UARXXX10.1177/1078087415617302Urban Affairs ReviewAnderson et al. 617302research-article2015

Article

Urban Affairs Review 31–­ 1 Economic Voting and © The Author(s) 2015 Reprints and permissions: Multilevel Governance: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1078087415617302 The Case of uar.sagepub.com

Cameron D. Anderson1, R. Michael McGregor2, Aaron A. Moore3, and Laura B. Stephenson1

Abstract Past work has shown that economic conditions influence electoral outcomes at multiple levels of government in Canada and in democratic states around the world. However, there is significant variation in the jurisdictional ability of different governments to influence economic conditions; in particular, municipal governments may be least able to influence the economy. As a result, voters may be less likely to hold municipal incumbents accountable for economic conditions than either provincial or federal politicians. Building on this discussion, this article explores several questions. First, do citizens differentiate between the impacts of different orders of government on economic conditions? Second, does the economy affect incumbent support in local elections? Finally, does knowledge of the jurisdictional responsibilities of the three levels of government condition economic effects at the municipal level in Canada? We consider these questions using individual-level data collected during the 2014 Toronto municipal election.

Keywords economic voting, municipal elections, Toronto

1University of Western Ontario, London, ON, Canada 2Bishop’s University, Lennoxville, QC, Canada 3University of Winnipeg, Winnipeg, MB, Canada Corresponding Author: Cameron D. Anderson, Department of Political Science, University of Western Ontario, Room 4154, Social Science Centre, London, ON, Canada N6A 5C2. Email: [email protected]

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 2 Urban Affairs Review

The economy is often considered to have a significant influence in election outcomes, and the literature on economic voting is both broad and deep (Kramer 1971; Lewis-Beck 1988). In many elections, economic conditions and citizens’ perceptions of them play a central role in the voters’ evaluation of incumbent performance. Unsurprisingly, politicians are well aware of the effect of the economy upon election outcomes. James Carville, in his role as strategist for Bill Clinton’s successful presidential campaign in 1992, famously emphasized the importance of the economy over all other matters. Seeking to bring American voters’ attention to a flagging national economy, a campaign mantra emerged: “It’s the economy, stupid.” This had the effect of focusing the U.S. electorate on the condition of the American economy rather than the incumbent George Bush’s foreign policy successes in the first Gulf War. According to many accounts, the economy was a central factor in President Bush’s defeat in 1992 (Fair 1996; Hetherington 1996). The example of the 1992 U.S. presidential election is far from unique. In advanced industrial democracies round the world, a clear relationship between economic conditions and incumbent electoral success can be found (Lewis-Beck and Stegmaier 2000, 2008). When the economy is strong (weak), incumbent vote share is higher (lower). We know this to be true at the national level of government and at the provincial or state level within federal states such as Canada, Spain, or the United States (for Canada, see C. D. Anderson 2008; Gélineau and Bélanger 2005; for Spain, see León 2011; for United States, see Atkeson and Partin 1995; Ebeid and Rodden 2006; Stein 1990). Indeed, the state of the economy is consistently either the best, or one of the best, predictors of vote choice at both the national and provincial/state levels (Lewis-Beck and Stegmaier 2000, 2008). Receiving significantly less scholarly attention is the relationship between economic conditions, perceptions of those conditions, and electoral choice in local, or municipal, contexts (but see Cutler and Matthews 2005; Martins and Veiga 2013). Prior work shows some effect of perceptions of local economic conditions on local incumbent vote choice (Cutler and Matthews 2005) and effects of national economic perceptions when the local incumbent is of the same party as the central government (Martins and Veiga 2013). At the same time, we know little about how much responsibility for economic conditions voters assign to local levels of government—do citizens believe that munici- pal governments influence the economy, or are only federal and provincial governments perceived as influential for the condition of the economy? If municipal governments are considered influential, do economic conditions factor into vote choices in mayoral or council/ward elections? Scholars have yet to fully consider several important questions pertaining to economic voting at the local level. For example, do citizens form impressions

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 3 of local economic conditions that are distinct from those at the provincial/state or national levels? Do they blame or credit municipal governments for the state of the economy? And, importantly, do attitudes about the municipal economy influence vote choice? This article considers three central questions regarding the relationship of economic conditions and municipal election results. First, do citizens dif- ferentiate between the impact of different levels of governments on eco- nomic conditions? Different levels of government within a multilevel system have different scopes of authority to influence economic conditions—do voters pick up on these differences? Second, did economic considerations affect vote choices in the 2014 Toronto municipal election? Finally, did knowledge of jurisdictional responsibilities condition economic effects on voting? Canadian municipal governments are far less influential than their provincial and federal counterparts, and those individuals who are more knowledgeable about the role municipal governments play in the local econ- omy should presumably be influenced differently by economic conditions than those who know less about the jurisdictional capabilities of the various orders of government. We consider these questions in the case of Toronto, Ontario, Canada, for two reasons. First, the institutional features of the City of Toronto make it a particularly stiff test for the presence of economic impact and ultimately, economic voting. Canada is a well-developed federal country with constitu- tionally entrenched federal and provincial levels of government who hold the major levers of economic influence. In contrast, municipal governments in Canada have no constitutional standing, and relatively little policy-mak- ing power rendering the role of municipal governments to influence the local economy unclear. In addition, Toronto has a “weak mayor” system (in which the mayor has one vote among 45 on City Council) and, roughly a year before this specific election, the mayor had the powers of his office significantly curtailed by Council. Given the lack of clarity of municipal responsibility, there is likely to be a wide range of opinions about the eco- nomic influence of municipal governments, making this an excellent case study. Second, appropriate measures and data have recently become available which make considering our research questions possible. The Toronto Election Study (TES) was conducted during the 2014 Toronto Municipal Election and includes a number of measures that bear upon the central ques- tions of the article, allowing us to properly consider the relationship between economic conditions and mayoral and ward vote choice.1 Our analysis allows us to determine whether, for municipal politicians, it really is “the economy, stupid,” or whether it is stupid to focus upon the economy.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 4 Urban Affairs Review

Economic Voting and Government Capacity A voluminous literature has emerged over the past 40 years that explores the empirical relationship between economic conditions and electoral outcomes (see Lewis-Beck and Stegmaier 2000, 2008, for reviews of the literally hun- dreds of studies on the topic). This literature shows that economic conditions regularly have significant effects on national-level elections across a wide range of countries (e.g., Canada: Happy 1992; Nadeau and Blais 1993, United Kingdom: Sanders 2005, Spain: Riba and Bosch 2005, United States: Fiorina 1981), levels of economic development (e.g., Gélineau 2007; Singer 2013), and institutional types (C. D. Anderson 2006; Powell and Whitten 1993; Whitten and Palmer 1999) . There is also consistent evidence that economic conditions at the subnational level influence provincial- or state-level elec- tion results. These studies are often in federal states such as Canada (e.g., C. D. Anderson 2008; Gélineau and Bélanger 2005; Tellier 2006), Spain (León 2011; Riba and Diaz 2002), and the United States (Atkeson and Partin 1995; Ebeid and Rodden 2006; Niemi, Stanley, and Vogel 1995).2 At the national and provincial/state levels of government, the consistency of economic effects (or economic voting) makes sense. Although there can be great variance in the jurisdictional strength of national and subnational gov- ernments in federal countries, these levels of government have constitution- ally entrenched and clearly specified scopes of authority over certain economic policies. Watts (2008) outlined a range of financial levers available to both national and subnational governments that provide the potential to influence economic conditions and investment decisions. Such levers avail- able to both levels of government in many federations include the ability to set tax rates (corporate, personal, and sales taxes) and the ability to borrow money from both domestic and international sources (Watts 2008). At both levels, then, governments typically have significant and tangible authority to impact the economic conditions of their geographic area. Do local governments, and specifically the City of Toronto, have an inde- pendent ability to influence economic conditions? Municipal governments in Canada have far less independent authority than the federal and provincial governments. Comparatively speaking, the financial tools available to munic- ipalities in Canada are severely limited, and their power is highly constrained by the provincial governments that create and ultimately control them (Slack 2011). For most municipalities, the property tax is the only major economic lever they have the authority to set. Kitchen and Slack (2003) found that in 2001 property tax accounted for 52.2% of municipal own-source revenue (up from 48.6% in 1988). Although some municipalities have access to specialty taxes, such tools provide little revenue and have minimal economic impact.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 5

The only other tax Toronto currently levies is a land transfer tax, which accounts for only 4% of the city’s operating revenue (Toronto 2015). Although the property tax is a substantial revenue source for municipalities, it does not grow with the economy like income or sales taxes. As such, although prop- erty taxes and other minor sole source municipal revenues, such as user fees, are useful for funding basic municipal services (e.g., snow removal, garbage collection, water), they do little to allow municipalities to implement, on their own, policies that could directly influence their local economy (Slack 2009). The limitations of and reliance on property taxes and user fees are further exasperated by provincial laws that limit municipal capital debt and prevent municipalities from running an operating deficit. Provincial and federal gov- ernments are able to spend and run deficits to help boost the economy during recessions and later pay off the accumulated debt with budget surpluses in better economic times. Although Canadian municipal governments can and do offer tax abatements as a lure to business, much of the research on such practices suggests that property tax rates play a marginal role in businesses’ decision making, aside from intraurban locational decisions (Bartik 1985; Blair and Premus 1987; Charney 1983). Canadian municipalities, like their American counterparts, do implement economic development policies. For instance, many large cities have development corporations responsible for the development of city-owned land. Although some of these corporations focus solely on the development of said land (e.g., Build Toronto), others are also tasked with stimulating development in declining areas of the city (e.g., CentreVenture in Winnipeg). However, there is little evidence, even in the United States where municipalities have a greater variety of tools at their disposal, that local economic development policies work (Green, Fleischmann, and Kwong 1996; Peters and Fisher 2004; Schneider 1992). Municipalities in Canada, therefore, have little, if any, ability to stimulate their own economy, and most certainly their influence is dwarfed by both the federal and provin- cial orders of government.3 In the context of the evidently limited scope for economic influence of local governments, therefore, this article considers whether and how this limited capacity impacts the presence and strength of local economic voting.

