Exercises in Recursive Macroeconomic Theory Preliminary and Incomplete

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Exercises in Recursive Macroeconomic Theory Preliminary and Incomplete Exercises in Recursive Macroeconomic Theory preliminary and incomplete Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh Pierre-Olivier Weill Lars Ljungqvist Thomas J. Sargent Introduction This is a ¯rst version of the solutions to the exercises in Recursive Macroeco- nomic Therory, First Edition, 2000, MIT press, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas J. Sargent. This solution manuscript is currently only available on the web. We in- vite the reader to bring typos and other corrections to our attention. Please email [email protected], [email protected] or [email protected]. We will regularly update this manuscript during the following months. Some questions ask for computations in matlab. The program ¯les can be downloaded from the ftp site zia.stanford.edu/pub/sargent/rmtex. The authors, Stanford University, March 15, 2003. Contents Introduction 2 List of Figures 5 Chapter 1. Time series 7 Chapter 2. Dynamic programming 33 Chapter 3. Practical dynamic programming 37 Chapter 4. Linear quadratic dynamic programming 43 Chapter 5. Search, matching, and unemployment 55 Chapter 6. Recursive (partial) equilibrium 83 Chapter 7. Competitive equilibrium with complete markets 95 Chapter 8. Overlapping generation models 109 Chapter 9. Ricardian equivalence 161 Chapter 10. Asset pricing 163 Chapter 11. Economic growth 175 Chapter 12. Optimal taxation with commitment 187 Chapter 13. Self-insurance 201 Chapter 14. Incomplete markets models 211 Chapter 15. Optimal social insurance 223 Chapter 16. Credible government policies 257 Chapter 17. Fiscal-monetary theories of inflation 267 Chapter 18. Credit and currency 283 Chapter 19. Equilibrium search and matching 307 Index 343 3 List of Figures 1 Exercise 1.7 a 21 2 Exercise 1.7 b 22 3 Exercise 1.7 c 22 4 Exercise 1.7 d 23 5 Exercise 1.7 e 23 6 Exercise 1.7 f 24 7 Exercise 1.7 g 24 1 Exercise 3.1 : Value Function Iteration VS Policy Improvement 41 1 Exercise 4.5 52 1 Exercise 8.1 113 1 Exercise 10.1 : Hansen-Jagannathan bounds 165 1 Exercise 13.2 205 1 Exercise 14.2 a 214 2 Exercise 14.2 b 214 3 Exercise 14.2 c 215 4 Exercise 14.5 : Cross-sectional Mean and Dispersion of Consumption and Assets 221 1 Exercise 15.2 226 2 Exercise 15.10 a : Consumption Distribution 238 3 Exercise 15.10 b : Consumption, Promised Utility, Pro¯ts and Bank Balance in Contract that Maximizes the Money Lender's Pro¯ts 239 4 Exercise 15.10 c : Consumption, Promised Utility, Pro¯ts and Bank Balance in Contract that Gives Zero Pro¯ts to Money Lender 240 5 Exercise 15.11 a : Pareto Frontier, ¯ = 0:95 241 6 Exercise 15.11 b : Pareto Frontier, ¯ = 0:85 242 7 Exercise 15.11 c : Pareto Frontier, ¯ = 0:99 243 5 6 LIST OF FIGURES 8 Exercise 15.12 a : Consumption, Promised Utility, Pro¯ts and Bank Balance in Contract that Maximizes the Money Lender's Pro¯ts 245 9 Exercise 15.12 b : Consumption Distribution 246 10 Exercise 15.12 c : Wage-Tenure Pro¯le 247 11 Exercise 15.14 a : Pro¯ts of Money Lender in Thomas-Worral Model 250 12 Exercise 15.14 b Evolution of Consumption Distribution over Time 251 1 Exercise 19.4 a: implicit equation for θi 319 2 Exercise 19.4 b : Solving for unemployment level in each skill market 320 3 Exercise 19.4 b : Solving for the aggregate unemployment level321 4 Exercise 19.5 : Solving for equilibrium unemployment 323 5 Execise 19.6 : Solving for equilibrium