Average-Cost Pricing, Increasing Returns, and Optimal Output in a Model with Home and Market Production

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Average-Cost Pricing, Increasing Returns, and Optimal Output in a Model with Home and Market Production Average-cost pricing, increasing returns, and optimal output in a model with home and market production Yew-Kwang Ng Dept. of Economics, Monash University Email: [email protected] Dingsheng Zhang Dept. of Economics, Monash University Institute for Advanced Economic Studies, Wuhan University [email protected] Abstract The analysis of economies of specialization at the individual level by Yang & Shi (1992) and Yang & Ng (1993) is combined with the Dixit & Stiglitz (1977) analysis of monopolistic-competitive firms to show that, ignoring administrative costs and indirect effects (such as rent-seeking), even if both the home and the market sectors are produced under conditions of increasing returns and there are no pre- existing taxes, it is still efficient to tax the home sector to finance a subsidy on the market sector to offset the under-production of the latter due to the failure of price- taking consumers to take account of the effects of higher consumption in reducing the average costs and hence prices, through increasing returns or the publicness nature of fixed costs. Within market production, it is efficient to subsidise more the sector with a higher fixed cost, a lower elasticity of substitution between goods, and a lower degree of importance in preference which all increases the degree of increasing returns. Keywords: increasing returns, average-cost pricing, monopolistic competition, home production, optimal output, fixed costs. JEL Classifications: D43, H21, L11. 1 Average-cost pricing, increasing returns, and optimal output in a model with home and market production The issue of increasing returns is one of those that will be raised incessantly as a neat general solution is lacking and many different outcomes are possible. Increasing returns are also prevalent in the real economy. Arrow (1995) explains how the relevance of information and knowledge in production makes increasing returns prevalent. (See also Wilson 1975, Radner & Stiglitz 1984, Arthur 1994. On empirical evidence for increasing returns, see Ades & Glaeser 1999, Antweiler & Trefler 2002.) Recent interest in the topic has also been considerable, as witnessed by a number of collected volumes (Arrow, et al. 1998, Buchanan & Yoon 1994a, Heal 1999.)1 A model much used in the analysis is one developed by Dixit & Stiglitz (1977) with symmetrical monopolistic competitive firms with free entry and produced with a fixed cost and a constant marginal cost. Though a special case, it reflects much of reality as much of increasing returns may be traced to some big fixed-cost components (a piece of land for farming, a factory for manufacturing production, a shop for retailing, learning costs for many skilled activities, etc.) and the variable costs (raw materials, intermediate goods purchased, stocks ordered, etc.) are largely constant within a wide range. While this model captures much of increasing returns at the firm level, those at the economy level arising from the economies of specialization made possible by the division of labor are analysed by Yang & Ng (1993). This latter framework starts from the most basic level of individual decisions on what activities (home production, trade, employment, consumption, etc.) to undertake to maximize utility and the interaction of the activities of individuals and their implications on economic organization, trade, growth, etc. Though the emergence of firms and other issues (including the choice of the variety of products; see Yang & Shi 1992) are also analysed, the economies of specialization is taken to be confined to the individual level. In principle, one may use this framework to 1 For a survey of the earlier literature on the economics of product variety which is related to monopolistic competition and increasing returns, see Lancaster (1990). 