Clarity of Responsibility and Municipal Economic Voting According to the theory of economic voting, voters use economic conditions to evaluate the performance of an incumbent government. If the economy is in good shape (by some measure), then the incumbent has governed reason- ably successfully and should be rewarded with reelection. In the case of a

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 6 Urban Affairs Review poor economy, voters infer some level of incompetence on behalf of the incumbent and vote against sitting officeholders. The main objective of this article is to assess whether such voting occurs in Toronto. In addition to the jurisdictional argument made above, there are many reasons to expect that economic voting should be absent in the 2014 Toronto mayoral and ward elections. Not only does the , like all municipal governments in Canada, have very little economic capacity, but it also operates in a federal environment and has a “weak mayor” system (which we describe below), where the “clarity of responsibility” is low. A key finding of the literature on economic voting is that the strength of economic effects on incumbent support is conditioned by clarity of responsi- bility. When decision-making responsibility can be more clearly attributed to a party or leader, economic effects on vote choice are typically greater. Powell and Whitten (1993) demonstrated this by showing that when policy-making responsibility is clearer within a level of government, economic effects on incumbent support are stronger (see also C. J. Anderson 2000; Whitten and Palmer 1999). In Toronto’s nonpartisan setting (meaning that party labels are not present and party discipline does not structure council votes and govern- ment policy), however, it is difficult to draw links between individual politi- cians and policy; it can be difficult for voters to determine which politicians supported or opposed particular policies. These effects have also been found on a vertical dimension, as decentralized federalism or multilevel governance can undermine the clarity of policy-making responsibility for the national government and thereby reduce economic effects on incumbent support in national elections (C. D. Anderson 2006). Relatedly, Toronto’s mayor is institutionally weak when compared with most American cities and some Canadian ones (e.g., , , and Winnipeg), and certainly compared with provincial premiers or the prime minister. Although he or she is elected at large, the mayor has only one vote of the 45 on Council and, because there are no political parties, is constantly at the mercy of ever-fluid coalitions of ward councillors.4 Thus, although the mayor is the only elected official in the city who can claim to represent the city as a whole, in practice City Council holds most of the authority in Toronto. The weakness of Toronto’s mayor was never more in evidence than when, due to the mayor’s admitted use of drugs and alcohol, City Council stripped Rob Ford of most of his mayoral authority, placing it instead in the hands of the deputy mayor (Church and Hui 2013).5 For almost a year before the October 2014 election—he was stripped of his authority in November 2013—Rob Ford was mayor in name alone. As a result of the “weak mayor” system, and the fact that the Rob Ford was stripped of most his authorities nearly a year before the 2014 election,

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 7 voters should presumably assign little or no responsibility for economic con- ditions directly to the mayor in the 2014 Toronto Election. As a result, weak or nonexistent economic effects on mayoral incumbent support might be expected. The situation is similar for individual councillors as well. Each councillor has but one vote on a 45-member council, and without political parties that might structure voting blocs, it is difficult to attribute responsibil- ity for decisions without undertaking a full review of each vote cast. Thus, the impact of economic conditions on voting for incumbents (mayoral or coun- cil) may be undermined by the institutional structure in Toronto. An additional reason to expect economic voting to be unimportant in this election is the lack of emphasis voters reportedly placed upon the economy. According to polls conducted throughout the campaign, issues related to the economy were all but absent from voters’ consciousness. According to a poll conducted by Nanos Research the month before the election, 49% of respon- dents identified transit and gridlock as the number one issue, followed dis- tantly by the need for a new mayor with 11% (Suen 2014). In another poll just prior to election day, 31% of respondents identified transit as the main issue facing the city, followed by infrastructure like roads and bridges at 15%, property taxes at 14%, and the economy at 9% (Armstrong 2014). The issue of transit and transportation spending clearly dominated as the most impor- tant issue for voters throughout the election whereas issues relating to the economy and city finances were of marginal importance.6 This is yet another reason to expect economic considerations to be of minimal importance in this contest. Regardless of whether one expects economic effects within the 2014 Toronto election, there are remarkably few studies that consider economic voting in local elections. There are other studies assessing electoral dynamics at the local level in Canada (notably Kushner, Siegel, and Stanwick 1997; Stanwick 2000; Walks 2013, 2015). While these studies make valuable con- tributions to understanding electoral dynamics at the local level in the prov- ince of Ontario (Kushner, Siegel, and Stanwick 1997) and the city of Toronto (Stanwick 2000), neither explicitly consider the effect of economic condi- tions on electoral outcomes. Outside of Canada, participation and voting in local elections has been studied by Kaufman (2004), Oliver and Ha (2007), Sellers et al. (2013), and Wood (2002). Cutler and Matthews (2005) considered voting behavior and the role of economic perceptions in the 2002 Vancouver mayoral election, which was fought by parties, rather than independent candidates. Among their findings, Cutler and Matthews observed that voters who held a positive view of Vancouver’s economy were 17 points more likely to support the incumbent party’s mayoral candidate.7 As these authors note, regardless of whether the

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 8 Urban Affairs Review local government has any control over local economic conditions, “voters appear to hold municipal governments accountable in a crude way for the nature of the times in the locale” (p 374, Cutler and Matthews 2005). Although only about 5% of respondents indicated that they thought that the municipal government was most responsible for the local economy, Cutler and Matthews observed that economic perceptions still had a “powerful influence on the vote.”8 In their study of municipal economic voting in Portugal, Martins and Veiga (2013) found that national economic conditions influence incumbent support in local elections when the incumbent is of the same party as the national government. They also find that local unemployment rates have a negative effect on incumbent support in local election when the incumbent is of the same party as the national government (Martins and Veiga 2013). However, this study was conducted in a case in which political parties assist in organizing the local electoral milieu and where these parties are integrated with regional and national party organizations. Our study differs from these in that Toronto’s election was nonpartisan, and our focus is upon local eco- nomic conditions only.

Economic Voting and Information We are also interested in the conditional effects of respondent information on economic voting. Does individual-level variation in knowledge of jurisdic- tional responsibilities condition economic effects? We have two reasons to expect that knowledgeable voters will be less likely than their low-knowledge counterparts to factor economic considerations into their vote choice. First, we suggest that low-knowledge voters are more likely to employ economic evaluations as a low-information cue when making their decisions. It is a well-known observation that levels of citizen information or knowl- edge about politics are not high (e.g., Delli Carpini and Keeter 1996; Fournier 2002). As a result, Lupia and McCubbins (1998) suggested the possibility of a “democratic dilemma” in which voters, called upon to make reasoned elec- toral choices, may not actually be capable of doing so due to low levels of information. One means of overcoming the “democratic dilemma” is for vot- ers to use heuristics or cognitive shortcuts, such as party identification (e.g., Lodge and Hamill 1986) or public endorsements by trusted public figures (e.g., Johnston et al. 1996), to reach a reasoned decision in the face of low information (often called “low information rationality”) (Lupia and McCubbins 1998; Popkin 1991; Sniderman, Brody, and Tetlock 1991). Evaluations of economic conditions can provide a simple means for low- information voters to arrive at a reasoned electoral choice in the absence of

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 9

information or knowledge. As previously stated, there were no political par- ties to help structure the ideological or issue environment, so the partisanship cue was unavailable to voters. One way for unsophisticated voters to navigate through the complex institutional landscape, which includes multiple levels of government (federal, provincial, and municipal) with varying responsibili- ties and powers, may be to evaluate incumbents on the basis of economic conditions. Accordingly, we expect that low-information voters are more likely to draw on simple cues, such as the economy, when forming their vote preferences. The second reason we expect economic voting to be more prevalent among low-knowledge voters is that such individuals are less likely to be aware of the economic impotence of municipal governments in Canada, and of Mayor Rob Ford (who had been stripped of most of his powers almost a year before the election) in particular. Less informed voters likely hold a worse understanding of the actual powers of the local government and the mayoral office and as a result fail to recognize its weak authority over the local economy. Thus, we suggest that economic effects on incumbent support should be stronger among these voters because they fail to realize that munic- ipal politicians cannot and should not be held accountable for these condi- tions. We, therefore, expect that economic voting will be greater among low-knowledge voters than among their higher knowledge counterparts.

