Declining Job Quality in the United States: Explanations and Evidence David R

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Declining Job Quality in the United States: Explanations and Evidence David R Declining Job Quality in the United States: Explanations and Evidence davId r. Howell and a rne l. Kalleberg The declining quality of jobs has emerged as a sharply rising overall wage inequality, and a key challenge for researchers and policymakers high and rising incidence of low pay. In con- in the twenty-first century. The growing realiza- trast to the egalitarian tendency during the first tion that the quality of jobs is central to ad- three postwar decades, post-1979 incomes have dressing a myriad of social and economic prob- either worsened or stagnated across most of the lems—such as economic development, family wage distribution, generating a growing polar- formation and social integration, poverty and ization between top 10 percent incomes and inequality, and individual well- being—has put the bottom 90 percent, and even more dramat- this age- old topic on the front burner for social ically, between the top 1 percent and the bot- scientists in the United States and around the tom 50 percent (Piketty, Saez, and Zucman world. This essay offers our perspective on the 2018; Acemoglu and Autor 2011; see also Sul- job quality problem and debate. We document livan, Warren, and Westbrook 2001; Atkinson changes in American job quality since the late and Brandolini 2011). Market incomes (before 1970s, survey leading explanations, and review taxes and benefits) for the average working- age the recent evidence. American adult actually fell between 1980 and After briefly reviewing the meaning of job 2014, reversing the strong upward trend of pre- quality, we describe American job quality, fo- vious decades. The incidence of low- wage and cusing on three dimensions of the post- 1979 very low- wage jobs (which we term poverty- low- wage crisis: stagnation or decline in real wage) grew, spectacularly so for young workers (inflation-adjusted) income and wage levels, (age eighteen through thirty- four) with less David R. Howell is professor of economics and public policy at the Milano School of Policy, Management, and Environment, the New School. Arne L. Kalleberg is Kenan Distinguished Professor of Sociology at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. © 2019 Russell Sage Foundation. Howell, David R., and Arne L. Kalleberg. 2019. “Declining Job Quality in the United States: Explanations and Evidence.” RSF: The Russell Sage Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences 5(4): 1–53. DOI: 10.7758/RSF.2019.5.4.01. We thank the participants of the conference on Changing Job Quality held at the Russell Sage Foundation in June 2018 for their helpful input on this paper as well as the valuable feedback we received from three external reviewers. We especially appreciate the comments on earlier drafts that we received from Eileen Appelbaum, Alison Campion, Peter Cappelli, Maury Gittleman, Sabrina Howell, Jennifer Hunt, Lane Kenworthy, Jeffrey Madrick, and John Schmitt. Howell thanks the Washington Center for Equitable Growth for the support that helped make possible some of the empirical results that appear in the paper. Direct correspondence to: David R. Howell at [email protected], 72 5th Ave., #702, New York, NY 10011; and Arne L. Kalleberg at [email protected], CB #3210 Hamilton Hall, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, NC 27599. Open Access Policy: RSF: The Russell Sage Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences is an open access journal. This article is published under a Creative Commons Attribution- NonCommercial- NoDerivs 3.0 Unported Li- cense. 2 cHangIng job qual Ity than a college degree. The poverty-wage share employer demands for them as computeriza- even increased for workers with a college de- tion (and perhaps offshoring) transform the gree. Young workers also experienced sizable workplace, eliminating the need for humans to declines in their median wage (males after 1979, do routine tasks. women after around 2000). In contested market models, wage- setting Declines in nonwage benefits such as takes place in firms that operate in imperfect employer- paid health insurance and pensions markets, and under these conditions employ- have also been greater for lower- wage workers, ers typically have substantial bargaining (mon- another source of rising absolute and relative opsony) power and make use of strategic wage inequality in job quality. The expansion of low- policies to elicit optimal effort, leading to the wage jobs has often been linked to concerns existence of good and bad jobs for similarly about the growth of nonstandard jobs—for ex- skilled workers (for example, respectively, Man- ample, temporary help agency workers, on- call ning 2011; Lazear and Shaw 2007). This is a neo- workers, contract workers, and (especially) in- classical view in which market failures are seen dependent contractors or freelancers—and as essential features of product and labor mar- though the question of the extent of the in- kets, and as a result, corrective institutions can crease in the share of nonstandard jobs re- improve efficiency and well-being. The low- mains controversial, evidence (and perception) wage problem reflects rising monopsony power is considerable that many dimensions of job and, reflecting this power, the growing use of quality have worsened for both standard and human resource practices that push wages be- nonstandard workers. In short, as measured by low competitive market levels. these and other indicators of job quality, the last Social- institutional approaches share the four decades have been characterized by un- contested market vision of the centrality of bar- shared—even extractive—economic growth.1 gaining power within the firm, but broaden the We consider leading explanations for these relevant terrain by underscoring the impor- striking changes in job quality and labor mar- tance of social, political, and structural forces; ket inequality by grouping them into three per- the effectiveness of protective labor institu- spectives concerning how labor markets work. tions; and workplace culture and conflict (for At one end of the theoretical spectrum is the example, Kaufman 1988, 2004; Osterman 2011). mainstream economist’s competitive market This is a political economy vision in which the model, which explains the wage distribution power wielded by different key stakeholders strictly in terms of the interaction of the supply generates the institutional configuration and and demand for worker skills in