2 model the increasing returns at the firm level through the complicated interaction between different individuals within the firm and their interaction with other factors employed by the firm, but the complication involved may raise issues of manageability. There are also models that analyse the increasing returns from employing production methods with more intermediate goods (e.g. Ethier 1979, Romer 1986, Buchanan & Yoon 1994b). However, there are advantages in directly allowing for increasing returns at the firm level from the fixed-cost components as in the Dixit-Stiglitz model. Moreover, the majority of production in most advanced economies is undertaken by firms with increasing returns prevailing over the whole relevant range of production, but also with individual home production still taking place. The present paper combines the analysis of economies of specialization at the individual level by Yang & Shi (1992) and Yang & Ng (1993) with the Dixit & Stiglitz (1977) analysis of the market production by monopolistic-competitive firms. (For an earlier model combining home production with market production by firms emphasizing the role of the number of intermediate goods and different stages of production, see Locay 1990. Here, the complications due to intermediate goods and stages in production are ignored.) It is hoped that this combination moves a step closer to the real economy with both home and firm/market production. The model developed in Section 1 below could be used to analyse problems other than those discussed in this paper. It is shown in Section 1 that, even if both the home and the market sectors are produced under conditions of increasing returns and there are no pre-existing taxes (including income taxes) on the market sector, it is still efficient to tax the home sector to finance a subsidy on the market sector to offset the under-production of the latter. The home sector is not under-produced because the increasing returns there are fully taken into account by the individuals/households. In the production by firms for the market, as the output is priced at average cost and each consumer takes the price as given, the effect of higher consumption in reducing the price through increasing returns is not taken into account. Viewed differently, the fixed cost of production possesses the publicness characteristic, causing under-production. However, the 3 taxation of the home sector may not be practically feasible. Section 2 allows market production to have two sectors and shows that it is efficient to tax the sector with a lower fixed cost, a higher elasticity of substitution between goods, and a higher degree of importance in preference (as all these factors contribute to a lower degree of increasing returns) and subsidize the other sector. Qualifications on the applicability of these results in the real economy are discussed in the concluding section. 1. A model with home and market production 1.1 The model Consider an economy with M identical consumers. Each of them has the following decision problem for consumption, working, and home production. α β 1−α−β ρ1 ρ1 ρ2 ρ2 (1) Max: u = l [∑ xr ] [∑ x j ] (utility function) r∈R j∈J s.t. ∑ pr xr = w(1−l − ∑l j ) (budget constraint) r∈R j∈J l − a x = j (home production function) j c where pr is the price of good r which are market goods, w is the price of labour, xr is the amount of good r that is purchased from the market, R is the set of market goods, xj is the amount of good j which is home good, lj is the amount of labour used in producing home good j, a<1 is the fixed cost of producing a home good, c is the marginal cost in home production, J is the set of home goods, l is leisure, (1− l − ∑l j ) is the amount of labour hired by firms, ρi ∈(0,1) (open interval) is the j∈J parameter of elasticity of substitution between each pair of consumption goods, α , β are preference parameters, and u is the utility level. It is assumed that each consumer is endowed with one unit of labour, which is the numeraire, so w =1. Each consumer is a price taker and her decision variables are l, lj and xr. It is assumed that the elasticity of substitution 1/(1-ρi) > 1RU! !i >0 for both i = 1, 2. 4 Denoting the number of home goods as m, by symmetry, the budget constraint can be rewritten as follow: (2) ∑ pr xr + mlh + l =1 r∈R where lh is labor used in the production of each home good. )URPWKH/DJUDQJHDQIXQFWLRQ/ ZKHUH LVXVHGDVWKHPXOWLSOLHU RIWKHDERYH maximization problem, the first-order conditions2 are: α −1 β ∂L 1−α−β ρ1 ρ1 ρ1−1 ρ2 lh − a β (3) = 0 ⇒ αl [∑ xr ] xr m ( ) = λ pr ∂xr r∈R c α β −1 ∂L β 1−α−β ρ1 ρ1 ρ2 lh − a β (4) = 0 ⇒ l [∑ xr ] m ( ) = λlh ∂m ρ2 r∈R c α β ∂L 1−α−β ρ1 ρ1 ρ2 lh − a β −1 (5) = 0 ⇒ βl [∑ xr ] m ( ) = cλm ∂lh r∈R c α β ∂L −α−β ρ1 ρ1 ρ2 lh − a β (6) = 0 ⇒ (1−α − β )l [∑ xr ] m ( ) = λ ∂l r∈R c ∂L (2) = 0 ⇒ ∑ pr xr + mlh + l =1 ∂λ r∈R Using (2)-(6), we can get following solutions a (7) lh = 1− ρ2 ρ (1−α − β) (8) l = 2 ρ2 + β(1− ρ2) β (1− ρ ) (9) m = 2 a[ρ2 + β (1− ρ2 )] αρ2 (10) x = ρ r 1 n 1 1−ρ ρ −1 1 1 [ρ2 + β(1− ρ2)]pr (∑ ps ) s=1 where n is the number of market goods. 2 It may be checked that second-order conditions are satisfied. 5 Before we consider the behaviour of firms, we first get the own price elasticity of demand for good r, using (10), we have ∂ln x ρ − n (11) r = 1 ∂ln pr n(1− ρ1) This formula is called Yang-Heijdra formula ( Yang and heijdra, 1993).