Data and Method We answer our research questions in two phases. First, we consider how Torontonians perceive the impact of the three orders of government upon their city’s economy. Given the constitutional responsibilities (or lack thereof) of municipal governments, there is good reason to expect that voters will be less likely to believe that the municipal government has influenced the econ- omy than has either the provincial or federal orders of government. The TES includes questions that ask respondents whether they believe each govern- ment has had a positive or negative effect upon the economy, or no effect at all, allowing us to evaluate this proposition. Second, we consider the importance of economic evaluations to incumbent vote choice in the mayoral and ward councillor races in Toronto.9 The key independent variable is a sociotropic retrospective economic evaluation of the condition of Toronto’s economy.10 If this variable is related to vote choice, after controlling for a series of other factors known to influence vote choice, then we can conclude that economic considerations were a significant influence upon the decisions of voters. For the many reasons outlined above, we expect that economic voting will not be a factor in Toronto’s mayoral and ward elections.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 10 Urban Affairs Review

Finally, we consider the effect of knowledge of the jurisdictional respon- sibilities of governments upon the importance of economic considerations in the Toronto election (at both the mayoral and ward levels). We do so by creat- ing a low-knowledge dummy variable, based upon a battery of questions from the TES, and interacting this variable with the retrospective economic variable. Recall that our expectation is that low-knowledge voters will be unable to recognize the weak influence of municipal government over the economy. As such, the dummy variable identifies the roughly 25% of the population with the lowest knowledge, comparing them with the remainder of the population. The individuals in the low-knowledge category answered 50% or fewer of the jurisdictional knowledge questions correctly.11 If the interaction of this low-knowledge dummy and economic considerations is significant, it would suggest that knowledge has a differential effect upon the impact of economic considerations on municipal vote decisions. Note that retrospective economic evaluations are theoretically only rele- vant if an incumbent candidate or party is present. Elections in Toronto are nonpartisan, and the outgoing mayor, Rob Ford, was forced to withdraw from the race due to illness on the date of the nomination deadline. His brother Doug, a sitting councillor, replaced him on the ballot that same day. It is our position that Doug Ford can be viewed as an acceptable incumbent in our model. The brothers have a strong, highly publicized association with one another (their voting histories on council are nearly identical, and Doug was a longtime advisor to Rob). Furthermore, TES data confirm that Torontonians viewed the policy platforms of the two brothers as very similar. Respondents were asked how similar they believed Doug’s policies were to those of Rob, and we omit from our mayoral vote choice models those individuals who believed that the policies of the brothers were either all or mostly different (this represents only 3.8% of our sample).12 We assume that, for all remaining respondents, Doug can be considered the de facto incumbent.13 At the ward level, we have no such issue, as incumbents were present in 37 of 44 wards; we limit this part of our analysis to these wards only.14 In addition, the impact of Rob Ford’s late withdrawal from the mayoral race had no impact on the number or quality of the main challengers for the mayoral office. As mentioned, Rob pulled out on the nomination deadline day—literally leaving no time for other candidates to declare. In addition, the two main challengers, and Olivia Chow, were well known in Toronto and of high quality. John Tory was a former candidate for mayor and had earlier been the leader of a major political party in the province (Progressive Conservative Party of Ontario). Olivia Chow was a former city councillor in Toronto, a former Member of Parliament of Canada for a Toronto-area riding, and widow of Jack Layton—a very popular former federal politician.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 11

Results Attribution of Credit/Blame for the Economy As noted above, Canada’s federal structure and the fact that municipalities have no constitutional standing and relatively little policy setting power sug- gest that the decisions of municipal governments should have little effect upon the economy and certainly less of an impact than either the federal or provincial governments. It is unknown, however, whether citizens perceive the municipal government’s power in such a manner. TES data reveal that, in fact, many Torontonians do not see the municipal government as less influential than the other orders of government. Respondents were asked to rank the three levels of government with respect to how much of an impact each has upon one’s quality of life. In total, 30.1% ranked the municipal government as having the most impact, and a further 20.8% rank it second. Contrary to what constitutional scholars might expect, only 43.6% of TES participants ranked the municipal government as having the least impact (5.6% of respondents did not know how to answer this ques- tion). Although this figure represents a plurality of responses, a majority of respondents believe the municipal government to be more influential than at least one of the other levels of government. Of course, influence over one’s quality of life is not the same as influence over the city’s economy. Despite believing the municipal government has a general impact, it is conceivable that Torontonians assign relatively little credit or blame to the municipal government for the direction of the economy. Table 1 shows the perceived impact of each level of government upon the economy, based upon the following question: “Have the policies of the [municipal/provincial/federal] government made Toronto’s economy better, worse, or not made much of a difference?” The most immediately striking feature of Table 1 is how little variation there is between the perceived impact of each level of government. Values in the “neutral” and “don’t know” rows are remarkably consistent for each level of government. The share of respondents who believe each government has had an impact, either positive or negative, is also very similar. In total, 43.7% of respondents thought the municipal government had influenced Toronto’s economy, compared with 44.9% and 41.9% for the provincial and federal governments, respectively. Perhaps surprisingly, fewer respondents believe that the federal government had an impact upon the city’s economy (either negative or positive) compared with the municipal or provincial govern- ments. Given the vastly different fiscal and policy setting power of the vari- ous levels of government, such a pattern is quite unexpected.15

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 12 Urban Affairs Review

Table 1. Perceived Impact of Three Levels of Government on the Economy of Toronto.

Level of Government

Municipal Provincial Federal (n = 2,890) (n = 2,890) (n = 2,890) Governmental impact Negative 25.7% 31.7% 28.3% Neutral 43.0% 40.9% 43.0% Positive 18.0% 13.2% 13.6% Don’t know 13.3% 14.3% 15.2%

Note. Entries report column percentages. Due to rounding, columns do not all sum to 100.

Although the frequencies of the perceived effects of government influ- ence are fairly consistent across the orders of government, Table 1 does not consider individual-level variation. Such information is important because attitudes toward the appropriate role of government in the economy may have a similar influence upon responses to questions about all types of government impact. For instance, libertarians might be opposed to govern- ment intervention in the economy on ideological grounds, whereas propo- nents of government involvement may be of the opinion that state action is, almost by definition, beneficial to the economy. If such an effect is widespread, this could account for the finding in Table 1 that similar num- bers of Torontonians believe the municipal, federal, and provincial gov- ernments have influenced the economy. This possibility is examined in Table 2, which shows the cross-tabulation of the municipal government impact variable with the provincial and federal impact variables, respectively. Although the majority of respondents lie on the diagonals for both the municipal–provincial and municipal–federal comparisons, there is signifi- cant variation in the perceived impact of the three orders of government upon Toronto’s economy. In the municipal–provincial comparison, 55.5% of respondents lie on the diagonal, whereas this value for the municipal–federal cross-tabulation is 57.8%. Accordingly, more than 4 in 10 voters perceive the impact of the federal and provincial governments to be different than that of the municipal government. There are still more reasons to conclude that voters are making indepen- dent assessments of the economic impacts of the three levels of government. First, many respondents who believe the municipal government influenced the economy were of the opinion that the other levels of government had the

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 13

Table 2. Municipal Versus Provincial and Federal Government Impact.

