Consumer demand in two- sided markets

Gunnar Niels (with Adriaan ten Kate)

CRESSE Conference

5-7 July 2019

Two working papers

• ‘Consumer Demand in Two-Sided Markets and the Platform-Specific Nature of Externalities’ (with Adriaan ten Kate)

• substitution (complements) in use versus economic substitution (complements) • definition of critical mass • pricing strategies • supply-side complements versus two-sided markets

• ‘Transaction versus non-transaction platforms: A false dichotomy in two-sided market definition’

2 Demand system: monopoly platform (I)

• extraordinary demand functions

• (2a) DA = GA(PA,QB) • (2b) DB = GB(PB,QA)

• ordinary demand functions

• (3a) DA = FA(PA,PB) • (3b) DB = FB(PA,PB)

• externalities defined as elasticities

• (4a) γAB = (∂GA/∂QB)(QB/QA) • (4b) γBA = (∂GB/∂QA)(QB/QA)

Strictly confidential 3 Demand system: monopoly platform (II)

• ordinary and extraordinary elasticities

• (5aa) εAA = ε̃AA/(1 – γAB γBA) • (5ab) εAB = γAB ε̃BB/(1 – γAB γBA) = γAB εBB • (5ba) εBA = γBA ε̃AA/(1 – γAB γBA) = γBA εAA • (5bb) εBB = ε̃BB/(1 – γAB γBA)

• positive, moderate externalities (γAB γBA < 1) → demand more elastic

• well-known result in two-sided markets

• strong externalities (γAB γBA > 1) → own elasticity becomes positive

• linked to concept of critical mass (see below)

4 Definition of critical mass (I)

• for any pair of prices (PA,PB)

• if all customers on side A expect volume QB = FB(PA,PB) on side B

• and all customers on side B expect volume QA = FB(PA,PB) on side A

• fulfilled-expectations equilibrium demand (FEED): all customers’ decisions to join happen to bring about expected volumes

• Nash equilibria of one-shot non-cooperative game (‘join’ or ‘don’t join’) between all customers on both sides • externalities make payoffs inter-dependent

5 Definition of critical mass (II)

• equilibria unstable if F-demand upward-sloping in prices (γAB γBA > 1)

• small increase in QA or QB makes demand explode further

• critical mass: for any pair of prices (PA,PB) there is critical mass when there is a pair of volumes (QA,QB) solving equations (2) such that the resulting F-functions are positively sloped at those prices

• related to volumes on both sides (not critical mass on one side only) • dependent on prices • similar to one-sided network effects where critical mass is upward-sloping part of FEED curve (Ten Kate & Niels, 2006, ‘Fulfilled-Expectations Equilibria in Network Demand’, Review of Network Economics, Vol. 5(3), pp. 320-36)

Strictly confidential 6 Demand system: competing platforms

• platform-specific elasticities

• (9aa) εAiAi = ε̃AiAi/(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) (for i = 1, … , N) • (9ab) εAiBi = γAiBi ε̃BiBi/(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) = γAiBi εBiBi (for i = 1, … , N) • (9ba) εBiAi = γBiAi ε̃AiAi/(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) = γBiAi εAiAi (for i = 1, … , N) • (9bb) εBiBi = ε̃BiBi/(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) (for i = 1, … , N)

• cross-platform elasticities

• (10aa) εAiAj = ε̃AiAj /(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) (for i ≠ j = 1, … , N) (10ab) εAiBj = γAiBi ε̃BiBj /(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) (for i ≠ j = 1, … , N) (10ba) εBiAj = γBiAi ε̃AiAj /(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) (for i ≠ j = 1, … , N) (10bb) εBiBj = ε̃BiBj /(1 – γAiBi γBiAi) (for i ≠ j = 1, … , N)

7 Elasticity matrix for demand system with competing platforms

Side A Side B

Side-specific Cross- cross- platform elasticities cross-side elasticities Ai (i = 1,…, N) Platform- Own-price specific elasticities cross-side elasticities

Cross- Side-specific platform cross- cross-side elasticities Bi elasticities (i = 1,…, N) Platform- specific Own-price cross-side elasticities elasticities

8 Substitutes and complements on same side and other side

Side A Side B

Substitutes in Economic use substitutes

A

Substitutes in Economic use complements

Economic Substitutes in substitutes use

B Economic Substitutes in complements use

9 Platforms compete on both sides simultaneously

• platform-specific nature of externalities are key

• more women in 1 benefits men in nightclub 1, not men in nightclub 2 • main driver behind skewed pricing (not internalising externalities) • different sides are economic complements on same platform but economic substitutes on different platforms

• side B on platform 2 may be closest competitor to side A on platform 1

• women in nightclub 2 may be closest substitute (highest UPP after merging) to men in nightclub 1

10 Two-sided market definition (I)

• transaction versus non-transaction platforms → relevant distinction?

• Filistrucchi et al. (2014) • Just Eat/Hungryhouse (CMA, 2017), AmEx (Scotus, 2018)

• hypothetical platform monopolist sets profit-maximising prices simultaneously on both sides

• realistic starting assumption: ‘inside products’ include both sides • but even if you start with one side, the other side of other platforms can still be closest substitute, so you include both sides • same for transaction and non-transaction platforms

Filistrucchi, L., Geradin, D., Damme E. van, and Affeldt, P. (2014), ‘Market definition in two-sided markets: theory and practice’, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, Vol. 10 (2), pp. 293-339.

11 Two-sided market definition (II)

• other features of transaction and non-transaction platforms

• zero or negative externalities in one direction • zero price on one side • different competitors on either side → no reason for different approach transaction v non-transaction

• what is a transaction, anyway?

• transaction can be observed and charged for • spectrum from transactions to ‘mere’ interactions (e.g. click-throughs) • myriad of charging structures

• two-sided market definition is complex enough – focusing on whether a platform is transaction or non-transaction does not help

12 Contact: [email protected]

www.oxera.com Follow us on Twitter @OxeraConsulting Oxera Consulting LLP is a limited liability partnership registered in no. OC392464, registered office: Park Central, 40/41 , , OX1 1JD, UK; in Belgium, no. 0651 990 151, registered office: Avenue Louise 81, 1050 Brussels, Belgium; and in Italy, REA no. RM - 1530473, registered office: Via delle Quattro Fontane 15, 00184 Rome, Italy. Oxera Consulting GmbH is registered in Germany, no. HRB 148781 B (Local Court of Charlottenburg), registered office: Rahel-Hirsch-Straße 10, Berlin 10557, Germany. Oxera Consulting (Netherlands) LLP is registered in Amsterdam, no. KvK: 72446218, registered office: Strawinskylaan 3051, 1077 ZX Amsterdam, The Netherlands. Although every effort has been made to ensure the accuracy of the material and the integrity of the analysis presented herein, Oxera accepts no liability for any actions taken on the basis of its contents. No Oxera entity is either authorised or regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority or the Prudential Regulation Authority within the UK or any other financial authority applicable in other countries. Anyone considering a specific investment should consult their own broker or other investment adviser. Oxera accepts no liability for any specific investment decision, which must be at the investor’s own risk. © Oxera 2018. All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purposes of criticism or review, no part may be used or reproduced without permission.