unemployment 326 CHAPTER 1 Time series 7 8 1. TIME SERIES Exercise 1.1. :9 :1 :5 Consider the Markov Chain (P; ¼ ) = ; ; where the state 0 :3 :7 :5 µ· ¸ · ¸¶ 1 space is x = : Compute the likelihood of the following three histories for 5 t = 0; 1; 2; 3; 4:· ¸ a. 1,5,1,5,1. b. 1,1,1,1,1. c. 5,5,5,5,5. Solution The probability of observing a given history up to t = 4; say (xi5 ; xi4 ; xi3 ; xi2 ; xi1 ; xi0 ); is given by P (xi4 ; xi3 ; xi2 ; xi1 ; xi0 ) = Pi4;i3 Pi3;i2 Pi2;i1 Pi1;i0 ¼0i0 where P = Prob (x = x x = x ) and ¼ = Prob (x = x ). ij t+1 jj t i 0i 0 i By applying this formula one obtains the following results: a. P (1; 5; 1; 5; 1) = P21P12P21P21¼01 = (:3) (:1) (:3) (:1) (:5) = :00045. 4 b. P (1; 1; 1; 1; 1) = P11P11P11P11¼01 = (:9) (:5) = :3281. 4 c. P (5; 5; 5; 5; 5) = P22P22P22P22¼02 = (:7) (:5) = :12. Exercise 1.2. 1 A Markov chain has state space x = : It is known that E (x x = x) = 5 t+1j t · ¸ 1:8 5:8 and that E x2 x = x = : Find a transition matrix consistent 3:4 t+1j t 15:4 · ¸ · ¸ with these conditional¡ expectations.¢ Is this transition matrix unique (i.e., can you ¯nd another one that is consistent with these conditional expectations)? Solution From the formulas for forecasting functions of a Markov chain, we know that E (h(x ) x = x) = P h; t+1 j t where h(x) is a function of the state represented by an n 1 vector h: Applying this formula yields: £ E (x x = x) = P x and E x2 x = x = P x2: t+1j t t+1j t This yields a set of 4 linear equations: ¡ ¢ 1. TIME SERIES 9 1:8 1 5:8 1 = P and = P ; 3:4 5 15:4 25 · ¸ · ¸ · ¸ · ¸ which can be solved for the 4 unknowns. Alternatively, using matrix notation, we can rewrite this as e = P h, where e = [e1; e2]; e1 = E (xt+1 xt = x) ; e2 = E x2 x = x and h = [h ; h ]; where h = x and h = x2 : j t+1j t 1 2 1 2 ¡ ¢ 1:8 5:8 1 1 = P : 3:4 15:4 5 25 · ¸ · ¸ Then P is uniquely determined as P = eh¡1: Uniqueness follows from the fact that h1 and h2 are linearly independent. After some algebra we obtain a well- de¯ned stochastic matrix: :8 :2 P = : :4 :6 · ¸ Exercise 1.3. Consumption is governed by an n state Markov chain P; ¼0 where P is a stochastic matrix and ¼0 is an initial probability distribution. Consumption takes one of the values in the n 1 vector c¹. A consumer ranks stochastic processes of consumption t = 0; 1 : : : according£ to 1 t E ¯ u(ct); t=0 X c1¡γ where E is the mathematical expectation and u(c) = 1¡γ for some parameter 1 t γ 1. Let ui = u(c¹i). Let vi = E[ t=0 ¯ u(ct) c0 = c¹i] and V = Ev, where ¯ ¸(0; 1) is a discount factor. j 2 P a. Let u and v be the n 1 vectors whose ith components are ui and vi, re- spectively. Verify the follo£wing formulas for v and V : v = (I ¯P )¡1u; and ¡ V = i ¼0;ivi. b. ConsiderP the following two Markov processes: :5 1 0 Process 1: ¼ = , P = . 0 :5 0 1 · ¸ · ¸ :5 :5 :5 Process 2: ¼ = , P = . 0 :5 :5 :5 · ¸ · ¸ 1 For both Markov processes, c¹ = . Assume that γ = 2:5; ¯ = :95. Compute 5 · ¸ unconditional discounted expected utility V for each of these processes. Which of the two processes does the consumer prefer? Redo the calculations for γ = 4. Now which process does the consumer prefer? c. An econometrician observes a sample of 10 observations of consumption rates 10 1. TIME SERIES for our consumer. He knows that one of the two preceding Markov processes generates the data, but not which one. He assigns equal \prior probability" to the two chains. Suppose that the 10 successive observations on consumption are as follows: 1; 1; 1; 1; 1; 1; 1; 1; 1; 1. Compute the likehood of this sample under process 1 and