Lucas Critique, Time Inconsistency, and Related Issues

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Lucas Critique, Time Inconsistency, and Related Issues Leigh Tesfatsion (Prof. of Econ, Iowa State University, Ames, IA 50011-1070) Last Updated: 1 January 2018 Course Site for Econ 502 (M.S. Macro Theory) http://www2.econ.iastate.edu/classes/econ502/tesfatsion/ Introduction to Rational Expectations: http://www2.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/reintro.pdf Notes on the Lucas Critique, Time Inconsistency, and Related Issues: http://www2.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/LucCrit.pdf Notes on the Lucas Critique, Time Inconsistency, and Related Issues 1 Preliminary Remarks on Government Policy Rules Consider an economy that exists over time periods t = 1; 2;:::, where period t is the interval from t to t + 1. Let It−1 denote the information set available to government at the beginning of period t (i.e., at the end of period t − 1). Let ht denote a possible policy choice vector for government in period t, where the components of ht might include tax rates, a target growth rate for the money supply, and so forth. Definition: Let I denote the collection of all possible government information sets, and let H denote the collection of all possible policy choice vectors. Then a sequence (h1; h2;:::) of government policy choice vectors ht is said to be chosen in accordance with a (determin- istic) policy rule1 if there exists some well-defined function g:I! H mapping information 1For simplicity of exposition, only deterministic policy rules are considered in this section, that is, policy rules that map each possible information state I for each period t into a single policy choice vector g(I) for period t. An alternative stochastic form would be for each possible information state I for period t to be mapped into a probability distribution PI (h) over feasible policy choice vectors h for period t. In either case, however, notice that the presumption that a government uses a single policy rule g over times t = 1; 2;::: means this government does not engage in learning; it already knows at time 1 what action(s) it will take in each possible information state in each period t ≥ 1. 1 sets into policy choice vectors such that ht = g(It−1) ; t = 1; 2;:::: (1) The policy rule g:I! H is said to be a feedback policy rule if it depends nontrivially on the information sets, i.e., if there exist information sets I∗ and I∗∗ in I such that g(I∗) is not equal to g(I∗∗). Otherwise it is said to be a fixed policy rule. If government implements a sequence (h1; h2; ···) of policy choice vectors that does not satisfy (1) for any well-defined function g:I! H, then government is said to be engaging in discretionary policy choice. Example: Optimal Policy Rule Selection via a Social Welfare Function The following example illustrates the way in which government policy choice problems were commonly represented in articles stressing microfoundations of macro prior to the ra- tional expectations debate beginning in the early nineteen seventies, and are still represented in many microfoundations of macro articles today. The framework, originally due to Nobel Laureate Jan Tinbergen (1967), will hereafter be referred to as the Tinbergen framework for government policy choice. For each t = 1;:::;T , let xt−1 be a vector describing the state of an economy at the o beginning of period t, where x0 is exogenously given in period 1. Also, let It−1 = (xt−1;I ) 2 I denote the information set available to government at the beginning of period t, where o the contents of I are clarified below. Finally, let H(It−1) ⊆ H denote the subset of policy choice vectors ht in H that are feasible for government to choose in period t, conditional on government's information set It−1. Assume the motion of the state of the economy over time is described by a system of state equations of the form xt = S(ht; vt; xt−1) ; t = 1;:::;T; (2) where vt denotes a vector of time-t stochastic shock terms and v = (v1; : : : ; vT ) in V is determined in accordance with a probability distribution function P (v) over V . For example, 2 the period-t state equation (2) might represent the period-t equations for a stochastic variant of a dynamic IS-LM model conditioned on a vector ht of government fiscal and monetary policy variables. Suppose that social welfare for the economy over periods 1 through T is measured in period 1 by a utilitarian social welfare function T X t W (h; v; x) = β Ut(ht; vt; xt−1) ; (3) t=1 where h = (h1; : : : ; hT ), x = (x0; : : : ; xT −1), Ut(·) denotes the utility function of a repre- sentative consumer in period t, and βt denotes the discount applied to this representative consumer in period t from the vantage point of the beginning of period 1. Call g:I! H