the presidentialelection leads them to prefer a "hedged"congress. At midterm,once the identity of the presidentis known,voters move congress further in the direction opposite to that of the president in order to achieve better moderation.Empirical studies by Alesina and Rosenthal (1989), Erikson (1990), and Alesina, Londregan,and Rosenthal (1993) have shown that this model of the midterm effect performs at least as well and often better than traditionalempirical voting models that emphasizeincumbency advantage and retrospectivevoting based on the state of the economy.5A sufficientlystrong midtermcycle or substantialsplit-ticket voting will producedivided government where the party holding the presidency does not have a majority in the legislature. We present both a complete information and an incomplete information model. In the former,but not the latter, the distributionof voter ideal points is common knowledge.Split-ticket voting, moderatingbehavior, and dividedgov- 4Cox (1987)analyzes strategic voting when voters decide more than one contest in the contextof the double-memberdistricts of Victorian England. He finds evidence of substantialsplit-ticket voting until cabinet governmentis instituted.With cabinet government,policy depends only on a parliamentarymajority and not on, as in the Americansystem, an executive-legislativeinteraction that is affectedby the compositionof the legislature.The virtualdisappearance of split-ticketvoting undercabinet government is expectedfrom the perspectiveof our model. 5Erikson (1988)tests coattailsand other alternativeexplanations of the midtermcycle and finds that they are not supportedby the data. This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Sat, 7 Jun 2014 15:22:45 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions THEORY OF DIVIDED GOVERNMENT 1313 emnment,present in both cases, can be more easily illustratedwith the complete informationmodel.6 A midtermcycle emerges only in the incompleteinforma- tion model. The Alesina and Rosenthal(1995, pp. 43-120) volume,written after the initial draft of this paper, motivates these models using the concept of conditionalsincerity briefly discussedin Section 3.2 of this paper but does not analyze equilibriumusing the game-theoreticconcepts of abstract stable sets and coalition proof Nash equilibrium. The paper is organizedas follows. In Section 2 we describe the one-period model and the game-theoreticsolution concepts which we employ.We analyze equilibriumin this basic model in Section 3. This section uses rather general assumptionsabout functional forms. In Section 4 we present the two-period complete informationcase with more restrictiveassumptions. In Section 5 we discuss the incompleteinformation version of the model for specific functional forms.Section 6 concludes. 2. THE ONE-PERIOD MODEL 2.1. Preferencesand Institutional Setup We consider a two-partysystem in which the parties (identified with the candidates)have policy preferences.In particular,the two parties, labelled D and R, and the voters have unidimensional,continuous, and strictly concave utility functions over a single policy issue. Utility functions are all identical except for the bliss point. The utility of a policy x is given as (1) u1 = U(X, 0i) where, for the two parties, we denote the bliss points as OD and OR with 0 < OD < OR < 1 and, for the generic voter i, we denote the bliss point as Oi. There is a continuumof voters. The bliss point cumulativedistribution H(O) is continuousand strictlyincreasing on the interval I = [0,1]. The median type is denoted ,u= H-1 (0.5). Any non-null subset, S, of I is termed a coalition. The preferences of both parties and voters are common knowledge.We choose to workwith a continuumof voters ratherthan with a finite numberfor reasonsof technicalconvenience clarified in footnote 13, followingProposition 2 below. The president is elected by majorityvote. If the executive had complete control of policy, the partywinning the presidencywould
Recommended publications
  • Parliamentary, Presidential and Semi-Presidential Democracies Democracies Are Often Classified According to the Form of Government That They Have
    Parliamentary, Presidential and Semi-Presidential Democracies Democracies are often classified according to the form of government that they have: • Parliamentary • Presidential • Semi-Presidential Legislative responsibility refers to a situation in which a legislative majority has the constitutional power to remove a government from office without cause. A vote of confidence is initiated by the government { the government must resign if it fails to obtain a legislative majority. A vote of no confidence is initiated by the legislature { the government must resign if it fails to obtain a legislative majority. A constructive vote of no confidence must indicate who will replace the government if the incumbent loses a vote of no confidence. A vote of no confidence is initiated by the legislature { the government must resign if it fails to obtain a legislative majority. A constructive vote of no confidence must indicate who will replace the government if the incumbent loses a vote of no confidence. A vote of confidence is initiated by the government { the government must resign if it fails to obtain a legislative majority. The defining feature of presidential democracies is that they do not have legislative responsibility. • US Government Shutdown, click here In contrast, parliamentary and semi-presidential democracies both have legislative responsibility. • PM Question Time (UK), click here In addition to legislative responsibility, semi-presidential democracies also have a head of state who is popularly elected for a fixed term. A head of state is popularly elected if she is elected through a process where voters either (i) cast a ballot directly for a candidate or (ii) they cast ballots to elect an electoral college, whose sole purpose is to elect the head of state.
