Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings, and the Liquidity Trap

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings, and the Liquidity Trap NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CREDIT CRISES, PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS, AND THE LIQUIDITY TRAP Veronica Guerrieri Guido Lorenzoni Working Paper 17583 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17583 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 November 2011 We thank Bob Hall and John Leahy for their useful discussions and for numerous exchanges. For helpful comments, we are grateful to Andy Atkeson, Chris Carroll, V. V. Chari, Vasco Curdia, Greg Kaplan, Juan Pablo Nicolini, Thomas Philippon, Valery Ramey, Rob Shimer, Nancy Stokey, Amir Sufi, Gianluca Violante, Iván Werning, Mike Woodford, Pierre Yared, and numerous seminar participants. Adrien Auclert and Amir Kermani provided outstanding research assistance. Guerrieri thanks the Sloan Foundation for financial support and the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis for its hospitality. Lorenzoni thanks the NSF for financial support and Chicago Booth and the Becker Friedman Institute for their hospitality. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2011 by Veronica Guerrieri and Guido Lorenzoni. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings, and the Liquidity Trap Veronica Guerrieri and Guido Lorenzoni NBER Working Paper No. 17583 November 2011 JEL No. E2,E4 ABSTRACT We study the effects of a credit crunch on consumer spending in a heterogeneous-agent incomplete-market model. After an unexpected permanent tightening in consumers’ borrowing capacity, some consumers are forced to deleverage and others increase their precautionary savings. This depresses interest rates, especially in the short run, and generates an output drop, even with flexible prices. The output drop is larger with nominal rigidities, if the zero lower bound prevents the interest rate from adjusting downwards. Adding durable goods to the model, households take larger debt positions and the output response may be larger. Veronica Guerrieri University of Chicago Booth School of Business 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue Chicago, IL 60637 and NBER [email protected] Guido Lorenzoni MIT Department of Economics E52-251C 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142-1347 and NBER [email protected] 1 Introduction How does an economy adjust from a regime of easy credit to one of tight credit? Suppose it is relatively easy for consumers to borrow and the economy is in a stationary state with a stable distribution of borrowing and lending positions. An unexpected shock hits the financial system and borrowing gets harder in terms of tighter borrowing limits and/or in terms of higher credit spreads. The most indebted consumers need to readjust towards lower levels of debt (delevaraging). Since the debtor position of one agent is the creditor position of another, this also means that lenders have to reduce their holdings of financial claims. How are the spending decisions of borrowers and lenders affected by this economy-wide financial adjustment? What happens to aggregate activity? How long does the adjustment last? In this paper, we address these questions, focusing on the response of the household sector, using a workhorse Bewley (1977) model in which households borrow and lend to smooth transitory income fluctuations. Since the model cannot be solved analytically, our approach is to obtain numerical results under plausible parametrizations and then to explore the mechanism behind them. The model captures two channels in the con- sumers’ response to a reduction in their borrowing capacity. First, a direct channel, by which constrained borrowers are forced to reduce their indebtedness. Second, a pre- cautionary channel, by which unconstrained agents increase their savings as a buffer against future shocks. Both channels increase net lending in the economy, so the equi- librium interest rate has to fall in equilibrium. Our analysis leads to two sets of results. First, we look at interest rate dynamics and show that they are characterized by a sharp initial fall followed by a gradual adjustment to a new, lower steady state. The reason for this interest rate overshooting is that, at the initial asset distribution, the agents at the lower end of the distribution try to adjust faster towards a higher savings target. So the initial increase in net lending is stronger. To keep the asset market in equilibrium, interest rates have to fall sharply. As the asset distribution converges to the new steady state the net lending pressure subsides and the interest rate moves gradually up. Second, we look at the responses of aggregate activity. Overly indebted agents can adjust in two ways: by spending less and by working more. In our model they do both, 1 so, for a given interest rate, the credit shock would lead to a reduction in consumer spending and to an increase in labor supply. Whether a recession follows depends on the relative strength of these two forces and on the interest rate elasticity of consumption and labor supply. In our baseline calibration, the consumption side dominates and out- put declines. As for the case of interest rates, the contraction is stronger in the short run, when the distribution of asset holdings is far from its new steady state and some agents are far below their savings target. A tightening of the credit limit that reduces household debt-to-GDP by 10 percentage points generates a 1% drop in output on impact. We then add nominal rigidities to the model. In presence of nominal rigidities, the zero lower bound on the nominal interest rate means that the central bank may be unable to achieve the