under process 2. Denote the likelihood function Prob(data Model ); i = 1; 2. j i d. Suppose that the econometrician uses Bayes' law to revise his initial proba- bility estimates for the two models, where in this context Bayes' law states: Prob(data Model ) Prob(Model ) Prob(Model data) = j i ¢ i : ij Prob(data Model ) Prob(Model ) j j j ¢ j The denominator of this expressionP is the unconditional probability of the data. After observing the data sample, what probabilities does the econometrician place on the two possible models? e. Repeat the calculation in part d, but now assume that the data sample is 1; 5; 5; 1; 5; 5; 1; 5; 1; 5. Solution 1 t a. Given that vi = E [ t=0 ¯ u(ct) c0 = ci] ; we can apply the usual vector nota- tion (by stacking ): j P 1 v = E ¯tu(c ) c = c : t j 0 " t=0 # X To apply the forecasting function formula in the notes: 1 E ¯k (h(x ) x = x) = (I ¯P )¡1 h: t+k j t ¡ Xk=0 Let h(x) = u(c). Then it follows immediately that: 1 v = E ¯tu(c ) c = c = (I ¯P )¡1 u: t j 0 ¡ " t=0 # X Second, to compute V = Ev, simply note that in general the unconditional expec- n tation at time 0 of a foreasting function h is given by: E(h(x0)) = i=1 hi¼0;i = ¼0 h, or, in particular: 0 P n V = vi¼0;i: i=1 X 1 t Also, you should be able to verify that V = E [ t=0 ¯ u(ct)] by applying the law of iterated expectations. b. the matlab program exer0103.m computes Pthe solutions. Process1 and Process 2: V = 7:2630 for γ = 2:5 Process1 and Process 2: V = ¡3:36 for γ = 4 ¡ 1.
Recommended publications
  • Calculating the Value Function When the Bellman Equation Cannot Be
    Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 28 (2004) 1437–1460 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Investment under uncertainty: calculating the value function when the Bellman equation cannot besolvedanalytically Thomas Dangla, Franz Wirlb;∗ aVienna University of Technology, Theresianumgasse 27, A-1040 Vienna, Austria bUniversity of Vienna, Brunnerstr.˝ 72, A-1210 Vienna, Austria Abstract The treatment of real investments parallel to ÿnancial options if an investment is irreversible and facing uncertainty is a major insight of modern investment theory well expounded in the book Investment under Uncertainty by Dixit and Pindyck. Thepurposeof this paperis to draw attention to the fact that many problems in managerial decision making imply Bellman equations that cannot be solved analytically and to the di6culties that arise when approximating therequiredvaluefunction numerically.This is so becausethevaluefunctionis thesaddlepoint path from the entire family of solution curves satisfying the di7erential equation. The paper uses a simple machine replacement and maintenance framework to highlight these di6culties (for shooting as well as for ÿnite di7erence methods). On the constructive side, the paper suggests and tests a properly modiÿed projection algorithm extending the proposal in Judd (J. Econ. Theory 58 (1992) 410). This fast algorithm proves amendable to economic and stochastic control problems(which onecannot say of theÿnitedi7erencemethod). ? 2003 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classiÿcation: D81; C61; E22 Keywords: Stochastic optimal control; Investment under uncertainty; Projection method; Maintenance 1. Introduction Without doubt, thebook of Dixit and Pindyck (1994) is oneof themost stimulating books concerning management sciences. The basic message of this excellent book is the following: Considering investments characterized by uncertainty (either with ∗ Corresponding author.