a feasible policy rule for government if g(It−1) is an element of H(It−1) for each t = 1;:::;T . Suppose the problem facing government at the beginning of period 1 is to choose a feasible policy rule for generating h = (h1; : : : ; hT ) over periods 1;:::;T that maximizes expected social welfare subject to (2), conditional on the period-1 information set o o I0 = (x0;I ), where I contains the structure of the state equations (2), the form of the prob- ability distribution function P (v), and the form of the the social welfare function W (h; v; x). Formally, then, government's optimization problem in period 1 takes the following form: Maximize expected social welfare Z E [W (h; v; x)jI0] = W (h; v; x)P (dv) (4) V with respect to the choice of h = (h1; : : : ; hT ) subject to xt = S(ht; vt; xt−1) ; t = 1;:::;T ; (5) ht 2 H(It−1) ; t = 1;:::;T ; (6) o It−1 = (xt−1;I ) ; t = 1;:::;T ; (7) x0 =x ¯0 : (8) 3 By construction, the solution of this stochastic optimization problem is a feasible policy ∗ rule g :I! H that determines how a particular policy vector ht should be chosen from H(It−1) in each period t = 1;:::;T , given the dynamic state equations (5) that reveal how a choice of ht in period t affects all current and future states of the economy. Such recur- sively structured problems are often solved numerically by means of \dynamic programming" methods; see Ljungqvist and Sargent (2004). In this engineering view of government policy optimization, the economy is a machine. Once the econometrician discovers the true structure of the machine as represented by the state function S(ht; vt; xt−1) and the shock probability distribution P (v), and a social con- sensus is reached concerning the appropriate specification for the social welfare function W (h; v; x) and the feasible policy choice sets H(It−1), the government can optimally control the machine by pressing the right buttons (selecting the right policy rule g). 2 The Lucas Critique Definition: Estimated functional forms obtained for an economic model are said to be deep (or structural) if they are invariant to announced or perceived changes in government policy rules.2 In particular, when unknown functional forms are replaced by functions that are assumed known up to unknown parameter values, the estimated parameter values are said to be deep if they are invariant to announced or perceived changes in government policy rules. The Lucas Critique: Estimated functional forms obtained for macroeconomic models in the Keynesian tradition (e.g. dynamic IS-LM models) are not deep because these models do not correctly take into account the dependence of private agent behavior on perceived or 2Since the term \structural" already has many other meanings in economics and econometrics, henceforth only the term \deep" will be used. 4 anticipated government policy rules for generating current and future values for government policy variables. While such models may be useful for forecasting future states of the economy conditional on a given goverment policy rule, they are fatally flawed for the purpose of analyzing the effects on the economy of changes in government policy rules. Specifically, they can seriously mislead policy makers with regard to the effectiveness and desirability of their policy rule choices. The best known source for the Lucas Critique is Lucas (1976). In this study, Lucas criticizes government policy optimization frameworks, such as the Tinbergen framework illustrated above, for not taking into account the degree to which estimated functional forms fail to be deep. Note that the Lucas Critique does not presume that agents have rational expectations, although Lucas (1976) motivates this critique using only rational expectations contexts. Rather, the Lucas Critique points out a problem that can occur whenever private agent behavior depends to some degree on government policy rules and this dependence is not taken into account. For example, to carry out real-world policy analysis within a Tinbergen framework, an econometrician would first need to determine the form of the state function S(ht; vt; xt−1) on the basis of past observations. In traditional econometric practice (i.e. econometric practice prior to 1976), this estimation would have proceeded without any attention being paid to the particular government policy rules in effect at the time these observations were made that were used to generate the observed settings for policy variables.3 Once the form of this state function was estimated, it would then have been incorporated into the Tinbergen framework as if it were deep. That is, it would have been treated as a constant of the model as alternative choices of policy rules g:I ! H were considered for government.
Recommended publications
  • The Lucas Critique – Is It Really Relevant?