Impact of Municipal Government

Negative Neutral Positive Don’t Know (n = 521) (n = 743) (n = 1,242) (n = 384) Impact of provincial government Negative 47.6% 24.4% 46.1% 4.6% Neutral 36.2% 62.0% 25.4% 2.6% Positive 13.7% 11.5% 24.9% 1.8% Don’t know 2.6% 2.1% 3.6% 91.1% Impact of federal government Negative 53.0% 22.9% 23.1% 4.8% Neutral 33.3% 61.8% 40.4% 4.2% Positive 9.6% 11.8% 32.1% 2.1% Don’t know 4.1% 3.5% 4.5% 89.0%

Note. Values in the table represent column percentages. Entries on the diagonal are bolded to highlight those individuals who give the same response for multiple levels of government.

opposite effect. Of the respondents who thought the municipal government had an impact on the economy (either positive or negative), 27.1% and 15.1% thought the provincial and federal governments, respectively, had an effect in the opposite direction. Moreover, respondents seem more likely to assign blame to multiple levels of government than they are to assign credit to more than one level of government. Our data reveal that respondents who perceived the municipal government’s impact as negative were more likely to believe the impact of both the federal or provincial governments was also negative than individuals who saw the municipal government’s impact as positive. Such asymmetry, coupled with the fact that a significant share of respondents lie off the diagonals of the table, suggests that, at least for a large segment of the population, voters are making independent assessments of the economic impact of the various levels of government (indeed, this is likely also the case for many of the voters who also fall on the diagonals in Table 2). Overall, two important findings are made clear by Tables 1 and 2. First, voters assess the economic impact of the three levels of government sepa- rately, and second, Torontonians tend to believe that the municipal govern- ment is as likely to influence the city’s economy as the federal and provincial governments. This suggests that economic voting may be as prominent in municipal elections as it is federally and provincially. We turn now to evalu- ate this possibility.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 14 Urban Affairs Review

The Effect of Economic Conditions on Vote Choice Given the (lack of) constitutional standing of Canadian municipalities, and Toronto’s weak mayor system, one might reason that economic voting will be nonexistent in municipal elections, at either the mayoral or ward level. However, the finding above, that Torontonians are just as likely to believe that the economy has been influenced by the municipal government as they are either the federal or provincial governments, provides at least modest cause to expect that economic voting may indeed be present at the municipal level. If economic perceptions do, in fact, influence vote choice at this level, we suspect that the effect may be moderated by knowledge of the jurisdic- tional responsibilities of Canadian governments. As the municipal govern- ment has much less capacity to influence the economy than do either of the other orders of government, those individuals who have a high degree of knowledge of the responsibilities of each level of government should be less likely to factor the city’s economy into their municipal vote decisions. Conversely, it may be the case that high-knowledge voters are more likely than their low-knowledge counterparts to draw a link between economic con- ditions and vote choice. These possibilities are evaluated in Table 3 through a series of four logistic regression models: two for the 2014 Toronto mayoral election and two for the ward councillor elections. Both models include controls for factors that may conceivably influence incumbent support but which can also be associated with economic evaluations, including sociodemographic characteristics, an economic conservatism index, and candidate evaluations (in the mayoral model only, as this information is not available for the ward elections). We also control for satisfaction with the performance of the incumbent candidate to isolate the effect of economic considerations from general retrospective evaluations.16 Our key independent variable (the direction of the economy) is based upon the following question: “In the past year, has Toronto’s economy gotten better, gotten worse, or stayed the same?” The dependent variable in all models is a vote for the incumbent, and a positive and significant finding for the “direction” variable would suggest that retrospective economic evalu- ations were a factor in the decisions of voters (evidence of economic voting). Finally, the jurisdictional knowledge variable is based upon a series of eight TES questions (note that the wording of the TES questions used in the con- struction of all variables can be found in the appendix). The second model for each level is used to consider whether the relation- ship between economic perceptions and vote choice is moderated by knowl- edge of the jurisdictional responsibilities of government. Recall that we expect those who have little understanding of the responsibilities of the

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 15

Table 3. The Economy and Incumbent Support.

Mayoral Ward Female −0.20 (0.26) −0.14 (0.27) −0.26 (0.18) −0.21 (0.18) Immigrant −0.01 (0.30) −0.01 (0.31) 0.36 (0.19)* 0.38 (0.20) Ethnic minority 0.07 (0.39) 0.01 (0.39) 0.18 (0.22) 0.22 (0.23) High age 0.50 (0.32) 0.41 (0.34) 0.17 (0.19) 0.24 (0.21) University educated −0.14 (0.29) −0.11 (0.29) 0.00 (0.17) −0.02 (0.18) High income −0.50 (0.28)* −0.56 (0.29)* −0.02 (0.18) −0.02 (0.19) Home owner −0.55 (0.34) −0.53 (0.36) 0.26 (0.21) 0.25 (0.22) North York Base = Toronto −0.11 (0.41) −0.25 (0.43) −0.72(0.22)*** −0.75(0.22)*** Scarborough −0.06 (0.41) −0.20 (0.43) 0.27 (0.23) 0.28 (0.24) Etobicoke −0.09 (0.39) −0.15 (0.39) −0.88(0.29)*** −0.84(0.30)*** Economic conservatism −0.89 (0.62) −1.03 (0.65) −0.29 (0.41) −0.28 (0.42) Ford 4.37 (0.69)*** 4.48 (0.69)*** Tory −4.06 (0.69)*** −4.17 (0.71)*** Chow −1.68 (0.55)*** −1.63 (0.56)** Satisfaction with incumbent 3.91 (0.71)*** 4.22 (0.78)*** 3.65 (0.33)*** 3.66 (0.34)*** Direction of the economy 0.89 (0.44)** 1.59 (0.52)*** −0.39 (0.25) −0.16 (0.30) Low knowledge 0.45 (0.46) 0.21 (0.33) Direction × Low Knowledge −1.95 (0.87)** −0.87 (0.56) Constant −2.15 (0.82)*** −2.37 (0.88)*** −1.75 (0.41)*** −1.48 (0.53)*** n 1,298 1,298 1,023 1,023 Pseudo-R2 .6535 .6598 .1825 .1827

Note. Entries report coefficients and standard errors (in parentheses). *p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01.

municipal government to be more likely to consider economic conditions in their vote choice. To fully investigate this expectation, we first consider whether knowledgeable voters are more likely to recognize that municipal politicians have very little power over the economy. The jurisdictional knowl- edge dummy variable suggests that knowledge is indeed related to the per- ceived economic impact of the municipal government. In total, 45.3% of knowledgeable voters thought the municipal government did not make much of a difference to the economy whereas only 41.4% of low-knowledge voters had the same opinion (this difference is significant at p < .05). The question we consider, however, is whether this knowledge affects the relationship between economic evaluations and vote choice. If jurisdictional knowledge makes voters less likely to base their municipal vote decisions on economic considerations, the interaction of the low-knowledge and the economy vari- ables should be positive and significant. Table 3 reveals several findings of note. First, the data suggest that the economy did indeed factor into the decisions of voters in the 2014 Toronto Mayoral Election. Despite the extremely limited capacity for Canadian municipalities to influence the economy, the city’s weak mayor system, and

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 16 Urban Affairs Review the fact that Rob Ford had most of his powers stripped of him nearly a year before the election, voters attributed responsibility for the economy to the outgoing mayor. The inclusion of the general satisfaction variable assures us that this effect is driven by economic considerations in particular, as opposed to evaluations of Rob Ford’s performance more generally. The marginal effect of the economic voting variable is equal to 5 points.17 In other words, if all other factors are held constant, voters who believed the economy had improved were 5 percentage points more likely to support Doug Ford than were voters who believed the economy had worsened. This result provides compelling evidence that economic voting was indeed a factor in the 2014 Toronto mayoral election. Even though the mayor has little power to affect the economy or even drive policy in Toronto, it appears that voters held the (pseudo-)incumbent candidate responsible for the direction of the city’s economy. The second notable finding in Table 3 is that ward-level vote decisions are not driven by economic evaluations. As with the mayoral election, general satisfaction with the performance of the incumbent councillor is the most significant predictor of vote choice. These two types of elections differ, how- ever, in that incumbent councillors were given no credit or blame for the economy.18 This null result conforms to our expectations, and suggests that voters focus upon different types of considerations for these two types of municipal elections.19 Voters may be more hesitant to attribute responsibility for the state of the city’s economy to a councillor who represents only a small portion of the city, than they are to the mayor, who represents the city as a whole. The third and final finding of note from Table 3 stems from the interaction terms, which test whether knowledge of the jurisdictional responsibility of local governments moderates the relationship between economic evaluations and vote choice. Contrary to expectations, the interaction term in the mayoral model is negative and significant, which suggests that economic consider- ations are actually less of a factor for individuals with low knowledge of the jurisdictional responsibilities of governments than for high-knowledge vot- ers.20 The constituent economic variable is significant which, given the fact that the knowledge variable is a dummy, suggests that economic consider- ations are important for high-knowledge voters. However, the negative (and significant) result for the interaction term is indeed the opposite of what we anticipated. Importantly, knowledge itself is not associated with support for Ford.21 It is the combination of knowledge and the opinion of the economy that appears to be affecting support for Doug Ford.22 Those individuals who are highly knowledgeable, and who should presumably be aware of the fact that the municipal government has relatively little power to influence the

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 17 economy are, in fact, the ones who are most likely to factor the economy into their mayoral vote decisions. Although the results in Table 3 indicate an interactive relationship between knowledge, evaluations of the economy, and support for Doug Ford, the raw regression coefficients presented in the table provide no information on the magnitude of effects. To that end, we present Figure 1, which shows the pre- dicted rate of support for Ford among low- and high-knowledge voters, for each value of the economic evaluation variable.23 To compare high- and low- knowledge voters, the values in the figure are based upon the mayoral model with the interaction term in Table 3. The figure illustrates graphically the nature of the interactive relationship between economic evaluations, knowl- edge, and vote choice. Figure 1 suggests multiple findings of interest. First, as suggested by the result of the interaction term in Table 3, the slopes of the lines for high- and low-knowledge voters are quite different. Evaluations of the economy are positively related to support for Ford among high-knowledge voters; the pre- dicted probability of voting for Ford is 8.7 percentage points higher if voters believed the economy to have improved (29.1%) than if they thought the city’s economy had worsened within the last year (20.4%).24 In contrast, the slope of the line for the low-knowledge group is not significantly different from zero, indicating that, for this group, the state of the economy was not a factor in vote choice. The figure also reveals an important pattern which Table 1 does not: the difference between high- and low-knowledge voters exists only if voters were of the opinion that the economy had improved. The vote choices of the two knowledge groups are not significantly different from one another in the “economy worsened” and “economy unchanged” categories. However, the predicted probability of voting for Ford jumps from 20.8% to 29.1%, moving from the low- to high-knowledge category, and this difference is statistically significant at p < .01. Put plainly, for those individuals who were of the opin- ion that the economy had improved, knowledge significantly moderated the impact of economic opinions on vote choice in the 2014 Toronto municipal election.