    [Show full text]
  • From Single-Agent to Multi-Agent Reinforcement Learning: Foundational Concepts and Methods Learning Theory Course
    From Single-Agent to Multi-Agent Reinforcement Learning: Foundational Concepts and Methods Learning Theory Course Gon¸caloNeto Instituto de Sistemas e Rob´otica Instituto Superior T´ecnico May 2005 Abstract Interest in robotic and software agents has increased a lot in the last decades. They allow us to do tasks that we would hardly accomplish otherwise. Par- ticularly, multi-agent systems motivate distributed solutions that can be cheaper and more efficient than centralized single-agent ones. In this context, reinforcement learning provides a way for agents to com- pute optimal ways of performing the required tasks, with just a small in- struction indicating if the task was or was not accomplished. Learning in multi-agent systems, however, poses the problem of non- stationarity due to interactions with other agents. In fact, the RL methods for the single agent domain assume stationarity of the environment and cannot be applied directly. This work is divided in two main parts. In the first one, the reinforcement learning framework for single-agent domains is analyzed and some classical solutions presented, based on Markov decision processes. In the second part, the multi-agent domain is analyzed, borrowing tools from game theory, namely stochastic games, and the most significant work on learning optimal decisions for this type of systems is presented. ii Contents Abstract 1 1 Introduction 2 2 Single-Agent Framework 5 2.1 Markov Decision Processes . 6 2.2 Dynamic Programming . 10 2.2.1 Value Iteration . 11 2.2.2 Policy Iteration . 12 2.2.3 Generalized Policy Iteration . 13 2.3 Learning with Model-free methods .
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamic Programming for Dummies, Parts I & II
    DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING FOR DUMMIES Parts I & II Gonçalo L. Fonseca [email protected] Contents: Part I (1) Some Basic Intuition in Finite Horizons (a) Optimal Control vs. Dynamic Programming (b) The Finite Case: Value Functions and the Euler Equation (c) The Recursive Solution (i) Example No.1 - Consumption-Savings Decisions (ii) Example No.2 - Investment with Adjustment Costs (iii) Example No. 3 - Habit Formation (2) The Infinite Case: Bellman's Equation (a) Some Basic Intuition (b) Why does Bellman's Equation Exist? (c) Euler Once Again (d) Setting up the Bellman's: Some Examples (i) Labor Supply/Household Production model (ii) Investment with Adjustment Costs (3) Solving Bellman's Equation for Policy Functions (a) Guess and Verify Method: The Idea (i) Guessing the Policy Function u = h(x) (ii) Guessing the Value Function V(x). (b) Guess and Verify Method: Two Examples (i) One Example: Log Return and Cobb-Douglas Transition (ii) The Other Example: Quadratic Return and Linear Transition Part II (4) Stochastic Dynamic Programming (a) Some Basics (b) Some Examples: (i) Consumption with Uncertainty (ii) Asset Prices (iii) Search Models (5) Mathematical Appendices (a) Principle of Optimality (b) Existence of Bellman's Equation 2 Texts There are actually not many books on dynamic programming methods in economics. The following are standard references: Stokey, N.L. and Lucas, R.E. (1989) Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. (Harvard University Press) Sargent, T.J. (1987) Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory (Harvard University Press) Sargent, T.J. (1997) Recursive Macroeconomic Theory (unpublished, but on Sargent's website at http://riffle.stanford.edu) Stokey and Lucas does more the formal "mathy" part of it, with few worked-through applications.