    Working Paper Series Department of Business & Management Macroeconomic Methodology, Theory and Economic Policy (MaMTEP) No. 7, 2016 The Lucas Critique – is it really relevant? By Finn Olesen 1 Abstract: As one of the founding fathers of what became the modern macroeconomic mainstream, Robert E. Lucas has made several important contributions. In the present paper, the focus is especially on his famous ‘Lucas critique’, which had tremendous influence on how to build macroeconomic models and how to evaluate economic policies within the modern macroeconomic mainstream tradition. However, much of this critique should not come as a total surprise to Post Keynesians as Keynes himself actually discussed many of the elements present in Lucas’s 1976 article. JEL classification: B22, B31 & E20 Key words: Lucas, microfoundations for macroeconomics, realism & Post Keynesianism I have benefitted from useful comments from Robert Ayreton Bailey Smith and Peter Skott. 2 Introduction In 1976, Robert Lucas published a contribution that since has had an enormous impact on modern macroeconomics. Based on the Lucas critique, the search for an explicit microfoundation for macroeconomic theory began in earnest. Later on, consensus regarding methodological matters between the New Classical and the New Keynesian macroeconomists emerged. That is, it was accepted that macroeconomics could only be done within an equilibrium framework with intertemporal optimising households and firms using rational expectations. As such, the representative agent was born. Accepting such a framework has of course not only theoretical consequences but also methodological ones as for instance pointed out by McCombie & Pike (2013). Not only should macroeconomics rest upon explicit and antiquated, although accepted, microeconomic axioms; macroeconomic theory also had to be formulated exclusively by use of mathematical modelling1.
    [Show full text]
  • 5. the Lucas Critique and Monetary Policy
    5. The Lucas Critique and Monetary Policy John B. Taylor, May 6, 2013 Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique • Highly influential (Nobel Prize) • Adds to the case for policy rules • Shows difficulties of econometric policy evaluation when forward-looking expectations are introduced • But it left an impression of a “mission impossible” for monetary economists – Tended to draw researchers away from monetary policy research to real business cycle models • Nevertheless it was constructive – An alternative approach suggested through three examples: • One focussed on monetary policy – inflation-unemployment tradeoff • The other two focused on fiscal policy – consumption and investment • Worth studying in the original First Derive the Inflation-Output Tradeoff Derive "aggregate supply" function : Supply yit in market i at time t is given by P c yit yit yit where P yit is "permanent" or "normal" supply c yit is "cyclical" supply Supply curve in market i c e yit ( pit pit ) pit is the log of the actual price in market i at time t e pit is the perceived (in market i) general price level in the economy at time t Find conditional expectation of general price level pit pt zit 2 pt is distributed normally with mean ptand variance 2 zit is distributed normally with mean 0 and variance Thus 2 2 pt p is distributed N t p 2 2 2 it pt e 2 2 2 pit E( pt pit , I t1 ) pt [ /( )]( pit pt ) (1 ) pit pt where 2 /( 2 2 ) Covariance divided by the variance Now, substitute the conditional expectation e pit (1 ) pit
    [Show full text]
  • The Econometrics of the Lucas Critique: Estimation and Testing of Euler Equation Models with Time-Varying Reduced-Form Coefficients
    The Econometrics of the Lucas Critique: Estimation and Testing of Euler Equation Models with Time-varying Reduced-form Coefficients Hong Li ∗y Princeton University Abstract The Lucas (1976) critique argued that the parameters of the traditional unrestricted macroeconometric models were unlikely to remain invariant in a changing economic envi- ronment. Since then, rational expectations models have become a fixture in macroeconomics Euler equations in particular. An important, though little acknowledged, implication of − the Lucas critique is that testing stability across regimes should be a natural diagnostic for the reliability of Euler equations. This paper formalizes this assertion econometrically in the framework of the classical two-step minimum distance method: The time-varying reduced- form in the first step reflects private agents' adaptation of their forecasts and behavior to the changing environment; The presumed ability of Euler conditions to deliver stable parame- ters that index tastes and technology is interpreted as a time-invariant second-step model. Within this framework, I am able to show, complementary to and independent of one an- other, both standard specification tests and stability tests are required for the evaluation of Euler equations. Moreover, this conclusion is shown to extend to other major estimation methods. Following this result, three standard investment Euler equations are submitted to examination. The empirical results tend to suggest that the standard models have not, thus far, been a success, at least for aggregate investment. JEL Classification: C13; C52; E22. Keywords: Parameter instability; Model validation testing; Classical minimum dis- tance estimation; The Lucas critique; Euler equations; Aggregate investment. ∗Department of Economics, Princeton University, NJ 08544.