Discussion and Conclusion Despite the reasons one might expect economic voting not to factor into municipal elections, TES data reveal that the economy was indeed a signifi- cant consideration in the decision-making calculus of voters in the 2014 Toronto mayoral election. Despite the myriad reasons why we might expect voters to believe the municipal government has no effect upon the economy,

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 18 Urban Affairs Review

Figure 1. Predicted support for Doug Ford by economic evaluation and knowledge.

Tables 1 and 2 reveal TES respondents were just as likely to believe the municipal government influenced the economy as they were the provincial or federal governments. Given this, perhaps it is not surprising that Table 3 shows that positive evaluations of the direction of the city’s economy led to increased support for (pseudo-)incumbent Doug Ford. Although the esti- mated effect (5 points) is much less than that observed by Cutler and Matthews (2005) in Vancouver’s 2002 partisan election (17 points), the effect may have been decisive if the 2014 Toronto mayoral election had been a closer race.25 Furthermore, we find that those most knowledgeable about the limitations of municipal government jurisdiction are the most likely to hold the incumbent mayoral candidate responsible. This is opposite to our expectations. So what might account for our potentially surprising findings? In terms of municipal economic voting, we can see two potential explanations. First, as suggested above, it may be that the absence of parties leads voters to search for alternative cues. They may turn to the economy as a shortcut, despite the many reasons why economic considerations should not factor into municipal vote decisions. Alternatively, it may be that political rhetoric is such that vot- ers are led to make incorrect links between the economy and the government/ mayor’s effect. In other words, it may be the perception of a politician’s eco- nomic impact, rather than the objective truth, that matters for vote choice. The side that does the best job of arguing its economic impact stands to ben- efit from an issue that should likely not factor into mayoral election

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 19

outcomes. Indeed, Rob Ford made several claims during his tenure, including in the months leading up to the election, that he had a significant, positive impact upon the city’s economy and the municipal government’s finances.26 He personally took credit for a drop in Toronto’s unemployment rate (Gee 2013; Shah 2013), describing the city’s economy as booming (Dale 2014). Despite being disproven by the media, he claimed to have saved the city CDN $1 billion (Moloney and Pagliaro 2014), and claimed rather infamously that “I have transformed Toronto into an economic powerhouse” (Gee 2013).27 Such specious claims are hardly beneficial for political accountabil- ity through realistic economic voting. As for the curious findings that knowledge of the jurisdictional responsi- bilities of governments increases the likelihood that electors will factor eco- nomic evaluations into their vote choices, and that a difference between high- and low-knowledge voters exists only among those who have positive evaluations of the economy, we can think of no obvious explanations or rea- sons for these effects. One potential explanation, which must be examined in future research, might be that knowledgeable voters may be more aware of political events and are thus more likely than low-knowledge voters to be exposed to claims made by politicians such as Rob Ford’s statement that he had a positive impact upon the city’s economy. If even some high-knowledge voters are willing to accept such claims, it could help to account for the inter- active relationship observed above. Note that, for their parts, the challengers in the election (Tory and Chow) made little mention of either the city’s econ- omy or Ford’s impact upon the economy. This could explain why the vote choices of those individuals with negative economic evaluations are not influenced by knowledge. Accordingly, voters were willing to reward the Ford brothers for positive economic performance, but not to punish them for poor performance. Another possible explanation for this finding may be that the Rob Ford scandal factored more heavily into the decisions of low-knowl- edge voters than their high-knowledge counterparts, who focused on more sophisticated considerations such as policy or the economy. Reproducing this study in a different setting would provide a test of this theory.28 On multiple fronts, therefore, the findings of this study are both surprising and difficult to explain, at least with TES data. The results above present other promising avenues for new research, which may further our under- standing of economic voting in understudied settings such as municipalities. Future research is required to test for the presence of economic voting, as well as the moderating effect of knowledge upon economic voting, in other settings, and, perhaps more importantly, also to explain it. In addition, our analysis of ward elections has focused upon the economy of Toronto as a whole, but the effect of ward-level economic conditions should also be

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 20 Urban Affairs Review considered—a more geographically specific economic measure would be required to do so. Finally, the measure of government impact considered in Tables 1 and 2 suggests the direction, but not the magnitude, of economic effects. A more precise measure may provide additional insight into citizen attitudes toward governmental impact upon the economy and vote choice. The characteristics of the 2014 Toronto election combine to provide a stiff test for economic voting to appear. Despite a highly complex institutional environment with multiple levels of government, a relatively weak municipal level of government, a weak mayor system, a mayor stripped of most of his powers, and an election where economic matters were reportedly of minimal importance to voters, municipal economic conditions nevertheless had a noteworthy influence in the vote decisions of Torontonians in the 2014 Toronto election. If we see economic voting present in a case as institution- ally set against it as Toronto, we might expect the presence of economic vot- ing in many other municipal contexts with less stringent institutional opposition. For mayoral candidates, our study therefore suggests that it is far from stupid to focus upon the economy.

Appendix Survey Questions

Economic variables.Governments at all levels make decisions that impact the lives of citizens. Please rank each level of government in terms of the amount of impact its decisions have upon your quality of life: municipal, provincial, and federal. Have the policies of the municipal government made Toronto’s economy better, worse, or not made much of a difference? Have the policies of the provincial government made Toronto’s economy better, worse, or not made much of a difference? Have the policies of the federal government made Toronto’s economy better, worse, or not made much of a difference? Over the past year, has Toronto’s economy gotten better, gotten worse, or stayed about the same?

Knowledge of jurisdictional responsibilities.Which level of government has pri- marily responsibility for the following policy areas? Employment insurance, social housing, health care, primary and secondary education, defense policy, transit and transportation, sewage and water, and police and fire services.

Sociodemographic characteristics.Dummies for gender, immigrant status, ethnic minority, age (over median age), university education, income (over median

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 21

income), home ownership, geography (dummies for North York, Scarbor- ough and Etobicoke, base = Toronto).

Economic conservatism index. Do you agree/disagree with the following state- ments: Government should leave it up to the private sector to create jobs, government should see to it that everyone has a decent standard of living.

Candidate evaluations. How do you feel about the following mayoral candi- dates on a scale from 0 to 100, where 0 means you really dislike the candi- date, and 100 means you really like the candidate? (Doug Ford, Olivia Chow, John Tory, Rob Ford)

Vote choice. Which mayoral candidate did you vote for? Which City Council candidate did you vote for in your ward?

Additional questions. In your opinion, how similar are Doug Ford’s policies to those is his brother Rob?

Quality control question. To ensure that your browser is downloading the con- tent of this survey correctly, please select option “four” below.

Ideological placement of candidates. On a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 means left and 10 means right, where would you place (Doug Ford, Olivia Chow, John Tory, Rob Ford)?

Declaration of Conflicting Interests The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Funding The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article: The authors acknowledge the financial support from the Social Science and Humanities Research Council of Canada (Insight Development Grant #430-2014-00700).