real interest rate that replicates the flexible price allocation. Moreover, with nominal rigidities, aggregate activity is purely driven by the response of consumer demand. Therefore, when the zero lower bound is binding the households’ net saving pressure translates into a larger output drop. Finally, we generalize the model to include durable consumption goods, which can be used as collateral. In this extension, households face a richer portfolio choice as they can invest in liquid bonds or in durable goods. To make bonds and durables imperfect substitutes, we assume a proportional cost of re-selling durables, so that durables are less liquid. After a credit crunch, net borrowers are forced to delevarage and have to reduce consumption of durable and non-durable goods. On the other hand, the pre- cautionary motive induces net lenders to save more by accumulating both bonds and durables. Durable purchases may increase or decrease, depending on the strength of these two effects. In our calibration, the net effect depends on the nature of the shock. A pure shock to the credit limit affects only borrowers close to the limit, so the lenders’ side dominates and durable purchases increase. A shock to credit spreads, on the other hand, affects a larger fraction of borrowers, leading to a contraction in durable purchases. Here the output effects can be large, leading to a 4% drop in consumption following a transi- tory shock that raises the spread on a one year loan from 1% to 3.8%. The consumption drop can be as large as 10% if prices are fixed and the zero lower bound is binding. Our paper focuses on households’ balance sheets adjustment and consumer spend- ing and is complementary to a growing literature that looks at the effects of credit shocks 2 on firms’ balance sheets and investment spending.1 Hall (2011a, 2011b) argues that the response of the household sector to the credit tightening is an essential ingredient to ac- count for the recent U.S. recession. Mian and Sufi (2011a, 2011b) use cross-state evidence to argue that the contraction in households’ borrowing capacity, mainly driven by a de- cline in house prices, was responsible for the fall in consumer spending and, eventually, for the increase in unemployment. Our model aims to capture the effects of a similar contraction in households’ borrowing capacity in general equilibrium. In modeling the household sector, we follow the vast literature on consumption and saving in incomplete market economies with idiosyncratic income uncertainty, going back to Bewley (1977), Deaton (1991), Huggett (1993), Aiyagari (1994), Carroll (1997).2 Our approach is to compute the economy’s transitional dynamics after a one-time, un- expected aggregate shock. This relates our paper to recent contributions that look at transitional dynamics after different types of shocks.3 Much work on business cycles in economies with heterogenous agents and incomplete markets, follows Krusell and Smith (1998) and looks at approximate equilibria in which prices evolve as functions of a finite set of moments of the wealth distribution. Here, we prefer to keep the entire wealth distribution as a state variable at the cost of focusing on a one time shock, be- cause our shock affects very differently agents in different regions of the distribution.4 Midrigan and Philippon (2011) take a different (and complementary) approach to mod- eling the effects of a credit crunch on the household sector. They use a cash-in-advance model to explore the idea that credit access, as money, is needed to facilitate transac- tions. Finally, our model with durables is related to Carroll and Dunn (1997), an early paper that uses an heterogenous agent, incomplete market model with durable and non- durable goods to look at the dynamics of consumer debt and spending following a shock 1Classic models of the role of firms’ balance sheets are Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999). Recent contributions include Jermann and Quadrini (2009), Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2010), Gertler and Kiyotaki (2010), Khan and Thomas (2010), Buera and Moll (2011), Del Negro, Eggertsson, Ferrero, and Kiyotaki (2011), Cagetti, De Nardi, and Bassetto (2011).
Recommended publications
  • Perceived Precautionary Savings Motives: Evidence from Fintech
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PERCEIVED PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVES: EVIDENCE FROM FINTECH Francesco D’Acunto Thomas Rauter Christoph K. Scheuch Michael Weber Working Paper 26817 http://www.nber.org/papers/w26817 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 March 2020 We thank Fabian Nagel, Tom Kim, Hannah Amann, and especially Federica Ansbacher for excellent research assistance. We appreciate helpful comments from Sumit Agarwal, Greg Buchak, Indraneel Chakraborty, Francisco Gomes, Sabrina Howell, David Low, Amit Seru, Wenlan Qian, and workshop participants at the Columbia “New Technologies in Finance” Conference, the 2019 Red Rock Finance Conference, the 2019 Summer Finance Conference at ISB, the 7th ABFER Annual Conference, the 2019 LBS Summer Finance Symposium, the 2019 CFPB Conference, and the 2020 AEA and AFA Annual Meeting. D’Acunto gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation. Rauter and Weber gratefully acknowledge financial support from the IBM Corporation Faculty Fellowship and the Fama Faculty Fellowship at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business. Scheuch gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Austrian Science Fund (FWF project number DK W 1001-G16). The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2020 by Francesco D’Acunto, Thomas Rauter, Christoph K. Scheuch, and Michael Weber. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.