    [Show full text]
  • The Lucas Critique and the Stability of Empirical Models∗
    Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ The Lucas Critique and the Stability of Empirical Models∗ Thomas A. Lubik Paolo Surico Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Bank of England and University of Bari July 2006 Working Paper No. 06-05 Abstract This paper re-considers the empirical relevance of the Lucas critique using a DSGE sticky price model in which a weak central bank response to inflation generates equilib- rium indeterminacy. The model is calibrated on the magnitude of the historical shift in the Federal Reserve’s policy rule and is capable of generating the decline in the volatility of inflation and real activity observed in U.S. data. Using Monte Carlo simulations and a backward-looking model of aggregate supply and demand, we show that shifts in the policy rule induce breaks in both the reduced-form coefficients and the reduced-form error variances. The statistics of popular parameter stability tests are shown to have low power if such heteroskedasticity is neglected. In contrast, when the instability of the reduced-form error variances is accounted for, the Lucas critique is found to be empirically relevant for both artificial and actual data. JEL Classification: C52, E38, E52. Key Words: Lucas critique, heteroskedasticity, parameter stability tests, rational expectations, indeterminacy. ∗WearegratefultoLucaBenati,AndrewBlake,Jon Faust, Jan Groen, Haroon Mumtaz, Serena Ng, Christoph Schleicher, Frank Schorfheide, Shaun Vahey and seminar participants at the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, the Bank of England, the 2006 meeting of the Society of Computational Economics, the con- ference on “Macroeconometrics and Model Uncertainty” held on 27-28 June 2006 at the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, and our discussant Timothy Kam for valuable comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Pluralism, the Lucas Critique, and the Integration of Macro and Micro
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Working Paper Pluralism, the Lucas critique, and the integration of macro and micro By Peter Skott Working Paper 2012‐04 UNIVERSITY OF MASSACHUSETTS AMHERST Pluralism, the Lucas critique, and the integration of macro and micro Peter Skotty March 6, 2012 Abstract Mainstream macroeconomics has pursued ‘micro founded’models based on the explicit optimization by representative agents. The result has been a long and wasteful detour. But elements of the Lucas critique are rele- vant, also for heterodox economists. Challenging common heterodox views on microeconomics and formalization, this paper argues that (i) economic models should not be based purely on empirically observed regularities, (ii) heterodox economists must be able to tell an integrated story about goal-oriented micro behavior in a speci…c macro environment, and (iii) relatively simple analytical models have an essential role to play. JEL codes: E1, B5 Key words: micro foundations, pluralism, old Keynesian theory, Kaleck- ian investment function. This paper is based on a presentation at the ICAPE conference, UMass, Amherst, 11 November 2011. I wish to thank Paul Auerbach, Roberto Veneziani and the participants at the conference for helpful comments. yDepartment of Economics, University of Massachusetts Amherst; [email protected] 1 Introduction There can be no single, correct theory or model of ‘the economy’. The economy is not a well-de…ned object and – even if it were – a theory does not aim to provide a complete picture of reality. As Joan Robinson noted, a map on a scale of one to one would be useless. Models and theories simplify and focus attention on speci…c aspects.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Robert Lucas (1967-1981): His Influence and Influences
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Andrada, Alexandre F.S. Article Understanding Robert Lucas (1967-1981): his influence and influences EconomiA Provided in Cooperation with: The Brazilian Association of Postgraduate Programs in Economics (ANPEC), Rio de Janeiro Suggested Citation: Andrada, Alexandre F.S. (2017) : Understanding Robert Lucas (1967-1981): his influence and influences, EconomiA, ISSN 1517-7580, Elsevier, Amsterdam, Vol. 18, Iss. 2, pp. 212-228, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econ.2016.09.001 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/179646 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ www.econstor.eu HOSTED BY Available online at www.sciencedirect.com ScienceDirect EconomiA 18 (2017) 212–228 Understanding Robert Lucas (1967-1981): his influence ଝ and influences Alexandre F.S.
    [Show full text]
  • THE LUCAS CRITIQUE and the VOLCKER DEFLATION Olivier J
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LUCAS CRITIQUE AND THE VOLCKER DEFLATION Olivier J. Blanchard Working Paper No. 1326 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 April 19814 The research reported here is part of the NBER's research program in Economic Fluctuations. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #1325 April 1984 The Lucas Critique and the Volcker Deflation ABSTRACT This paper examines, in light of the Lucas Critique, the behavior of the Phillips curve and of the term structure of interest rates after October 1 979. Itstarts with an informal account of the policy change and then discusses how we might expect these two relations to shift after such a change. It finds little evidence of a direct effect of the policy change on the Phillips curve, at least until 1982. It finds substantial evidence of a direct effect on term structure. Olivier J. Elanchard Department of Economics N. I. T. Cambridge, MA 02139 (617) 253—8891 The Lucas Critique and the Voicker Deflation by Olivjer J. Blanchard* Robert Lucas warned us in 1976 [1976] that our econometric modelswere, by their very design, likely to perform poorly in the face ofpolicy regime changes. The US econorny has in the last four years experiencedprecisely such a change, namely a change in monetary policy. Now is therefore a good time tostudy how two of the central macroeconometric equations, the Phillips curve and the term structure of interest rates, have fared during that period.