Notes 1. Data were collected through a two-wave Internet survey. The first wave was administered in the weeks leading up to the election (from September 19 until October 27) whereas the second was administered shortly after election day (from October 28 until November 3). The sampling frame included eligible

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 22 Urban Affairs Review

voters only (those individuals over 18 who are Canadian citizens and who live in Toronto). Respondents were recruited through existing panels from an estab- lished Canadian survey firm and were compensated for their responses. To maxi- mize the representativeness of our results, data have been weighted for gender, age, and education level to match the actual population of Toronto. Weighting is particularly important with Internet surveys, as there may be some concern that the sample is not representative of the population. Although we minimize concern of representativeness through the use of controls and weighting, it is nevertheless worth briefly comparing our sample with the population (based upon data from the most recent Census, 2011). According to , 52.7% of eligible voters in Toronto were female, though women represent 43.4% of Toronto Election Study (TES) respondents. Among the voting age popula- tion, 30.9% was between the ages of 18 and 34, 37.0% between 35 and 54, and another 32.0% over the age of 54. The share of TES respondents in these catego- ries was 20.9%, 36.9%, and 32.0%, respectively. Although the TES sample thus does differ slightly from the population with respect to gender and age, these proportions are brought to exactly match population values through the use of weighting. 2. The role of partisan or candidate bias in considering the effect of economic evaluations on casting a ballot in support of the incumbent has been a source of significant debate in the economic voting literature. In short, the argument is that the consideration of the effects of economic evaluations on vote choice is corrupted because partisan or candidate bias is significantly entwined with the formation of positive and negative economic evaluations in the first instance. In the case of the Toronto Election, this argument would suggest that evaluations of Rob (and/or Doug) Ford significantly contributed to respondents’ perceptions of Toronto’s economic conditions—positive evaluations of the Fords lead to posi- tive evaluations of the economy. As such, economic evaluations are claimed to be endogenous and cannot reliably be distinguished from candidate choice. This possibility has been extensively debated, and the conclusions remain mixed. Some (e.g., C. J. Anderson, Mendes, and Tverdova 2004; Evans and Andersen 2006) find evidence of endogeneity whereas others (e.g., Lewis-Beck 2006; Lewis-Beck, Nadeau, and Elias 2008) dispute these findings. 3. Although there is mixed evidence on the effect of infrastructure investment on economic development (Kemmerling and Stephan 2002; Kessides 1993), Canadian municipal governments rely heavily on contributions from federal and provincial government when engaging in such investments. As a result, even if such investments lead to economic payoffs, municipal governments in Canada cannot claim significant credit for them. 4. Since 2006, Toronto’s mayor has had the authority to appoint a 12-member executive committee (EC) from City Council (Lu 2006). This committee acts as the municipal government’s executive, is nominally responsible for the budget, and members of the committee act as chairs of the various standing committees. However, the 12 members and mayor only account for 27% of votes on council (12 of 45), and the EC lacks the authority to hire and fire staff. Even EC members

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 23

have proven to have limited loyalties to mayor, a fact made clear during the ten- ure of both former mayors Rob Ford and David Miller (Church and Hui 2013; Dale 2013b; Vincent 2009). 5. The scandal that led to Ford’s loss of authority began on May 16, 2013, when the website Gawker reported that it had been offered a video purportedly showing then Mayor Rob Ford smoking crack cocaine. Later that day, two reporters from the claimed they had seen the video (Doolittle and Donovan 2013). After the story broke about the video, the Mayor’s behavior came under greater scrutiny, with a number of reports emerging of him being high or intoxicated at various events (Lu, Rider, and Kane 2013; Mahoney and Rogers 2013). In early November, the mayor apologized for being drunk in public, and then admitted to smoking crack in the video (Church and Friesen 2013; Dale 2013c, 2013d). The mayor’s behavior, admission to smoking crack in the video, and refusal to seek help finally led to City Council stripping him of most of his authority on November 18, 2013 (Mendleson and Edwards 2013). Importantly for this article, the scandal was not economic in nature, meaning that the scandal should theo- retically have no impact upon economic voting. 6. It is also important to note that the scandal surrounding Rob Ford received rela- tively little attention after he was replaced on the ballot by his brother Doug. 7. Vancouver is one of a minority of cities in Canada that have political parties at the local level. As a result, Cutler and Matthews’ work may have limited applicabil- ity when examining Toronto. Unlike Toronto’s ward elections, Vancouver elects its councillors using an at-large, list system—voters vote for all council posi- tions. The 15 candidates with most votes are elected. Over the last few decades, Vancouver has also developed a fairly robust party system (party affiliation is indicated next to candidates’ names on the ballot). Since the emergence of party politics in Vancouver, the mayor, who is also elected at large, has always been the leader of the party with the most seats on council. As a result, Vancouver’s mayor has acquired significant authority when compared with Toronto’s, and councillors tend to vote as a block on Council. 8. Outside of Canada, a few studies exist that consider economic influences on local elections. Both Vermeir and Heyndels (2006) and Bosch and Solé-Ollé (2007) assessed the role of tax policy and intermunicipal comparison (yardstick competition) in municipal election outcomes in Flanders and Spain, respectively. 9. Note that Toronto has 44 wards. Councillors are elected under a single-member plurality electoral system. 10. Results from the TES indicate that 13.3% of respondents thought that the Toronto economy had improved, 34.5% thought it had worsened, and 44% thought it had stayed the same over the previous 12 months (8.2% didn’t know). So while the modal category was a neutral perception, more thought that the economy had worsened than improved. For comparison, objective indicators of the condition of the Toronto economy suggested a mixed picture. In May of 2014, the unem- ployment rate in the City of Toronto stood at 9.2% and while this was down from the time of the previous election in 2010 (where unemployment hovered around 10%), this was up by 0.8% over the previous 12 months (Toronto 2014a). By

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 24 Urban Affairs Review

contrast, gross domestic product (GDP) growth for Toronto remained consis- tently positive since the previous election with average annual rates of growth ranging between 1% and 3% (Toronto 2014b). So on balance, TES respondents tended to be a little more pessimistic about the condition of the economy than was actually the case. 11. High-knowledge voters are those who answered more than 50% of the eight knowledge questions correctly (76% of cases are in this category), and low- knowledge voters are those who answered 50% or fewer correctly (24% of cases fall into this group). Note that the mean number of correct answers was 5.6 out of 8. Our decision to define low-knowledge voters using a cutoff point of 50% or fewer questions reflects a desire to identify those voters who are low knowledge in absolute, rather than simply in relative terms. Nevertheless, we did run a test of the robustness of the findings below, whereby knowledge was divided into three terciles, and our substantive findings remain unchanged: The economic effects upon vote choice are different for low- and high-knowledge voters. 12. It should be noted that, although we exclude these respondents from our sam- ple for theoretical reasons, the substantive conclusions of our analysis remain unchanged if these cases are included. 13. There are other reasons to see Doug as a pseudoincumbent. TES respondents also rated the two brothers quite similarly—the Pearson correlation between 101-point feeling thermometers for the two brothers is an impressive .90. In addition, the TES has data on preelection vote intention that shows that an over- whelming majority (94%) of decided Doug supporters claimed that they would have supported Rob if he were running. Finally, electors viewed the brothers very similarly in ideological terms—assigning Doug an average score of 7.35 on a left (0) right (10) scale, and Rob an average value of 7.33. 14. Incumbents were present in all wards except 2, 3, 4, 5, 16, 20, and 39. The TES was administered online and contained a quality control question to weed out respondents who were not taking the survey seriously. Those individuals who failed this question (3.1% of the sample) are excluded from all analysis here. 15. It is conceivable that the wording of this survey question, which implies that gov- ernments are impactful, might bias respondents against the “not much of a differ- ence” response. If such a bias exists, however, it should apply to equally to the three levels of government. The finding that respondents are just as likely to believe the municipal government has impacted the economy as the other two levels of govern- ment should therefore not be influenced by any potential bias of this nature. 16. We argue that the inclusion of both the candidate ratings and the incumbent sat- isfaction variable further mitigate concern about endogeneity in these estimates of economic effects on vote choice. 17. As determined using the “margins” command in STATA following the base may- oral model above. 18. Even in a bivariate analysis, the economy is unrelated to vote choice in ward elections. 19. Note that if the mayoral model is limited to only those cases included in the ward model, the economy variable remains positive and statistically significant. Such

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 25

a finding suggests that the difference in the mayoral and ward results is not due to the restriction of the ward model to particular wards. It also suggests that those people without a councillor to blame/credit are no more likely to blame/credit the mayor than are those who do not have such an option. 20. Although we have chosen to employ a dummy knowledge variable here for theoretical reasons, the substantive conclusions of the models in Table 3 remain unchanged when an interval version of the knowledge variable is used instead. 21. Note that the knowledge variable is also insignificant if included in the mayoral and ward models without the interaction terms. 22. While insignificant, the interaction term in the ward model is also negative. The p value is .14, which by itself is likely not worthy of mention. In light of the surprising positive result from the mayoral model, however, the finding provides some suggestive evidence that the interaction of economic considerations and jurisdictional knowledge does indeed have an effect at the ward level. 23. Values were determined using postestimation, manipulating the economy and knowledge variables but leaving all other variables unchanged. 24. Note that the predicted rate of Ford support among the entire sample considered in Figure 1 is 23.8%. 25. We should note that some care should be taken when making this comparison, as Cutler and Matthews’ model was specified in a slightly different manner (their model did not include measures of candidate evaluations). 26. Although Rob Ford claimed to make dramatic changes to the City’s finances, when compared with Miller’s tenure, there is little evidence of a substantial change. Property tax increases were marginally lower under Ford, but user fees were increased (Dale 2013a; Toronto n.d.). 27. TES data suggest a relationship between vote choice and the belief that the municipal government impacted the economy. Ford voters were less likely to think that the municipal government had no impact (40.5%) than were those individuals who voted for other candidates (48.1%). Unsurprisingly, they are also much more likely to be of the opinion that the policies of the municipal government had a positive impact upon the economy than other voters (39.8% vs. 11.9%). 28. Still another explanation for this finding may be that high- and low-knowledge voters tend to focus upon different types of factors, or issues, when making their vote choice. Specifically, it may conceivably be the case that high-knowledge voters place more emphasis on specific issues, rather than the economy more generally. TES data suggest that this is not the case. The data set includes a series of questions on how important respondents believe a series of issues are (includ- ing transit, traffic and congestion, taxes, and municipal finances). We interacted each of these terms with knowledge and added these variables to the large may- oral model from Table 3. None of the interaction terms were close to statisti- cal significance, indicating that knowledge did not moderate the effect of issue importance upon support for Ford. Thus, knowledge moderates the relationship between economic evaluations and vote choice, but not between attitudes toward issue importance and vote choice.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 26 Urban Affairs Review