    [Show full text]
  • The Uncertainty Bellman Equation and Exploration
    The Uncertainty Bellman Equation and Exploration Brendan O’Donoghue 1 Ian Osband 1 Remi Munos 1 Volodymyr Mnih 1 Abstract tions that maximize rewards given its current knowledge? We consider the exploration/exploitation prob- Separating estimation and control in RL via ‘greedy’ algo- lem in reinforcement learning. For exploitation, rithms can lead to premature and suboptimal exploitation. it is well known that the Bellman equation con- To offset this, the majority of practical implementations in- nects the value at any time-step to the expected troduce some random noise or dithering into their action value at subsequent time-steps. In this paper we selection (such as -greedy). These algorithms will even- consider a similar uncertainty Bellman equation tually explore every reachable state and action infinitely (UBE), which connects the uncertainty at any often, but can take exponentially long to learn the opti- time-step to the expected uncertainties at subse- mal policy (Kakade, 2003). By contrast, for any set of quent time-steps, thereby extending the potential prior beliefs the optimal exploration policy can be com- exploratory benefit of a policy beyond individual puted directly by dynamic programming in the Bayesian time-steps. We prove that the unique fixed point belief space. However, this approach can be computation- of the UBE yields an upper bound on the vari- ally intractable for even very small problems (Guez et al., ance of the posterior distribution of the Q-values 2012) while direct computational approximations can fail induced by any policy. This bound can be much spectacularly badly (Munos, 2014). tighter than traditional count-based bonuses that For this reason, most provably-efficient approaches to re- compound standard deviation rather than vari- inforcement learning rely upon the optimism in the face of ance.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomics: a Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach
    Macroeconomics: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach Mausumi Das Lecture Notes, DSE Jan 29-Feb 19, 2019 Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) DGE Approach Jan29-Feb19,2019 1/113 Modern Macroeconomics: the Dynamic General Equilibrium (DGE) Approach Modern macroeconomics is based on a dynamic general equilibrium approach which postulates that Economic agents are continuously optimizing/re-optimizing subject to their constraints and subject to their information set. They optimize not only over their current choice variables but also the choices that would be realized in future. All agents have rational expectations: thus their ex ante optimal future choices would ex post turn out to be less than optimal if and only if their information set is incomplete and/or there are some random elements in the economy which cannot be anticipated perfectly. The agents are atomistic is the sense that they treat the market factors as exogenous in their optimization exercise. The optimal choices of all agents are then mediated through the markets to produce an equilibrium outcome for the macroeconomy (which, by construction, is also consistent with the optimal choice of each agent). Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) DGE Approach Jan29-Feb19,2019 2/113 Modern Macroeconomics: DGE Approach (Contd.) This approach is ‘dynamic’because agents are making choices over variables that relate to both present and future. This approach is ‘equilibrium’because the outcome for the macro-economy is the aggregation of individuals’equilibrium (optimal) behaviour. This approach is ‘general equilibrium’because it simultaneously takes into account the optimal behaviour of diiferent types of agents in different markets and ensures that all markets clear.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 2010C: Lecture 1 Introduction to Dynamic Programming
    Economics 2010c: Lecture 1 Introduction to Dynamic Programming David Laibson 9/02/2014 Outline of my half-semester course: 1. Discrete time methods (Bellman Equation, Contraction Mapping Theorem, and Blackwell’s Sufficient Conditions, Numerical methods) Applications to growth, search, consumption, asset pricing • 2. Continuous time methods (Bellman Equation, Brownian Motion, Ito Process, and Ito’s Lemma) Applications to search, consumption, price-setting, investment, indus- • trial organization, asset-pricing Outline of today’s lecture: 1. Introduction to dynamic programming 2. The Bellman Equation 3. Three ways to solve the Bellman Equation 4. Application: Search and stopping problem 1 Introduction to dynamic programming. Course emphasizes methodological techniques and illustrates them through • applications. We start with discrete-time dynamic optimization. • Is optimization a ridiculous model of human behavior? Why or why not? • Today we’ll start with an -horizon stationary problem: • ∞ The Sequence Problem (cf. Stokey and Lucas) Notation: is the state vector at date (+1) is the flow payoff at date ( is ‘stationary’) is the exponential discount function is referred to as the exponential discount factor The discount rate is the rate of decline of the discount function, so ln = ≡− − h i Note that exp( )= and exp( )= − − Definition of Sequence Problem: Find () such that ∞ (0)= sup (+1) +1 =0 { }∞=0 X subject to +1 Γ() with 0 given. ∈ Remark 1.1 When I omit time subscripts, this implies that an equation holds for all relevant values of . In the statement above, +1 Γ() implies, ∈ +1 Γ() for all =0 1 2 ∈ Example 1.1 Optimal growth with log utility and Cobb-Douglas technology: ∞ sup ln() =0 { }∞=0 X subject to the constraints, 0+ +1 = and 0 given.