Recommended publications
  • Suggested Answers Problem Set 3 Health Economics
    Suggested Answers Problem Set 3 Health Economics Bill Evans Spring 2013 1. Please see the final page of the answer key for the graph. To determine the market clearing level of quantity, set inverse supply equal to inverse demand and solve for Q. 40 + 4Q = 400 - 8Q, so 360=12Q or Q=30. Initial equilibrium is point a below. Substitute this back into either inverse demand or supply and solve for P, P=40+4Q = 40+4(30) = 160. CS = 0.5(400-160)(30) = 3600. PS = 0.5(160-40)(30) = 1800. 2. Given the externality, the MSC= 52+4Q. The socially optimal output is where MSC=Inverse demand, 52+4Q = 400 - 8Q and therefore Q=29. Market clearing price should be P=400 - 8Q = 400 - 8(29) = 168 (point b). Because of the externality, market production is greater than socially optimal. The social cost of producing Q=30 is MSC = 52+4Q = 172. Since the externality is not internalized, consumers receive a benefit of dbae. The social cost is dbce. Therefore, deadweight loss is abc. This value is 0.5(1)(12) = 6. 3. The market equilibrium is determined by setting inverse supply equal to inverse demand and solving for Q: 8+2Q = 80 - Q, so 72=3Q so Q=24. Price would equal 8+2(24) = 56. The MSB=80-2Q so the socially optimal consumption would be at the point where inverse supply equals MSB, or 8+2Q = 80-2Q so 72=4Q or Q=18. Suppliers would supply this amount at a price of 8+2Q = 8+2(18) = 44.
    [Show full text]
  • An Overview of US Blueberry Production, Trade, and Consumption, with Special Reference to Florida1 Edward A
    FE952 An Overview of US Blueberry Production, Trade, and Consumption, with Special Reference to Florida1 Edward A. Evans and Fredy H. Ballen2 Introduction the total production of blueberries was traded in the world market. Blueberry is cultivated commercially in about 27 countries worldwide, most of which are located in temperate zones. Between 2002 and 2011, world blueberry production grew at an annual rate of 5.45 percent, from 230,769 tonnes in 2002 to 356,533 tonnes in 2011. Blueberry production in 2011 was 13.66 percent higher than in the previous year, and 54.50 percent above the 2002 calendar year. The top five blueberry producers are the United States, Canada, Poland, Mexico, and Germany, respectively (FAOSTAT 2013a). The United States is by far the largest blueberry producer, with a production share of 56.07 percent between 2009 and 2011, followed by Canada (30.29%), Poland (2.92%), Germany (2.5%), and Mexico (0.94%). Between 2001 and 2010, global exports of blueberry more than doubled, from 53,232 tonnes in 2001 to over 113,000 tonnes in 2010 (FAOSTAT 2013b). During this same period, export value grew from $119.29 million in 2001 to $370.97 million in 2010. The top five exporters are the United States, Canada, Poland, the Netherlands, and Spain, respectively. The United States accounted for 50.94 Global blueberry imports grew from 49,224 tonnes in percent of the world exports from 2008 to 2010, followed by 2002 to over 113,000 tonnes in 2010. The United States is Canada (25.89%), Poland (6.78%), the Netherlands (5.44%), the largest importer, absorbing 63.30 percent of the global and Spain (1.74%).
    [Show full text]
  • A Framework for Nonmarket Accounting
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: A New Architecture for the U.S. National Accounts Volume Author/Editor: Dale W. Jorgenson, J. Steven Landefeld, and William D. Nordhaus, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-41084-6 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/jorg06-1 Conference Date: April 16-17, 2004 Publication Date: May 2006 Title: A Framework for Nonmarket Accounting Author: Katharine G. Abraham, Christopher Mackie URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c0136 4 A Framework for Nonmarket Accounting Katharine G. Abraham and Christopher Mackie 4.1 Introduction and Motivation Since their earliest construction for the United States by Simon Kuznets in the 1930s (Kuznets 1934), concerns have been voiced that the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPAs) are incomplete. The NIPAs meet rigorous standards and enjoy broad acceptance among data users inter- ested in tracking economic activity. They are, however, primarily market based and, by design, shed little light on production in the home or in other nonmarket situations. Further, even where activity is organized in markets, important aspects of that activity may be omitted from the NIPAs. In other cases, unpaid time inputs and associated outputs are critical to production processes but, because no market transaction is associated with their pro- vision, they are not reflected in the accounts. One illustration is provided by estimates (LaPlante, Harrington, and Kang 2002) suggesting that the Katharine G. Abraham is a professor of survey methodology and adjunct professor of eco- nomics at the University of Maryland and a research associate of the National Bureau of Eco- nomic Research.