    [Show full text]
  • National Security in Divided Government Executive Summary • Divided Government Is the Norm in Recent History, Not the Exception
    Maj. Gen. Arnold L. Punaro, USMC (Ret.) Former Staff Director, Senate Armed Services Committee National Security in Divided Government Executive Summary • Divided government is the norm in recent history, not the exception. In the last 54 years, 34 years had at least one of the three bodies (president, House, Senate) led by the opposite party. • Regardless of unified or divided government, the president still signed both a defense authorization bill and an appropriations bill that funded defense and intelligence activities into law each year. In all years, the defense committees operated in the main in their traditional bipartisan fashion. It should be recognized that a president can veto something out of a bill but hardly ever can veto something into a bill. • The automatic sequester cuts are still in effect for FY20 and FY21 on defense and domestic discretionary spending. This unfortunately provides a strong default position for those who do not want to reach another bipartisan spending compromise. • The deficits, interest on the debt, the apparent failure to spend domestic discretionary appropriated at the agreed levels, and the Freedom Caucus’s cure of their deficit spending amnesia will add to the degree of difficulty in reaching a bipartisan budget compromise. • With history as a guide, the Democratic majority in the House will likely set a lower defense topline than requested; curtail nuclear weapons programs; push social and environmental issues; fence troubled programs; provide generous pay, benefits, and pro-family programs; challenge any major organizational proposals; constrain ongoing operations while requiring real-time operational updates; and pursue arms control restrictions.
    [Show full text]
  • Federalism, Bicameralism, and Institutional Change: General Trends and One Case-Study*
    brazilianpoliticalsciencereview ARTICLE Federalism, Bicameralism, and Institutional Change: General Trends and One Case-study* Marta Arretche University of São Paulo (USP), Brazil The article distinguishes federal states from bicameralism and mechanisms of territorial representation in order to examine the association of each with institutional change in 32 countries by using constitutional amendments as a proxy. It reveals that bicameralism tends to be a better predictor of constitutional stability than federalism. All of the bicameral cases that are associated with high rates of constitutional amendment are also federal states, including Brazil, India, Austria, and Malaysia. In order to explore the mechanisms explaining this unexpected outcome, the article also examines the voting behavior of Brazilian senators constitutional amendments proposals (CAPs). It shows that the Brazilian Senate is a partisan Chamber. The article concludes that regional influence over institutional change can be substantially reduced, even under symmetrical bicameralism in which the Senate acts as a second veto arena, when party discipline prevails over the cohesion of regional representation. Keywords: Federalism; Bicameralism; Senate; Institutional change; Brazil. well-established proposition in the institutional literature argues that federal Astates tend to take a slow reform path. Among other typical federal institutions, the second legislative body (the Senate) common to federal systems (Lijphart 1999; Stepan * The Fundação de Amparo à Pesquisa no Estado
    [Show full text]
  • Divided Government, Deadlock and the Survival of Presidents and Presidential Regimes
    Divided Government, Deadlock and the Survival of Presidents and Presidential Regimes José Antonio Cheibub University of Pennsylvania [email protected] Presented at the conference “Constitutional Design 2000,” December 9-11, 1999, Center for Continuing Education, University of Notre Dame Introduction1 Of the 133 transitions to and from democracy that occurred in the world between 1946 and 1996, 59 took place in Latin America.2 Early theorizing on the causes of political instability in the region has tended to focus on structural variables -- the degree of dependency, the level of inequality, poverty, and so on -- which supposedly created conditions that were conducive to the demise of democratic regimes. Recent research has moved away from this focus on economic and social conditions and has concentrated instead on the impact of institutional features on the survival and operation of democracy in Latin America. Stimulated by the formulations first advanced by Juan Linz (1994),3 the breakdown of democratic regimes and the alleged “crisis of governability” of new democracies have been attributed to presidentialism, which, in combination with permissive electoral systems and weakly institutionalized political parties produce divided governments, deadlocks, institutional paralysis and, ultimately, the breakdown of democratic institutions. Yet, Latin American democracies, all of which are presidential, survive in many countries, even as governments implement policies aimed at radically restructuring their economies. This fact suggests that we need to take another look at arguments that attribute to presidentialism a causal impact on regime instability in Latin America. Or at least that we need to reconsider the causal mechanisms that are allegedly responsible for presidentialism's relatively poor performance.