    [Show full text]
  • Expectations, Credibility, and Disinflation in a Small
    Expectations, Credibility, and Disinflation in a Small Macroeconomic Model∗ Chan G. Huh† Kevin J. Lansing‡ Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Forthcoming, Journal of Economics and Business First Draft:November 1997 This Draft:June 1, 1999 Abstract We use a version of the Fuhrer-Moore model to study the effects of expectations and central bank credibility on the economy’s dynamic transition path during a disinflation. Simulations are compared under four different specifications of the model that vary ac- cording to the way that expectations are formed (rational versus adaptive) and the degree of central bank credibility (full versus partial). The various specifications exhibit qualita- tively similar behavior and can reasonably approximate the trend movements in U.S. macro variables during the Volcker disinflation of the early 1980s. However, the specification with adaptive expectations/partial credibility is the only one to capture the temporary rise in long-term nominal interest rates observed in U.S. data at the start of the disinflation. We also show that incremental reductions in the output sacrifice ratio are largest at the low end of the credibility range, suggesting that a central bank may face diminishing returns in its efforts to enhance credibility. Keywords: Monetary Policy, Inflation, Business Cycles. JEL Classification: E31, E32, E43, E52. ∗ We thank Jeff Fuhrer for generously providing us with his computer programs and for assistance in modi- fying them for this paper. For helpful comments and suggestions, we also thank Timothy Cogley, John Judd, Athanasios Orphanides, Glenn Rudebusch, and seminar participants at FRB Cleveland, the Hoover Institution, the Federal Reserve System Macro Conference (November 1997), and an anonymous referee.
    [Show full text]
  • Trinity College Department of Economics Working Paper 12-07
    Department of Economics Trinity College Hartford, CT 06106 USA http://www.trincoll.edu/depts/econ/ TRINITY COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER 12-07 Aggregate Structural Macroeconomic Modelling: A Reconsideration and Defence Mark Setterfield* and Shyam Gouri Suresh August 2012 Abstract Aggregate structural macroeconomic modelling (ASMM) is frequently criticized for being ad hoc and justified (if at all) only as a pragmatic expedient. This paper argues instead that ASMM is consistent with the principles of well-established bodies of social theory. Appeal to these principles reveals that aggregate-level analysis of the type exemplified by ASMM is likely necessary and (in some circumstances) certainly sufficient for the successful prosecution of macroeconomic enquiry. J.E.L. Codes: B41, B22 Keywords: Macroeconomics, microfoundations, macrofoundations, aggregate structural models * Corresponding author 1. Introduction According to mainstream economic thought, the determinants of all economic outcomes are to be sought and found at the level of the individual decision maker. In macroeconomics, this thinking has found expression in the “microfoundations of macroeconomics” project. The microfoundations project is central to the “consensus view” of macroeconomics enshrined in contemporary dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models, as celebrated by authors such as Blanchard (2009) and Woodford (2009).1 At its core, the microfoundations project is a reaction against aggregate structural macroeconomic modelling (ASMM), which seeks to explain aggregate economic outcomes in terms of models based on aggregate structural and behavioural relations. The microfoundations project deems ASMM an insufficient basis for explaining aggregate outcomes, because it does not involve explicit description of the intentions and actions of the individual decision makers of which the economy as a whole is undoubtedly comprised.