    [Show full text]
  • Of National Price Controls in the European Economic Community
    COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES The effects of national price controls in the European Economic Community COMPETITION - APPROXIMATION OF LEGISLATION SERIES - 1970 - 9 I The effects of national price controls in the European Economic Community Research Report by Mr. Horst Westphal, Dipl. Rer. Pol. Director of Research: Professor Dr. Harald JOrgensen Director, Institute of European Economic Policy, University of Hamburg Hamburg 1968 STUDIES Competition-Approximation of legislation series No. 9 Brussels 1970 INTRODUCTION BY THE COMMISSION According to the concept underlying the European Treaties, the prices of goods and services are usually formed by market economy principles, independent of State intervention. This statement only has to be qualified for certain fields where the market economy "laws" either cannot provide a yardstick of scarcity at all or cannot do so to the best economic and social effect. The EEC Treaty contains no specific price rules. As against this., the Member States take numerous price formation and price control measures whose methods and intensity are hard to determine. These measures pursuant to price laws and regulations are generally considered to include all direct price control measures taken by the State-in particular those described as "close to the market". Such measures have many legal forms-maximum prices, minimum prices, fixed prices, price margin and price publicity arrangements, in particular. The economic impact of State price arrangements-especially on competition policy-is complex. The present study has been rendered necessary by the varied nature of the subject matter and the extreme difficulty of ascertaining with sufficient accuracy the economic effects on the common market of varying national price laws and regulations.
    [Show full text]
  • Handbook on Price and Volume Measures in National Accounts
    HANDBOOK ON PRICE AND VOLUME MEASURES IN NATIONAL ACCOUNTS Final version, September 2001 Handbook on Price and Volume Measures in National Accounts 1. INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................................ 1 1.1. BACKGROUND AND AIM OF THIS HANDBOOK ................................................................................. 1 1.2. SCOPE OF THIS HANDBOOK........................................................................................................... 3 1.3. THE DISTINCTION BETWEEN PRICE, VOLUME, QUANTITY AND QUALITY .......................................... 4 1.4. THE A/B/C CLASSIFICATION ........................................................................................................ 5 1.5. HOW TO READ THIS HANDBOOK.................................................................................................... 6 2. A/B/C METHODS FOR GENERAL PROCEDURES ................................................................ 1 2.1. THE USE OF AN INTEGRATED APPROACH........................................................................................ 1 2.1.1. An accounting approach to constant price estimations...................................................... 1 2.1.2. Advantage of balancing constant price data...................................................................... 3 2.1.3. Valuation problems........................................................................................................... 4 2.1.4. The case of price
    [Show full text]
  • Unemployment, Market Work and Household Production
    IZA DP No. 3955 Unemployment, Market Work and Household Production Michael C. Burda Daniel S. Hamermesh DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER January 2009 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Unemployment, Market Work and Household Production Michael C. Burda Humboldt University of Berlin, CEPR and IZA Daniel S. Hamermesh University of Texas at Austin, NBER and IZA Discussion Paper No. 3955 January 2009 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post World Net. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.