    [Show full text]
  • Divided Government, Legislative Productivity, and Policy Change in the US and France
    Divided Government, Legislative Productivity, and Policy Change in the US and France Frank R. Baumgartner, UNC-Chapel Hill ([email protected]) Sylvain Brouard, Sciences Po Bordeaux ([email protected]) Emiliano Grossman, Sciences Po Paris ([email protected]) Sebastien G. Lazardeux, St. John Fisher College ([email protected]) Jonathan Moody, Penn State University ([email protected]) Abstract The concept of “divided government” is more complicated than scholars have allowed. We expand our knowledge of divided government by considering France as well as the US, by looking at all laws as well as important laws, and by distinguishing among four levels of divided v. unified government rather than a simple dichotomy as has been done in the past. Democratic governance requires that parties address important issues and they do so regardless of the patterns of institutional control. We find that periods of unified government show higher levels of production of important laws in the US, but we find no difference for overall legislative productivity. We find the same results in France. Keywords: divided government, legislative productivity, legislative-executive relations, France, United States Word count: 10,129 Submitted to British Journal of Political Science, March 12, 2012 1 INTRODUCTION In early August 2011, the Republican-controlled House of Representatives, the Democratic- controlled Senate, and President Barack Obama finally agreed on a compromise to increase the debt ceiling just hours before a federal payment default. The divided government produced by the 2010 election proved able to cope with this issue, but only when faced with a major economic crisis. This recent story perfectly exemplifies how law-making is affected by divided government.
    [Show full text]
  • AP® Government and Politics: United States Balance of Power Between Congress and the President
    PROFESSIONAL DEVELOPMENT AP® Government and Politics: United States Balance of Power Between Congress and the President Special Focus The College Board: Connecting Students to College Success The College Board is a not-for-profit membership association whose mission is to connect students to college success and opportunity. Founded in 1900, the association is composed of more than 5,400 schools, colleges, universities, and other educational organizations. Each year, the College Board serves seven million students and their parents, 23,000 high schools, and 3,500 colleges through major programs and services in college admissions, guidance, assessment, financial aid, enrollment, and teaching and learning. Among its best-known programs are the SAT®, the PSAT/NMSQT®, and the Advanced Placement Program® (AP®). The College Board is committed to the principles of excellence and equity, and that commitment is embodied in all of its programs, services, activities, and concerns. For further information, visit www.collegeboard.com. The College Board acknowledges all the third-party content that has been included in these materials and respects the intellectual property rights of others. If we have incorrectly attributed a source or overlooked a publisher, please contact us. © 2008 The College Board. All rights reserved. College Board, Advanced Placement Program, AP, AP Vertical Teams, connect to college success, Pre-AP, SAT, and the acorn logo are registered trademarks of the College Board. PSAT/NMSQT is a registered trademark of the College Board and National Merit Scholarship Corporation. All other products and services may be trademarks of their respective owners. Visit the College Board on the Web: www.collegeboard.com.