    [Show full text]
  • Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Investment
    Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Investment Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 1 Introduction These notes introduce and discuss modern theories of firm investment. While much of this is done as a decision rule problem of the firm, it is easily incorporated into a general equilibrium structure. 2 Tobin's Q Jim Tobin (1969) developed an intuitive and celebrated theory of investment. He reasoned that if the market value of physical capital of a firm exceeded its replacement cost, then capital has more value \in the firm” (the numerator) than outside the firm (the denominator). Formally, Tobin's Q is defined as: Market Value of Firm Capital Q = (1) Replacement Cost of Capital Tobin reasoned that firms should accumulate more capital when Q > 1 and should draw down their capital stock when Q < 1. That is, net investment in physical capital should depend on where Q is in relation to one. How would one measure Q in the data? Typically this is done by using the value of the stock market in the numerator and data on corporate net worth in the denominator { here net worth is defined as the replacement cost of capital goods. For example, suppose that a company is in the business of bulldozing. It owns a bunch of bulldozers. Suppose that it owns 100 bulldozers, which cost 100 each to replace. This means its replacement cost is 10; 000. Suppose it has 1000 outstanding shares of stock, valued at 15 per share. The market value of the firm is thus 15; 000 and the replacement cost is 10; 000, so Tobin's Q is 1.5.
    [Show full text]
  • Regional Inflation, Banking Integration, and Dollarization*
    Review of Finance, 2018, 2073–2108 doi: 10.1093/rof/rfx021 Advance Access Publication Date: 10 May 2017 Regional Inflation, Banking Integration, and Dollarization* Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rof/article-abstract/22/6/2073/3813131 by guest on 29 October 2018 Martin Brown1, Ralph De Haas2, and Vladimir Sokolov3 1University of St. Gallen, 2European Bank for Reconstruction and Development and Tilburg University, and 3ICEF, National Research University Higher School of Economics Abstract We exploit variation in consumer price inflation across seventy-one Russian regions to examine the relationship between the perceived stability of the domestic currency and financial dollarization. Our results show that regions with higher inflation expe- rience an increase in the dollarization of household deposits and a decrease in the dollarization of loans. The impact of inflation on credit dollarization is weaker in regions with less integrated banking markets. This suggests that the currency- portfolio choices of households and firms are constrained by the asset-liability man- agement of banks. JEL classification: E31, E44, F36, G21, P22, P24 Keywords: Financial dollarization, Banking integration, Regional inflation Received March 10, 2016; accepted March 31, 2017 by Editor Franklin Allen. 1. Introduction Financial dollarization—the widespread holding of assets and liabilities in a foreign cur- rency—is viewed as both a constraint on monetary policy (Ongena, Schindele, and Vonnak, 2015) and a threat to financial stability in many emerging markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3 the Representative Agent Model