    [Show full text]
  • Household Production and Consumption Proposal for a Methodology of Household Satellite Accounts
    2003 EDITION Household Production and Consumption Proposal for a Methodology of Household Satellite Accounts THEME 3 Population EUROPEAN and social COMMISSION 3conditions Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers to your questions about the European Union New freephone number: 00 800 6 7 8 9 10 11 A great deal of additional information on the European Union is available on the Internet. It can be accessed through the Europa server (http://europa.eu.int). Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 2003 ISSN 1725-065X ISBN 92-894-6049-0 © European Communities, 2003 HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION Proposal for a Methodology of Household Satellite Accounts Task force report for Eurostat, Unit E1 CONTENTS PREFACE .......................................................................................................... 3 1. INTRODUCTION............................................................................................... 4 2. PURPOSES AND USES OF HHSA ................................................................... 6 3. PRODUCTION BOUNDARIES IN NATIONAL ACCOUNTS AND IN THE HHSA ................................................................................................................. 7 3.1 General production boundary ................................................................. 7 3.2 SNA production boundary....................................................................... 7 3.3 Production covered by the HHSA............................................................ 8
    [Show full text]
  • Market Power, Production (Mis)Allocation and OPEC∗
    Market Power, Production (Mis)Allocation and OPEC∗ John Asker Allan Collard-Wexler Jan De Loecker UCLA Duke University KU Leuven and Princeton University NBER NBER NBER and CEPR October 18, 2017 Abstract This paper estimates the extent to which market power is a source of production misal­ location. Productive inefficiency occurs through more production being allocated to higher- cost units of production, and less production to lower-cost production units, conditional on a fixed aggregate quantity. We rely on rich micro-data covering the global market for crude oil, from 1970 to 2014, to quantify the extent of productive misallocation attributable to mar­ ket power exerted by the OPEC. We find substantial productive inefficiency attributable to market power, ranging from 14.1 percent to 21.9 percent of the total productive inefficiency, or 105 to 163 billion USD. Key words: Market Power, Productive Inefficiency, Misallocation, Cartels, Oil, OPEC. JEL Code: D2, L1, L4, L72 ∗We would like to thank Russell Cooper, Martin Hackmann, Volker Nocke, Michael Whinston, Rob Porter, and Jo Van Biesebroeck, and participants in various seminars and conferences for their comments. Excellent research assis­ tance was provided for by El Hadi Caoui, Ardis Zhong, Sherry Wu and Yilin Jiang. Financial Assistance from Prince­ ton University’s Industrial Organization Group, NSF (SPS #220783) and FWO Odysseus Grant is greatly appreci­ ated. Contact information: [email protected], [email protected] and [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction Market Power and Aggregate Welfare In this paper we re-evaluate the following statement of Harberger describing the state-of­ affairs in ?When we are interested in the big picture of our manufacturing economy, we need not apologize for treating it as competitive, for in fact it is awfully close to being so.
    [Show full text]
  • Homework in Monetary Economics: Inflation, Home Production, and the Production of Homes
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEWORK IN MONETARY ECONOMICS: INFLATION, HOME PRODUCTION, AND THE PRODUCTION OF HOMES S. Boragan Aruoba Morris A. Davis Randall Wright Working Paper 18276 http://www.nber.org/papers/w18276 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 2012 We thank many friends and colleagues for helpful input, especially Chrisophe Andre, Jeff Campbell, Larry Christiano, Marcello Veracierto, Yu Zhu, and Gwen Eudey. Aruoba and Wright also thank the NSF, Davis and Wright thank the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, and Wright thanks the Ray Zemon Chair in Liquid Assets at the Wisconsin School of Business for research support. The usual disclaimer applies. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2012 by S. Boragan Aruoba, Morris A. Davis, and Randall Wright. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Homework in Monetary Economics: Inflation, Home Production, and the Production of Homes S. Boragan Aruoba, Morris A. Davis, and Randall Wright NBER Working Paper No. 18276 August 2012 JEL No. E41,E52,R21 ABSTRACT We study models incorporating money, household production, and investment in housing. Inflation, as a tax on market activity, encourages substitution into household production, and thus investment in household capital.