    [Show full text]
  • Precautionary Saving in a Macroeconomic Perspective: a Comparison Between New Keynesian and Post Keynesian Consumption Theory §
    Precautionary Saving in a macroeconomic perspective: A comparison between New Keynesian and Post Keynesian consumption theory x Jan-Oliver Menz∗ October 22, 2007 Abstract The following paper gives a survey of the current state of consumer theory. It shows that the New Keynesian theory of Precautionary Saving has again come to more traditional Keynesian results already highlighted by Post Keynesians during the last decades. The often ne- glected consumer theory in the Post Keynesian paradigm is expanded using insights from both Economic Sociology and Behavioural Eco- nomics. Finally, the paper will disuss both agreement and disagree- ment between the two theoretical strands. Keywords: Precautionary Saving, Consumption Theory, Post Key- nesianism, New Keynesianism JEL classification: x ∗∗University of Warwick, United Kingdom, jan [email protected] I Conference Paper Contents J.-O. Menz Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Precautionary Saving 2 2.1 Neoclassicals and New Keynesians . 2 2.2 The Model . 3 3 The Postkeynesian Theory of Consumption 6 3.1 Social Class Behaviour . 6 3.2 Risk and Uncertainty . 9 3.3 The Model . 12 4 Macroeconomic implications 15 4.1 Derivation of the New Keynesian IS-curve with precautionary saving . 15 4.2 Derivation of the Post Keynesian IS-curve . 16 4.3 A New Keynesian model using Post Keynesian insights . 19 5 Summary and Outlook 20 References 22 II Conference Paper 1 Introduction J.-O. Menz 1 Introduction This paper deals with consumption theory using a paradigmatic approach and trying to figure out similarities and differences
    [Show full text]
  • Buffer Stocks and Precautionary Savings with Loss Aversion
    Journal of International Money and Finance 17Ž. 1998 931]947 Buffer stocks and precautionary savings with loss aversion U Joshua Aizenman Economics Department, Dartmouth College, 6106 Rockefeller Hall, Hano¨er, NH 03755-3514, USA Abstract This paper reexamines buffer stocks and precautionary savings in the presence of loss aversion. We assume that agents are disappointment averse, as in Gulw Econometrica, 59 Ž.1991 667]686x . We show that the concavity of the marginal utility continues to determine precautionary saving, but its effect is of a second order magnitudeŽ proportional to the square of the coefficient of variation.Ž compared to the first order effect proportional to the coefficient of variation. induced by loss aversion. We show that a stabilization fund that is rather small when agents are maximizing the conventional expected utility, turns out to be rather large with loss aversion. Q 1998 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. JEL classifications: F39, E21, O16 Keywords: Buffer stocks; Precautionary saving; Loss aversion; Reference point 1. Introduction The purpose of this paper is to show that loss aversion may lead to a much larger optimal size of stabilization funds and precautionary savings than the size predicted if agents are maximizing the conventional expected utility. Loss aversion is the tendency of agents to be more sensitive to reductions in their consumption than to increases relative to a reference point. It characterizes many of the recent general- ized expected utility frameworks. Specifically, we investigate the impact of volatility U Tel.: q1 603 6462531; fax: q1 603 6462122; e-mail: [email protected] 0261-5606r98r$19.00 Q 1998 Elsevier Science Ltd.