    Chapter 3 The representative agent model 3.1 Optimal growth In this course we’re looking at three types of model: 1. Descriptive growth model (Solow model): mechanical, shows the im- plications of a given fixed savings rate. 2. Optimal growth model (Ramsey model): pick the savings rate that maximizes some social planner’s problem. 3. Equilibrium growth model: specify complete economic environment, find equilibrium prices and quantities. Two basic demographies - rep- resentative agent (RA) and overlapping generations (OLG). 3.1.1 The optimal growth model in discrete time Time and demography Time is discrete. One representative consumer with infinite lifetime. Social planner directly allocates resources to maximize consumer’s lifetime expected utility. 1 2 CHAPTER 3. THE REPRESENTATIVE AGENT MODEL Consumer The consumer has (expected) utility function: ∞ X t U = E0 β u(ct) (3.1) t=0 where β ∈ (0, 1) and the flow utility or one-period utility function is strictly increasing (u0(c) > 0) and strictly concave (u00(c) < 0). In addition we will impose an Inada-like condition: lim u0(c) = ∞ (3.2) c→0 The social planner picks a nonnegative sequence (or more generally a stochas- tic process) for ct that maximizes expected utility subject to a set of con- straints. The technological constraints are identical to those in the Solow model. Specifically, the economy starts out with k0 units of capital at time zero. Output is produced using labor and capital with the standard neoclassical production function. Labor and technology are assumed to be constant, and are normalized to one. yt = F (kt,Lt) = F (kt, 1) (3.3) Technology and labor force growth can be accommodated in this model by applying the previous trick of restating everything in terms of “effective la- bor.” Output can be freely converted to consumption ct, or capital investment xt, as needed: ct + xt ≤ yt (3.4) Capital accumulation is as in the Solow model: kt+1 = (1 − δ)kt + xt (3.5) Finally, the capital stock cannot fall below zero.
    [Show full text]
  • Bankruptcy Costs, Liability Dollarization, and Vulnerability to Sudden Stops Uluc Aysun University of Connecticut
    University of Connecticut OpenCommons@UConn Economics Working Papers Department of Economics October 2008 Bankruptcy Costs, Liability Dollarization, and Vulnerability to Sudden Stops Uluc Aysun University of Connecticut Adam Honig Amherst College Follow this and additional works at: https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers Recommended Citation Aysun, Uluc and Honig, Adam, "Bankruptcy Costs, Liability Dollarization, and Vulnerability to Sudden Stops" (2008). Economics Working Papers. 200841. https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers/200841 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Bankruptcy Costs, Liability Dollarization, and Vulnerability to Sudden Stops Uluc Aysun University of Connecticut Adam Honig Amherst College Working Paper 2008-41 October 2008 341 Mansfield Road, Unit 1063 Storrs, CT 06269–1063 Phone: (860) 486–3022 Fax: (860) 486–4463 http://www.econ.uconn.edu/ This working paper is indexed on RePEc, http://repec.org/ Abstract Emerging market countries that have improved institutions and attained inter- mediate levels of institutional quality have experienced severe financial crises fol- lowing capital flow reversals. However, there is also evidence that countries with strong institutions and deep capital markets are less affected by external shocks. We reconcile these two observations using a calibrated DSGE model that extends the financial accelerator framework developed in Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999). The model captures financial market institutional quality with creditors. ability to recover assets from bankrupt firms. Bankruptcy costs affect vulnerabil- ity to sudden stops directly but also indirectly by affecting the degree of liabil- ity dollarization. Simulations reveal an inverted U-shaped relationship between bankruptcy recovery rates and the output loss following sudden stops. We provide empirical evidence that this non-linear relationship exists.