References Anderson, Cameron D. 2006. “Economic Voting and Multilevel Governance: An Individual-Level Analysis.” American Journal of Political Science 50 (2): 449– 63. Anderson, Cameron D. 2008. “Economic Voting, Multilevel Governance and Information in Canada.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 41 (2): 329–54. Anderson, Christopher J. 2000. “Economic Voting and Political Context: A Comparative Perspective.” Electoral Studies 19 (2): 151–70. Anderson, Christopher J., Silvia M. Mendes, and Yuliya V. Tverdova. 2004. “Endogenous Economic Voting: Evidence from the 1997 British Election.” Electoral Studies 23 (4): 683–708. Armstrong, James. 2014. “Transit, Infrastructure the Top Issues in Toronto, Poll Says.” Global News, October 14. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://global- news.ca/news/1613939/transit-infrastructure-the-top-issue-in-toronto-poll-says/. Atkeson, Lonna R., and Randall W. Partin. 1995. “Economic and Referendum Voting: A Comparison of Gubernatorial and Senatorial Elections.” American Political Science Review 89 (1): 99–107. Bartik, Timothy J. 1985. “Business Location Decisions in the United States: Estimates of the Effects of Unionization, Taxes, and Other Characteristics.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 3 (1): 14–22. Blair, John P., and Robert Premus. 1987. “Major Factors in Industrial Location: A Review.” Economic Development Quarterly 1 (1): 72–85. Bosch, Nuria, and Albert Solé-Ollé. 2007. “Yardstick Competition and the Political Costs of Raising Taxes: An Empirical Analysis of Spanish Municipalities.” International Tax and Public Finance 14 (1): 71–92. Charney, Alberta H. 1983. “Intraurban Manufacturing Location Decisions and Local Tax Differentials.” Journal of Urban Economics 14 (2): 184–205. Church, Elizabeth, and Joe Friesen. 2013. “Toronto Mayor Rob Ford Apologizes, but Will Not Step Down, After Admitting to Smoking Crack.” The Globe and Mail, November 5. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.theglobeandmail.com/ news/toronto/rob-ford-councillors/article15263319/ Church, Elizabeth, and Ann Hui. 2013. “Mayor’s Allies Prepare to Run City.” The Globe and Mail, May 24. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.theglobeandmail.com/ news/toronto/mayor-rob-fords-allies-prepare-to-run-toronto/article12123758/. Cutler, Fred, and Scott Matthews. 2005. “The Challenge of Municipal Voting: Vancouver 2002.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 38 (2): 359–82. Dale, Daniel. 2013a. “Fact Check: How True Are Rob Ford’s Economic Claims?” Toronto Star, August 30. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.thestar.com/ news/city_hall/2013/08/30/fact_check_how_true_are_rob_fords_economic_ claims.html. Dale, Daniel. 2013b. “Paul Ainslie resigns from Rob Ford’s executive” Toronto Star, October 12. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.thestar.com/news/city_ hall/2013/10/11/paul_ainslie_resigns_from_rob_fords_executive.html. Dale, Daniel. 2013c. “Rob Ford Apologizes for Public Drunkenness, but Won’t Step Down.” Toronto Star, November 3. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 27

thestar.com/news/gta/2013/11/03/rob_ford_apologizes_for_public_drunken- ness_but_wont_step_down.html. Dale, Daniel. 2013d. “Rob Ford: ‘Yes, I Have Smoked Crack Cocaine.’” Toronto Star, November 5. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.thestar.com/news/ crime/2013/11/05/rob_ford_yes_i_have_smoked_crack_cocaine.html. Dale, Daniel. 2014. “Rob Ford on Worsening Unemployment Rate: ‘Toronto Is Booming.’” Toronto Star, January 15. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www. thestar.com/news/city_hall/toronto2014election/2014/01/15/rob_ford_on_wors- ening_unemployment_rate_toronto_is_booming.html. Delli Carpini, Michael X., and Scott S. Keeter. 1996. What Americans Know About Politics and Why It Matters. New Haven: Yale Univ. Press. Doolittle, Robyn, and Kevin Donovan. 2013. “Rob Ford in ‘Crack Cocaine’ Video Scandal.” Toronto Star, May 16. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www. thestar.com/news/city_hall/2013/05/16/toronto_mayor_rob_ford_in_crack_ cocaine_video_scandal.html. Ebeid, Michael, and Jonathan Rodden. 2006. “Economic Geography and Economic Voting: Evidence from the US States.” British Journal of Political Science 36 (3): 527–47. Evans, Geoffrey, and Robert Andersen. 2006. “The Political Conditioning of Economic Perceptions.” The Journal of Politics 68 (1): 194–207. Fair, Ray. 1996. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President: 1992 Update.” Political Behavior 18 (2): 119–39. Fiorina, Morris. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven: Yale Univ. Press. Fournier, Patrick. 2002. “The Uninformed Canadian Voter.” In Citizen Politics: Research and Theory in Canadian Political Behaviour, edited by Joanna Everitt and Brenda O’Neill, 92–109. Toronto: Oxford Univ. Press. Gee, Marcus. 2013. “Rob Ford’s Numbers Simply Don’t Add Up.” The Globe and Mail, November 22. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.theglobeandmail. com/news/toronto/rob-fords-numbers-simply-dont-add-up/article15558420/. Gélineau, Francois. 2007. “Presidents, Political Context, and Economic Accountability Evidence from Latin America.” Political Research Quarterly 60 (3): 415–28. Gélineau, Francois, and Eric Bélanger. 2005. “Electoral Accountability in a Federal System: National and Provincial Economic Voting in Canada.” Publius: The Journal of Federalism 35 (3): 407–24. Green, Gary, Arnold Fleischmann, and Tsz M. Kwong. 1996. “The Effectiveness of Local Economic Development Policies in the 1980s.” Social Science Quarterly 77 (3): 609–25. Happy, J. R. 1992. “The Effect of Economic and Fiscal Performance on Incumbency Voting: The Canadian Case.” British Journal of Political Science 22 (1): 117– 30. Hetherington, Marc. 1996. “The Media’s Role in Forming Voters’ National Economic Evaluations in 1992.” American Journal of Political Science 40 (2): 372–95. Johnston, Richard, Andre Blais, Elisabeth Gidengil, and Neil Nevitte. 1996. The Challenge of Direct Democracy: The 1992 Canadian Referendum. Montréal: McGill-Queen’s Univ. Press.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 28 Urban Affairs Review

Kaufman, Karen M. 2004. The Urban Voter: Group Conflict and Mayoral Voting Behaviour in American Cities. Ann Arbor: Univ. of Michigan Press. Kemmerling, Achim, and Andreas Stephan. 2002. “The Contribution of Local Public Infrastructure to Private Productivity and Its Political Economy: Evidence from a Panel of Large German Cities.” Public Choice 113 (3–4): 403–24. Kessides, Christine. 1993. The Contributions of Infrastructure to Economic Development: A Review of Experience and Policy Implications. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Kitchen, Harry M., and Enid Slack. 2003. “Special Study: New Finance Options for Municipal Governments.” Canadian Tax Journal 51 (6): 2215–75. Kramer, Gerald H. 1971. “Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896– 1964.” American Political Science Review 65 (1): 131–43. Kushner, Joseph, David Siegel, and Hannah Stanwick. 1997. “Ontario Municipal Elections: Voting Trends and Determinants of Electoral Success in a Canadian Province.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 30 (3): 539–53. León, Sandra. 2011. “Who Is Responsible for What? Clarity of Responsibilities in Multilevel States: The Case of Spain.” European Journal of Political Research 50 (1): 80–109. Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 1988. Economics and Elections: The Major Western Democracies. : Univ. of Michigan Press. Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 2006. “Does Economics Still Matter? Econometrics and the Vote.” The Journal of Politics 68 (1): 208–12. Lewis-Beck, Michael S., Richard Nadeau, and Angelo Elias. 2008. “Economics, Party and the Vote: Causality Issues and Panel Data.” American Journal of Political Science 52 (1): 84–95. Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Mary Stegmaier. 2000. “Economic Determinants of Electoral Outcomes.” Annual Review of Political Science 3 (1): 183–219. Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Mary Stegmaier. 2008. “Economic Models of Voting.” In The Oxford Handbook of Political Behavior, edited by Russell Dalton and Hans-Dieter Klingemann, 518–37. Oxford: Oxford Univ. Press. Lodge, Milton, and Ruth Hamill. 1986. “A Partisan Schema for Political Information Processing.” American Political Science Review 80 (2): 505–19. Lu, Vanessa. 2006. “Toronto’s Mayor Gets Power Boost.” Toronto Star, June 28, Page A-1. Lu, Vanessa, David Rider, and Laura Kane. 2013. “Mayor Rob Ford appears to slur words at Taste of the Danforth, videos show.” Toronto Star, August 10. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.thestar.com/news/gta/2013/08/10/mayor_rob_ ford_appears_to_slur_words_at_taste_of_the_danforth_videos_show.html. Lupia, Arthur, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1998. The Democratic Dilemma: Can Citizens Learn What They Need to Know. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press. Mahoney, Jill, and Kaleigh Rogers. 2013. “New Video of ‘Extremely Inebriated’ Toronto Mayor Rob Ford surfaces.” The Globe and Mail, November 7. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.theglobeandmail.com/news/toronto/nw-ford- video/article15310059/.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 29