    [Show full text]
  • Constitutional Restriction of International Agreements in France Gerald L
    \\jciprod01\productn\C\CIN\45-2\CIN201.txt unknown Seq: 1 2-MAY-12 14:39 The Brakes that Failed: Constitutional Restriction of International Agreements in France Gerald L. Neuman† Can constitutions successfully constrain the exercise of the treaty power? This article examines the French Constitution of 1958 as a case study. The founders of the Fifth Republic drafted provisions intended to protect national sovereignty, as the Gaullists understood that concept, against inroads resulting from international agreements. Looking back fifty years later, it is clear that those protective efforts did not succeed. The sequence of events by which the constraints were loosened or evaded may represent one nation’s particular his- tory, but they illustrate the limited capacity of constitutional restrictions to control international commitments in the long term. I. The Constitution of the Fifth Republic.................... 259 R II. Constitutional Restrictions— In Theory ................... 263 R A. Article 55 and Treaty Enforcement ..................... 263 R B. The Uncertain Legacy of the 1946 Preamble ........... 265 R C. Article 54 and Treaty Ratification ...................... 267 R III. Constitutional Restrictions— In Practice................... 271 R A. Prior to the 1992 Maastricht Amendment .............. 273 R 1. Article 54: Procedure ............................... 273 R 2. Article 54: Substance ............................... 278 R a. Step One...................................... 279 R b. The Crossroads of 1976 ....................... 281 R c. The Road to Maastricht ........................ 289 R d. The First Maastricht Decision.................. 294 R e. The Distance Traveled ......................... 299 R f. Postscript: Maastricht II and III ................ 300 R 3. The Reconstruction of Article 55 .................... 304 R a. Article 55 and Subsequent Statutes ............ 304 R † J. Sinclair Armstrong Professor of International, Foreign, and Comparative Law, Harvard Law School.
    [Show full text]
  • Post-Communist Romania: a Peculiar Case of Divided Government Manolache, Cristina
    www.ssoar.info Post-communist Romania: a peculiar case of divided government Manolache, Cristina Veröffentlichungsversion / Published Version Zeitschriftenartikel / journal article Empfohlene Zitierung / Suggested Citation: Manolache, C. (2013). Post-communist Romania: a peculiar case of divided government. Studia Politica: Romanian Political Science Review, 13(3), 427-440. https://nbn-resolving.org/urn:nbn:de:0168-ssoar-448327 Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Dieser Text wird unter einer CC BY-NC-ND Lizenz This document is made available under a CC BY-NC-ND Licence (Namensnennung-Nicht-kommerziell-Keine Bearbeitung) zur (Attribution-Non Comercial-NoDerivatives). For more Information Verfügung gestellt. Nähere Auskünfte zu den CC-Lizenzen finden see: Sie hier: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0 https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/deed.de Post-Communist Romania 427 Post-Communist Romania A Peculiar Case of Divided Government CRISTINA MANOLACHE If for the most part of its post-communist history, Romania experienced a form of unified government based on political coalitions and alliances which resulted in conflictual relations between the executive and the legislative and even among the dualist executive itself, it should come as no surprise that the periods of divided government are marked by strong confrontations which have culminated with two failed suspension attempts. The main form of divided government in Romania is that of cohabitation, and it has been experienced only twice, for a brief period of time: in 2007-2008 under Prime-Minister Călin Popescu Tăriceanu of the National Liberal Party and again, starting May 2012, under Prime Minister Victor Ponta of the Social Democratic Party.
    [Show full text]
  • Separation of Powers: an Overview
    Separation of Powers: An Overview Matthew E. Glassman Analyst on the Congress January 8, 2016 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R44334 Separation of Powers: An Overview Summary Congress’s role and operation in national politics is fundamentally shaped by the design and structure of the governing institution in the Constitution. One of the key principles of the Constitution is separation of powers. The doctrine is rooted in a political philosophy that aims to keep power from consolidating in any single person or entity, and a key goal of the framers of the Constitution was to establish a governing system that diffused and divided power. These objectives were achieved institutionally through the design of the Constitution. The legislative, executive, and judicial branches of the government were assigned distinct and limited roles under the Constitution, and required to be comprised of different political actors. The constitutional structure does not, however, insulate the branches from each other. While the design of the Constitution aims, through separation, to prevent the centralization of power, it also seeks the same objective through diffusion. Thus, most powers granted under the Constitution are not unilateral for any one branch; instead they overlap. The constitutional structure of separation of powers invites conflict between the branches, particularly between Congress and the President. The electoral structure of the federal government provides not only separate bases of authority, but also different bases of authority for political actors, as well as different time horizons. Likewise, the assignment of powers under the Constitution is not only overlapping, but also somewhat vague, creating inter-branch contests for power across many key functions of the government.