    [Show full text]
  • The Marshallian Approach to Post-Walrasian Econometrics
    The Past as the Future: The Marshallian Approach to Post-Walrasian Econometrics Kevin D. Hoover Department of Economics University of California 1 Shields Avenue Davis, California 95616-8578 Tel. (530) 752-2129 Fax (530) 752-9382 E-mail [email protected] Revised, 13 October 2004 Paper prepared for the Middlebury Conference on Post Walrasian Macroeconomics, 30 April – 2 May 2004. I thank David Colander for comments on an earlier version. I. Post-Walrasian Econometrics The popular image of the scientific revolution usually pits young revolutionaries against old conservatives. Freeman Dyson (2004, p. 16) observes that, in particle physics in the mid-20th century, something had to change. But in the revolution of quantum electrodynamics, Einstein, Dirac, Heisenberg, Born, and Schödinger were old revolutionaries, while the winners, Feynman, Schwinger, and Tomonaga, were young conservatives. Post-Walrasian economics is not a doctrine, but a slogan announcing that something has to change. Most of the self-conscious efforts to forge a post-Walrasian economics are due to old radicals. Here I want to explore the space of the young conservative: the future is past, particularly in the methodology of Alfred Marshall’s methodological essay, “The Present Position of Economics” (1885). The radical approach identifies the problem as Walrasian theory and seeks to replace it with something better and altogether different. The conservative approach says that theory is not the problem. The problem is rather to establish an empirical discipline that connects theory to the world. Marshall’s methodology places the relationship between theory and empirical tools on center stage. In North America, if not in Europe, the dominant tools of macroeconometrics are the vector autoregression (VAR) and calibration techniques.
    [Show full text]
  • The Lucas Critique & Lucasianism – Considering the History Of
    The Lucas Critique & Lucasianism – Considering the History of Macroeconomics Elke Muchlinski Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaft Diskussionsbeiträge Economics 1999/01 PD Dr. E. Muchlinski 2 Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin Nr. 1999/1 VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE REIHE ISBN 3-933225-46-9 http://userpage.fu-berlin.de [email protected] PD Dr. E. Muchlinski 3 Table of Contents O. Introduction I. Lucas's view on Tinbergen 1. A note on Tinbergen's economic theory of policy 2. Tinbergen versus Lucas II. Lucasianism 3. The Three Pillars of Lucasianism 4. A brief history of the "Lucas Critique" III. Keynes's critique on Tinbergen 5. Divergences 6. Some generalizations IV. Concluding remarks V. Bibliography http://userpage.fu-berlin.de [email protected] PD Dr. E. Muchlinski 4 O. Introduction Reference to the Lucas critique is common knowledge within the macroeconomic li- terature and discussions nowadays. But the meaning of it is quite different from its original content. The exegetical story of the Lucas critique regularly outlines the failures of Keyne- sian macroeconometrics and macroeconomics, referring to Tinbergen. Considering the his- tory of macroeconomics it is surprising that Tinbergen's theory of policy is identified with so-called Keynesian economics which was the reason for a critique of Lucas and Lucasians. Exegesists of Tinbergen and Keynes tend to conclude that Keynes's critique on Tinbergen's method, published in 1938, was grounded on a technical misunderstanding of Tinbergen's work. Keynes was accused of being a dilettante. I believe that this misinterpretation can be avoided by investigating some of Keynes's writings.
    [Show full text]
  • Reacting to the Lucas Critique: the Keynesians' Replies
    Reacting to the Lucas Critique: The Keynesians’ Replies Aurélien GOUTSMEDT1 Université Paris 1 - Centre d’économie de la Sorbonne (CES) Erich PINZÓN-FUCHS Universidad Nacional de Colombia (FCE) Matthieu RENAULT Universidade de São Paulo (FEA-USP) Francesco SERGI University of the West of England (UWE) Bristol In 1976, Robert Lucas explicitly criticized Keynesian macroeconometric models for their inability to correctly predict the effects of alternative economic policies. Today, most contemporary macroeconomists and some historians of economics consider that the Lucas’s critique led forcefully to an immediate disqualification of the Keynesian macroeconometric approach. This narrative is based on the interpretation of the Lucas Critique as a fundamental principle for economic reasoning that was (and still is) logically unquestionable. We consider that this narrative is problematic both in terms of historiography and of the effects that it can have in the field as a way of assigning importance and credit to particular macroeconomists. Indeed, the point of view of the Keynesian economists is missing despite the fact that they were the target of Lucas’s paper and that throughout the 1970s and 1980s they produced a fierce reaction against it. In this paper we analyze the reactions by a broad set of authors (that we label as “Keynesians”) that disputed the relevance of the critique. In spite of their diversity in methodological, theoretical, and policy issues, these reactions were characterized by their common questioning of the empirical and practical relevance of the Lucas critique. Keywords: History of macroeconomics; Lucas Critique; Keynesian macroeconometrics; Stagflation JEL codes: B22; B41; E60; E12 1 Corresponding author: [email protected].
    [Show full text]