    [Show full text]
  • Consumption Puzzles and Precautionary Savings
    Journal of Monetary Economics 25 (1990) 113-136. North-Holland CONSUMPTION PUZZLES AND PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS Ricardo J. CABALLERO* Columbia University, New York, NY 1002 7, USA Received March 1989, final version received October 1989 When marginal utility is convex, agents accumulate savings as a precautionary measure against labor-income eventualities. This paper shows that precautionary savings can go a long way in making the excess-growth, excess-smoothness, and excess-sensitivity features of consumption consistent with the stochastic processes of labor income observed in the U.S. at the microeco- nomic level. 1. Introduction Most of the empirical research on the Life-Cycle/Permanent-Income hy- pothesis (LCH/PIH), which deals with the relation between income and consumption disturbances, uses certainty-equivalence assumptions. One possi- ble explanation for the repeated use of this specification is the degree of difficulty involved in obtaining closed-form solutions in the multiperiod opti- mization problem of a consumer who faces a random sequence of (uninsur- able) labor income and whose utility function is not quadratic.’ Unfortunately, by using a quadratic utility function important aspects of the problem are ignored. Theoretical studies have shown that whenever the utility function is separable and has a positive third derivative (U “’ > 0) - a prop- erty of utility functions that exhibit nonincreasing absolute risk aversion - an increase in labor-income uncertainty, when insurance markets are not com- plete, will reduce current consumption and alter the slope of the consumption path [e.g., Leland (1968), Sandmo (1970), Dreze and Modigliani (1972), Miller (1974, 1976), Caballero (1987a), Kimball (1988), and Skinner (1988)].
    [Show full text]
  • Risk Aversion and Precautionary Savings in Dynamic Settings
    Risk Aversion and Precautionary Savings in Dynamic Settings Antoine Bommier François Le Grand∗ September 15, 2017 Abstract We study the saving behavior of infinitely long-lived agents who face income uncer- tainty and deterministic interest rates. Using monotone recursive preferences, we prove that risk aversion unambiguously increases savings. The result accounts for possibly bind- ing borrowing constraints and holds for very general specification of income uncertainty, which can follow any kind of stochastically monotone process. Keywords: risk aversion, precautionary savings, recursive models, risk-sensitive prefer- ences, monotonicity. JEL codes: D80, D91, E21. 1 Introduction Analyzing the impact of risk on individual behaviors is a long-standing line of research in decision sciences. However, understanding how individuals make decisions in real life situa- tions is a very difficult question to tackle. Indeed, choices under uncertainty may depend on a number of factors, such as risk appetite, the type of decision that has to be made, interaction between the various risks at stake or insurance possibilities. Clear-cut characterizations of individual behavior under risk can only be ascertained when the problem is more precisely specified. One particular issue is the so-called precautionary saving problem, where one seeks to understand how future income uncertainty affects saving decisions. The early works of Leland (1968) and Sandmo (1970) on the issue have been followed by numerous contributions in both the economics and finance literature. In particular, Carroll (1997) emphasized in a seminal paper that precaution –i.e., sensitivity to future income uncertainty– is, quantitatively ∗Bommier: ETH Zurich, [email protected]; Le Grand: emlyon business school and ETH Zurich, [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution Vs. Risk Aversion
    WORKING PAPER NO: 12/27 Determinants of Precautionary Savings: Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution vs. Risk Aversion August 2012 Arif ODUNCU © Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey 2012 Address: Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey Head Office Research and Monetary Policy Department İstiklal Caddesi No: 10 Ulus, 06100 Ankara, Turkey Phone: +90 312 507 54 02 Facsimile: +90 312 507 57 33 The views expressed in this working paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the official views of the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey. The Working Paper Series are externally refereed. The refereeing process is managed by the Research and Monetary Policy Department. Determinants of Precautionary Savings: Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution vs. Risk Aversion Abstract The purpose of this paper is to understand the effects of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (EIS) and risk aversion on savings separately and determine which coefficient is more important factor for precautionary savings. This is an important question since a significant fraction of the capital accumulation is due to precautionary savings according to literature. Thus, knowing the important determinant of precautionary savings will be helpful to understand the capital accumulation mechanism. This paper uses an Epstein-Zin utility function, which permits risk attitudes to be disentangled from the degree of intertemporal substitutability, in the model in order to study the effects of EIS and risk aversion separately. It is shown that saving increases as EIS increases. Similarly, saving increases as the coefficient of risk aversion increases. More importantly, it is observed that EIS is a more important factor for precautionary savings than risk aversion because saving is more responsive to changes in EIS than changes in risk aversion.