    [Show full text]
  • Q-Function Learning Methods
    Q-Function Learning Methods February 15, 2017 Value Functions I Definitions (review): π 2 Q (s; a) = Eπ r0 + γr1 + γ r2 + ::: j s0 = s; a0 = a Called Q-function or state-action-value function π 2 V (s) = Eπ r0 + γr1 + γ r2 + ::: j s0 = s π = Ea∼π [Q (s; a)] Called state-value function Aπ(s; a) = Qπ(s; a) − V π(s) Called advantage function Bellman Equations for Qπ π I Bellman equation for Q π π Q (s0; a0) = Es1∼P(s1 j s0;a0) [r0 + γV (s1)] π = Es1∼P(s1 j s0;a0) [r0 + γEa1∼π [Q (s1; a1)]] π I We can write out Q with k-step empirical returns π π Q (s0; a0) = Es1;a1 j s0;a0 [r0 + γV (s1; a1)] 2 π = Es1;a1;s2;a2 j s0;a0 r0 + γr1 + γ Q (s2; a2) h k−1 k π i = Es1;a1:::;sk ;ak j s0;a0 r0 + γr1 + ··· + γ rk−1 + γ Q (sk ; ak ) Bellman Backups I From previous slide: π π Q (s0; a0) = Es1∼P(s1 j s0;a0) [r0 + γEa1∼π [Q (s1; a1)]] I Define the Bellman backup operator (operating on Q-functions) as follows π [T Q](s0; a0) = Es1∼P(s1 j s0;a0) [r0 + γEa1∼π [Q(s1; a1)]] π I Then Q is a fixed point of this operator T πQπ = Qπ π I Furthermore, if we apply T repeatedly to any initial Q, the series converges to Qπ Q; T πQ; (T π)2Q; (T π)3Q; ···! Qπ Introducing Q∗ ∗ I Let π denote an optimal policy ∗ π∗ ∗ π I Define Q = Q , which satisfies Q (s; a) = maxπ Q (s; a) ∗ ∗ ∗ I π satisfies π (s) = arg maxa Q (s; a) I Thus, Bellman equation π π Q (s0; a0) = Es1∼P(s1 j s0;a0) [r0 + γEa1∼π [Q (s1; a1)]] becomes ∗ ∗ Q (s0; a0) = Es1∼P(s1 j s0;a0) r0 + γ max Q (s1; a1) a1 I Another definition ∗ ∗ Q (s0; a0) = Es1 [r + γV (s1)] Bellman Operator for Q∗ I Define a corresponding
    [Show full text]
  • Dollarization and Money Demand Stability in Bolivia
    Economics and Business Letters 4(3), 116-122, 2015 Dollarization and money demand stability in Bolivia Casto Martin Montero Kuscevic* • Darius Daniel Martin Department of Economics, American University of Beirut, Lebanon Received: 13 July 2015 Revised: 28 October 2015 Accepted: 10 November 2015 Abstract This paper investigates the long-run money demand stability in Bolivia over the period 1990- 2014 using a variety of estimators, namely, dynamic OLS, fully modified OLS, and canonical co-integrating regressions. Our results are robust and reveal that long-run money demand in- stability has been reversed even with persistent inflation volatility. We also show that de-dol- larization is associated with money demand stabilization. Keywords: money demand, financial dollarization, Bolivia JEL Classification Codes: E41, E52 1. Introduction From a theoretical standpoint, the seminal papers of Miles (1978) and McKinnon (1982) show that the currency substitution—i.e. dollarization—can create instabilities in money demand. Some researchers have empirically examined money demand in a dollarized economy. For ex- ample, Rogers (1992) and Ortiz (1983) using data for Mexico found that the high dollarization in the Mexican economy has important consequences for the monetary sector. Money demand instability could become persistent if dollarization becomes irreversible. On top of that, some authors argue that dollarization could be permanent1 even with low inflation due to the cost of switching currencies. In this paper, we analyze the stability of money demand in Bolivia over the period 1990- 2014. The Bolivian case is interesting for several reasons. First, hyperinflation in the Bolivian economy (1984-1985) had prolonged effects on the expectations of economic agents, which in turned got reflected in their preference for foreign currency i.e.
    [Show full text]