Martins, Rodrigo, and Francisco Veiga. 2013. “Economic Voting in Portuguese Municipal Elections.” Public Choice 155 (3–4): 317–34. Mendleson, Rachel, and Peter Edwards. 2013. “Rob Ford Stripped of Power as Council.” Toronto Star, November 18. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.thestar.com/news/city_hall/2013/11/18/rob_ford_stripped_of_ power_as_mayor_by_toronto_council.html. Moloney, Paul, and Jennifer Pagliaro. 2014. “Mayor Rob Ford’s $1 Billion Savings Claim ‘Misleading,’ Staff Say.” Toronto Star, April 28. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.thestar.com/news/city_hall/2014/04/28/mayor_rob_fords_1_ billion_savings_claim_misleading_staff_say.html. Nadeau, Richard, and Andre Blais. 1993. “Explaining Election Outcomes in Canada: Economy and politics.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 26 (4): 775–90. Niemi, Richard G., Harold W. Stanley, and Ronald J. Vogel. 1995. “State Economies and State Taxes: Do Voters Hold Governors Accountable?” American Journal of Political Science 39 (4): 936–57. Oliver, James, and Shang Ha. 2007. “Vote Choice in Suburban Elections.” American Political Science Review 101 (3): 393–408. Peters, Alan, and Peter Fisher. 2004. “The Failure of Economic Development Incentives.” Journal of the American Planning Association 70 (1): 27–37. Popkin, Samuel L. 1991. The Reasoning Voter: Communication and Persuasion in Presidential Elections. Chicago: Univ. of Chicago. Powell, G. Bingham, and Guy Whitten. 1993. “A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (2): 391–414. Riba, Clara, and Agusti Bosch. 2005. “Vote and Economic Situaiton in Spain, 1985– 1996.” Papers: Revista de sociolgia 75:117–40. Riba, Clara, and A. Diaz. 2002. “Economic Voting in Subnational Government: Catalonian Evidence.” In Economic Voting, edited by Han Dorusson and Michael Taylor, 173–99. New York: Routledge. Sanders, David. 2005. “The Political Economy of UK Party Support, 1997–2004: Forecasts for the 2005 General Election.” Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 15 (1): 47–71. Schneider, Mark. 1992. “Undermining the Growth Machine: The Missing Link Between Local Economic Development and Fiscal Payoffs.” The Journal of Politics 54 (1): 214–30. Sellers, Jeffrey M., Daniel Kübler, Alan R. Walks, and Melanie Walter-Rogg. 2013. The Political Ecology of the Metropolis. Colchester, UK: European Consortium of Political Research Press. Shah, Maryam. 2013. “Mayor Rob Ford Insists He Created Jobs.” Toronto Sun, September 15. Accessed November 18, 2015. http://www.torontosun. com/2013/09/15/mayor-rob-ford-insists-he-created-jobs Singer, Matthew. 2013. “Economic Voting in an Era of Non-crisis: The Changing Electoral Agenda in Latin America, 1982–2010.” Comparative Politics 45 (2): 169–85.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 30 Urban Affairs Review

Slack, Enid. 2009. “Guide to Municipal Finance.” In The Human Settlements Financing Tools and Best Practices Series. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT. Slack, Enid. 2011. “Financing Large Cities and Metropolitan Areas.” IMFG Papers on Municipal Finance and Governance No. 3, The Institute on Municipal Finance and Governance, Toronto. Sniderman, Paul M., Richard A. Brody, and Philip E. Tetlock. 1991. Reasoning and Choice: Explorations in Political Psychology. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press. Stanwick, Hannah. 2000. “A Megamayor for All People? Voting Behaviour and Electoral Success in the 1997 Toronto Municipal Election.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 33 (3): 549–68. Statistics Canada. 2011. “Census Profile—Toronto Census Subdivision.” Accessed November 7, 2015. https://www12.statcan.gc.ca/census-recensement/2011/ dp-pd/prof. Stein, Robert. M. 1990. “Economic Voting for Governor and U.S. Senator: The Electoral Consequences of Federalism.” The Journal of Politics 52 (1): 29–53. Suen, Fan-Yee. 2014. “Transit and Gridlock Top Election Issues: New Poll.” CTV News, September 3. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://toronto.ctvnews.ca/tran- sit-and-gridlock-top-election-issues-new-poll-1.1988507. Tellier, Genevieve. 2006. “Effect of Economic Conditions on Government Popularity: The Canadian Provincial Case.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 39 (1): 27–51. Toronto. 2014a. “Economic Development (ED).” Presentation on Economic Dashboard, June 11. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.toronto.ca/leg- docs/mmis/2014/ed/bgrd/backgroundfile-70700.pdf. Toronto. 2014b. “Economic Development and Culture (EDC).” Report from the General Manager, Economic Development and Culture on Economic Dashboard, May 9. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.toronto.ca/legdocs/mmis/2014/ ed/bgrd/backgroundfile-69083.pdf. Toronto. 2015. “Toronto 2015 Budget: Budget at a Glance.” In 2015 Staff Recommended Tax and Rate Supported Operating Budget and 2015-2024 Capital Budget and Plan. Toronto: City of Toronto. Toronto. n.d. “Budget Summaries.” Accessed November 18, 2015. http://www1. toronto.ca/wps/portal/contentonly?vgnextoid=96c98f90dba60310VgnVCM100 0003dd60f89RCRD . Vermeir, Jan, and Bruno Heyndels. 2006. “Tax Policy and Yardstick Voting in Flemish Municipal Elections.” Applied Economics 38 (19): 2285–98. Vincent, Donovan. 2009. “Miller’s Long Goodbye Hits Rough Water.” Toronto Star, September 29. Accessed November 7, 2015. http://www.thestar.com/news/ gta/2009/09/29/david_millers_long_goodbye_hits_rough_water.html. Walks, Alan. 2013. “Metropolitan Political Ecology and Contextual Effects in Canada.” In The Political Ecology of the Metropolis, edited by Jeffrey Sellers, Daniel Kübler, Melanie Walter-Rogg and R. Alan Walks, 87-124. Colchester, UK: European Consortium of Political Research Press.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015 Anderson et al. 31

Walks, Alan. 2015. “Stopping the ‘War on the Car’: Neoliberalism, Fordism and the Politics of Automobility in Toronto.” Mobilities 10 (3): 402–22. Watts, Ronald. 2008. Comparing Federal Systems. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s Univ. Press. Whitten, Guy, and Harvey Palmer. 1999. “Cross-National Analyses of Economic Voting.” Electoral Studies 18 (1): 49–67. Wood, Curtis. 2002. “Voter Turnout in City Elections.” Urban Affairs Review 38 (2): 209–31.

Author Biographies Cameron D. Anderson is an associate professor and chair of the Graduate Program in the Department of Political Science at the University of Western Ontario. His research interests include political behavior and Canadian politics. R. Michael McGregor is an assistant professor in the Department of Politics and International Studies at Bishop’s University. He studies political behavior, Canadian politics, and the politics of Toronto. Aaron A. Moore is an assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at the University of Winnipeg and a fellow at the Institute on Municipal Finance and Governance, Munk School of Global Affairs, . His research interests include municipal institutions, urban governance, and the politics of urban development. Laura B. Stephenson is an associate professor in the Department of Political Science at the University of Western Ontario. Her research focuses on political behavior and institutions, including the intersection of the two.

Downloaded from uar.sagepub.com at BISHOPS UNIV LIBRARY on December 7, 2015