    [Show full text]
  • Precautionary Saving and Partially Observed Income$
    ARTICLE IN PRESS Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (2004) 1645–1681 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Precautionary saving and partially observed income$ Neng Wangà Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, 3022 Broadway, Uris Hall 812, New York, NY 10027, USA Received 18 August 2003; received in revised form 3 May 2004; accepted 17 June 2004 Available online 11 November 2004 Abstract I propose an intertemporal precautionary saving model in which the agent’s labor income is subject to (possibly correlated) shocks with different degrees of persistence and volatility. However, he only observes his total income, not individual components. I show that partial observability of individual components of income gives rise to additional precautionary saving due to estimation risk, the error associated with estimating individual components of income. This additional precautionary saving is higher, when estimation risk is greater. Compared with a precautionary agent who is otherwise identical, but ignores estimation risk, the rational agent consumes less at the beginning of his life, but consumes more later, because of larger wealth accumulated from savings for estimation risk. The utility cost of ignoring estimation risk is also quantified in closed form. r 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: D11; D91; E21 Keywords: Precautionary saving; Separation principle; Incomplete information; Kalman filter $I thank Steve Davis, Darrell Duffie, Jeremy Greenwood, Steve Grenadier, Fatih Guvenen, Bob Hall, Ken Judd, Yingcong Lan, Luigi Pistaferri, Charles Plosser, Tom Sargent, John Shoven, Ken Singleton, Chris Telmer, Steve Zeldes, and especially the anonymous referee, for their helpful comments. Yangchun Chu provided excellent research assistance. ÃTel.: +1 212 854 3869.
    [Show full text]
  • How Prudent Are Consumers?
    How Prudent Are Consumers? Karen E. Dynan Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System Using data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey, this paper pre- sents a simple test that provides an explicit estimate of the parameter in the utility function that reflects the strength of the precautionary saving motive, the coefficient of relative prudence. The test yields a fairly precise estimate of a small precautionary motive; in fact, the estimate is too small to be consistent with widely accepted beliefs about risk aversion. The presence of liquidity-constrained house- holds does not appear to explain this finding, and there is some evidence that self-selection of households into risky environments also cannot explain the results. I. Introduction Theories of precautionary saving have intuitive appeal and important empirical implications. Despite the recent emphasis on such theories, however, there have been few direct tests of whether the precaution- ary motive actually is an important force in consumer behavior. Using data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey, this paper presents a simple test that not only indicates whether a precautionary motive is present but also provides an explicit estimate of the parameter in the utility function that reflects the strength of the precautionary motive, the coefficient of relative prudence. As Deaton (1992) emphasizes, uncertainty may substantially alter consumers' behavior. Skinner (1988) derives an approximation for optimal life cycle consumption that implies that, with plausible amounts of income uncertainty and risk aversion, precautionary sav- I would like to thank Larry Ball, Chris Carroll, Doug Elmendorf, Jonathan Skinner, David Weil, Philippe Weil, two anonymous referees, the editor, and especially Greg Mankiw for helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Short-Time Work and Precautionary Savings
    DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 14329 Short-Time Work and Precautionary Savings Thomas Dengler Britta Gehrke APRIL 2021 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 14329 Short-Time Work and Precautionary Savings Thomas Dengler Humboldt University of Berlin Britta Gehrke University of Rostock, IAB and IZA APRIL 2021 Any opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but IZA takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The IZA Institute of Labor Economics is an independent economic research institute that conducts research in labor economics and offers evidence-based policy advice on labor market issues. Supported by the Deutsche Post Foundation, IZA runs the world’s largest network of economists, whose research aims to provide answers to the global labor market challenges of our time. Our key objective is to build bridges between academic research, policymakers and society. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author. IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Schaumburg-Lippe-Straße 5–9 Phone: +49-228-3894-0 53113 Bonn, Germany Email: [email protected] www.iza.org IZA DP No. 14329 APRIL 2021 ABSTRACT Short-Time Work and Precautionary Savings* In the Covid-19 crisis, most OECD countries use short-time work schemes (subsidized working time reductions) to preserve employment relationships.