    [Show full text]
  • Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive and Mixed Authority
    French Politics, 2005, 3, (323–351) r 2005 Palgrave Macmillan Ltd 1476-3419/05 $30.00 www.palgrave-journals.com/fp Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive And Mixed Authority Patterns Matthew Søberg Shugart Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, San Diego, USA. E-mail: [email protected] Maurice Duverger in 1980 advanced the concept of a ‘semi-presidential’ regime: a mix of a popularly elected and powerful presidency with a prime minister heading a cabinet subject to assembly confidence.We can understand the performance of these regimes through a neo-Madisonian perspective that stresses agency relations between institutional actors.Executive and legislature as separate agents of the electorate — as in presidentialism — necessitates transactional interbranch relations.Fusion of powers — as in parliamentarism — means an executive that is hierarchically subordinated to the legislature.The dual executive of a semi- presidential system mixes a transactional executive-legislative relationship with a hierarchical one.The advantages of this perspective include allowing delinea- tion of semi-presidentialism from other hybrids, highlighting subtypes (premier- presidential and president-parliamentary) according to variations in the locus of transactional and hierarchical institutional relationships, and predicting which observed relationships between actors derive from relatively immutable constitutional features and which from more transitory features such as partisan alignments. French Politics
    [Show full text]
  • The Bicameral Roots of Congressional Deadlock: Analyzing Divided Government Through the Lens of Majority Rule William Bianco
    The Bicameral Roots of Congressional Deadlock: Analyzing Divided Government Through the Lens of Majority Rule William Bianco Regina Smyth Indiana University January 2015 Abstract It is widely argued that a primary source of legislative deadlock in America is the combination of a secular increase in polarization, combined with constitutional provisions that divide law-making power across branches. However, empirical tests have yielded mixed results. Our premise is that polarization affects productivity, but only given a particular pattern of divided government. We distinguish between split branches, where a President from one party faces a Congress controlled by the other, and split chambers, where each party controls one house of Congress. We show that show that enactments of major legislation are less likely given split chambers compared to the other options – and that polarization has no impact after controlling for these factors. These results redefine the conditions under which polarization drives deadlock. They also explain why the increase in polarization over the last two decades has until recently had little impact on major enactments. Word Count: 7197 For most Congress scholars, descriptions of recent congressional terms as “the least productive body in a generation,” “the most ineffectual in history,” and "the laziest Congress ever,”(Steinhauer 2012, Klein and Soltas 2013, Halperin 2014) are no surprise. It is widely argued that a primary source of legislative deadlock is the combination of a secular increase in the polarization of American political parties, combined with constitutional provisions that divide power between the legislative and executive branches, and establish a system of elections that allows divided partisan control.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 DIVIDED GOVERNMENT and the RATIFICATION of the AMSTERDAM TREATY Simon Hug University of Texas at Austin Thomas König Universi
    DIVIDED GOVERNMENT AND THE RATIFICATION OF THE AMSTERDAM TREATY Simon Hug University of Texas at Austin Thomas König University of Konstanz 1 Introduction The member countries of the European Union (EU) signed the treaty of Amsterdam on October 2, 1997. It amended the Treaty on European Union (TEU) and the three Community Treaties. The most noteworthy modifications concerned the six areas of citizenship, justice and home affairs, employment, the environment, agricultural and fishing and a common foreign and security policy (Langrish 1998, 3). Compared to the Maastricht treaty, these modifications were less ambitious on European integration, because member states excluded half of the issues of the draft proposal to find consensus at the Amsterdam intergovernmental conference (Hug and König forthcoming). According to Moravcsik and Nicolaidis (1999a, 70), governments widely circulated the draft proposal for the intergovernmental conference ". to minimize the possibility of subsequent ratification failures." If this is correct, the Amsterdam intergovernmental conference (IGC) provides a powerful illustration of the influence domestic ratification constraints may have on the bargaining process of international cooperation. These effects of domestic ratification constraints on international cooperation have become increasingly under the theoretical scrutiny of scholars. According to Pahre (this book) two perspectives can be distinguished: Ever since Putnam's (1988) seminal article "Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: the logic of two-level games" scholars have paid more attention to studying Schelling's (1960) "Paradox of Weakness." Authors adopting this perspective (e.g., Iida 1993 and 1996, Mo 1994 and 1995, Schneider and Cederman 1994, Milner and Rosendorff 1996, Pahre 1997) examine whether governments, which are more restricted by domestic ratification constraints, perform better in international negotiations than their domestically less restricted counterparts.
    [Show full text]