    [Show full text]
  • GDP As a Measure of Economic Well-Being
    Hutchins Center Working Paper #43 August 2018 GDP as a Measure of Economic Well-being Karen Dynan Harvard University Peterson Institute for International Economics Louise Sheiner Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy, The Brookings Institution The authors thank Katharine Abraham, Ana Aizcorbe, Martin Baily, Barry Bosworth, David Byrne, Richard Cooper, Carol Corrado, Diane Coyle, Abe Dunn, Marty Feldstein, Martin Fleming, Ted Gayer, Greg Ip, Billy Jack, Ben Jones, Chad Jones, Dale Jorgenson, Greg Mankiw, Dylan Rassier, Marshall Reinsdorf, Matthew Shapiro, Dan Sichel, Jim Stock, Hal Varian, David Wessel, Cliff Winston, and participants at the Hutchins Center authors’ conference for helpful comments and discussion. They are grateful to Sage Belz, Michael Ng, and Finn Schuele for excellent research assistance. The authors did not receive financial support from any firm or person with a financial or political interest in this article. Neither is currently an officer, director, or board member of any organization with an interest in this article. ________________________________________________________________________ THIS PAPER IS ONLINE AT https://www.brookings.edu/research/gdp-as-a- measure-of-economic-well-being ABSTRACT The sense that recent technological advances have yielded considerable benefits for everyday life, as well as disappointment over measured productivity and output growth in recent years, have spurred widespread concerns about whether our statistical systems are capturing these improvements (see, for example, Feldstein, 2017). While concerns about measurement are not at all new to the statistical community, more people are now entering the discussion and more economists are looking to do research that can help support the statistical agencies. While this new attention is welcome, economists and others who engage in this conversation do not always start on the same page.
    [Show full text]
  • International Trade and Labor Markets: Unemployment, Inequality and Redistribution
    International Trade and Labor Markets: Unemployment, Inequality and Redistribution A dissertation presented by Oleg Itskhoki to The Department of Economics in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the subject of Economics Harvard University Cambridge, Massachusetts April 2009 c 2009 { Oleg Itskhoki All rights reserved. Dissertation Advisor: Professor Elhanan Helpman Oleg Itskhoki International Trade and Labor Markets: Unemployment, Inequality and Redistribution International trade is typically believed to lead to aggregate welfare gains for trading countries. However, it is also often viewed as a source of growing social disparity|by causing unemployment and greater inequality within countries|which calls for an offset- ting policy response. This dissertation consists of three theoretical essays studying these issues. The first chapter develops a model of international trade with labor market frictions that differ across countries. We show that differences in labor market institutions con- stitute a source of comparative advantage and lead to trade between otherwise similar countries. Although trade ensures aggregate welfare gains for both countries, the more flexible country stands to gain proportionately more. An increase in the country's labor market flexibility leads to welfare gains at home, but causes welfare losses in the trading partner via decreased competitiveness of foreign firms. Trade can increase or decrease unemployment by inducing an intersectoral labor reallocation generating rich patterns of unemployment. The second chapter proposes a new framework for thinking about the distributional consequences of trade that incorporates firm and worker heterogeneity, search and match- ing frictions in the labor market, and screening of workers by firms.
    [Show full text]
  • 2020 Summer Quarterly Markets Report Page Ii ISO-NE PUBLIC Preface
    Summer 2020 Quarterly Markets Report By ISO New England’s Internal Market Monitor © ISO New England Inc. NOVEMBER 11, 2020 ISO-NE PUBLIC [Intentionally blank] 2020 Summer Quarterly Markets Report page ii ISO-NE PUBLIC Preface The Internal Market Monitor (“IMM”) of ISO New England Inc. (the “ISO”) publishes a Quarterly Markets Report that assesses the state of competition in the wholesale electricity markets operated by the ISO. The report addresses the development, operation, and performance of the wholesale electricity markets and presents an assessment of each market based on market data, performance criteria, and independent studies. This report fulfills the requirement of Market Rule 1, Appendix A, Section III.A.17.2.2, Market Monitoring, Reporting, and Market Power Mitigation: The Internal Market Monitor will prepare a quarterly report consisting of market data regularly collected by the Internal Market Monitor in the course of carrying out its functions under this Appendix A and analysis of such market data. Final versions of such reports shall be disseminated contemporaneously to the Commission, the ISO Board of Directors, the Market Participants, and state public utility commissions for each of the six New England states, provided that in the case of the Market Participants and public utility commissions, such information shall be redacted as necessary to comply with the ISO New England Information Policy. The format and content of the quarterly reports will be updated periodically through consensus of the Internal Market Monitor, the Commission, the ISO, the public utility commissions of the six New England States and Market Participants. The entire quarterly report will be subject to confidentiality protection consistent with the ISO New England Information Policy and the recipients will ensure the confidentiality of the information in accordance with state and federal laws and regulations.
    [Show full text]