    [Show full text]
  • Nber Working Paper Series Life Cycle Consumption, And
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RISKY INCOME, LIFE CYCLE CONSUMPTION, AND PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS Jonathan Skinner Working Paper No. 2336 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 1987 I am grateful to Andrew Abel, Charles Engel, Eric Engen, Diane Lim, Steven Lippman, Richard Startz, Stephen Zeldes, participants in the Macroeconomic Workshop at the University of Virginia, and especially Maxim Engers forvery helpful suggestions. The research reported here is part of the NBER's researchprogram in Taxation. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #2336 August 1987 Risky Income, Life Cycle Consumption, and PrecautionarySavings ABSTRACT This paper argues that precautionary savings against uncertain income comprise a large fraction of aggregate savings. A closed-form approximation for life cycle consumption subject to uncertain interestrates and earnings is derived by taking a second-order Taylor-Seriesapproximation of the Euler equations. Using empirical measures of income uncertainty, I find that precautionary savings comprises up to 56 percent of aggregate life cycle savings. The derived expression for n-period optimal consumption iseasily implemented for econometric estimation, and accords well with theexact numerical solution. Empirical comparisons of savings patterns among occupationalgroups using the Consumer Expenditure Survey contradict the predictions of the life cycle model. Riskier: occupations, such as the
    [Show full text]
  • Disentangling the Importance of the Precautionary Saving Motive1
    Disentangling the Importance of the Precautionary Saving Motive1 Arthur Kennickell (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System) and Annamaria Lusardi (Dartmouth College and NBER) November 2005 Abstract We evaluate the importance of the precautionary saving motive by relying on a direct question about precautionary wealth from the 1995 and 1998 waves of the Survey of Consumer Finances. In this survey, a new question has been designed to elicit the amount of desired precautionary wealth. This allows us to assess the amount of precautionary accumulation and to overcome many of the problems of previous works on this topic. We find that a precautionary saving motive exists and affects virtually every type of household. However, precautionary savings account for only 8 percent of total wealth holdings. Even though this motive does not give rise to large amounts of wealth, particularly for young and middle-age households, it is particularly important for two groups: older households and business owners. Overall, we provide strong evidence that we need to take the precautionary saving motive into account when modeling saving behavior. JEL classification: D91, E21, C21. Keywords: Risk, buffer-stock models of saving, old cohorts wealth, business owners wealth. 1Corresponding author: Annamaria Lusardi, Department of Economics, Dartmouth College, 328 Rockefeller Hall, Hanover, NH 03755. Tel: 603-646-2099. Fax: 603-646-2122. E-mail: [email protected]. We would like to thank Rob Alessie, Erich Battistin, Christopher Carroll, Jeffrey Dominitz, Michael Haliassos, Erik Hurst, Michael Palumbo, Jon Skinner, Steven Venti, and participants at the NBER Summer Institute, the TMR Conference on Savings and Pensions, Evian, France, the 21st Arne Ryde Symposium on Non-Human Wealth and Capital Accumulation, Lund, Sweden, the Ente Luigi Einaudi for Monetary, Banking and Financial Studies, Rome, Italy, the plenary session at the 27th Conference of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, Stockholm, Sweden, for suggestions and comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Precautionary Savings, Illiquid Assets, and the Aggregate Consequences of Shocks to Household Income Risk∗
    Precautionary Savings, Illiquid Assets, and the Aggregate Consequences of Shocks to Household Income Risk∗ Christian Bayer,† Ralph Luetticke,‡ Lien Pham-Dao§ and Volker Tjaden¶ June 4, 2018 Abstract Households face large income uncertainty that varies substantially over the busi- ness cycle. We examine the macroeconomic consequences of these variations in a model with incomplete markets, liquid and illiquid assets, and a nominal rigid- ity. Heightened uncertainty depresses aggregate demand as households respond by hoarding liquid “paper” assets for precautionary motives, thereby reducing both illiquid physical investment and consumption demand. We document the empirical response of portfolio liquidity and aggregate activity to surprise changes in idiosyn- cratic income uncertainty and find both to be quantitatively in line with our model. The welfare consequences of uncertainty shocks and of the policy response thereto depend crucially on a household’s asset position. Keywords: Incomplete Markets, Nominal Rigidities, Uncertainty Shocks. JEL-Codes: E22, E12, E32 ∗The paper was circulated before as “Household Income Risk, Nominal Frictions, and Incomplete Markets.” We would like to thank the editor and four anonymous referees, Thomas Hintermaier, Andreas Kleiner, Keith Kuester, Alexander Kriwoluzky and seminar participants in Bonn, Birmingham, Hamburg, Madrid, Mannheim, Konstanz, the EEA-ESEM 2013 in Gothenburg, the SED meetings 2013 in Seoul, the SPP meeting in Mannheim, the Padova Macro Workshop, the 18th Workshop on Dynamic Macro in Vigo, the NASM 2013 in L.A., the VfS 2013 meetings in Düsseldorf, the 2014 Konstanz Seminar on Monetary Theory and Monetary Policy, the ASSET 2014 in Aix-en-Provence and SITE 2015 for helpful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]