highly com- organizational diversity that in turn helps de- petitive external labor markets (for example, termine key outcomes, including not just wages Goldin and Katz 2007; Acemoglu and Autor and nonwage job quality but also the nature 2011, 2012; Autor and Dorn 2013). In this view, and use of available production technologies. protective labor institutions, like labor unions, The low- wage problem is rooted in deregula- are inefficient interventions, but skill-biased tion and technological advances that have in- production technologies are reducing their im- creased employer power, manifested in firm portance, making the perfect competition restructuring and adversarial labor practices model an increasingly good approximation for aimed at cutting labor costs as the countervail- how labor markets work. The result is the law ing power of labor institutions collapsed. In of one wage, in which workers in the same skill this view, the decline in post- 1979 job quality group are paid the same wage in similar jobs can be explained by a declining willingness to no matter where they work. The low-wage prob- pay decent wages by lead firms with consider- lem is explained by the failure of worker skills able market power and a declining ability to pay (college degrees) to keep pace with increases in decent wages by their suppliers and other firms 1. By extractive growth, we mean unshared growth in which increasing inequality is characterized not just by a growing gap between top and bottom parts of the wage-income distribution, but by absolute declines in inflation- adjusted wages or incomes at the bottom. rsf: the russell sage foundation journal of the social sciences declInIng job qual Ity In t He un Ited states 3 confronted with increasingly competitive prod- countries that face similar technological ad- uct markets (Appelbaum 2017). vances and globalization pressures. These three perspectives assign different Researchers who see the labor market roles for markets, institutions, and conflict. In through the lenses of the two bargaining power contested market and social- institutional ap- approaches have focused on evidence of rising proaches, large shifts in labor demand and sup- monopsony power, increases in employment ply can be important sources of wage and other restructuring to reduce labor costs through out- job quality outcomes. For example, a surplus sourcing nonessential tasks formerly done in pool of workers vying for jobs can be expected house, and the eroding power of countervailing to undermine their bargaining power, as Adam labor institutions (such as laws governing the Smith argued centuries ago (discussed further labor process, collective bargaining protec- later). But the same is not the case for the role tions, and minimum wage legislation). In ad- of protective institutions (formal and informal) dition, social- institutional scholarship has in the textbook competitive market explana- pointed to the effects of changes in national tion. Here the wage is set in the external labor and local public policies that affect human re- market by supply and demand, and wage in- source practices
Recommended publications
  • A RIGHT-TO-WORK MODEL, the UNIONIZATION of FAIRFAX COUNTY GOVERNMENT WORKERS By
    A RIGHT-TO-WORK MODEL, THE UNIONIZATION OF FAIRFAX COUNTY GOVERNMENT WORKERS by Ann M. Johnson A Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of George Mason University in Partial Fulfillment of The Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy Sociology Committee: ___________________________________________ Director ___________________________________________ ___________________________________________ ___________________________________________ Department Chairperson ___________________________________________ Program Director ___________________________________________ Dean, College of Humanities and Social Sciences Date: _____________________________________ Spring Semester 2017 George Mason University Fairfax, VA A Right-to-Work Model, the Unionization of Fairfax County Government Workers A Dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at George Mason University by Ann M. Johnson Master of Arts University of North Carolina at Charlotte, 1995 Bachelor of Arts Hamilton College, 1986 Director: Dae Young Kim, Professor Department of Sociology Spring Semester 2017 George Mason University Fairfax, VA COPYRIGHT 2017 ANN M. JOHNSON ALL RIGHTS RESERVED ii Dedication This is dedicated to the memory of my beloved parents, Wilfred and Ailein Faulkner, and sister, Dawn “Alex” Arkell. iii Acknowledgements I would like to thank the staff and members of the Fairfax County Government Employee Union who generously gave of their time and expertise: Kevin Jones, Jessica Brown, LaNoral
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding the Historic Divergence Between Productivity
    Understanding the Historic Divergence Between Productivity and a Typical Worker’s Pay: Why It Matters and Why It’s Real By Josh Bivens and Lawrence Mishel | September 2, 2015 Introduction and key findings Wage stagnation experienced by the vast majority of American workers has emerged as a central issue in economic policy debates, with candidates and leaders of both parties noting its importance. This is a welcome development because it means that economic inequality has become a focus of attention and that policymakers are seeing the connection between wage stagnation and inequality. Put simply, wage stagnation is how the rise in inequality has damaged the vast majority of American workers. The Economic Policy Institute’s earlier paper, Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge, presented a thorough analysis of income and wage trends, documented rising wage inequality, and provided strong evidence that wage stagnation is largely the result of policy choices that boosted the bargaining power of those with the most wealth and power (Bivens et al. 2014). As we argued, better policy choices, made with low- and moderate-wage earners in mind, can lead to more widespread wage growth and strengthen and expand the middle class. This paper updates and explains the implications of the central component of the wage stagnation story: the growing gap between overall productivity growth and the pay of the vast majority of workers since the 1970s. A careful analysis of this gap between pay and productivity provides several important insights for the ongoing debate about how to address wage stagnation and rising inequality.
    [Show full text]
  • SOCIOLOGY 9191A Social Science in the Marxian Tradition Fall 2020
    SOCIOLOGY 9191A Social Science in the Marxian Tradition Fall 2020 DRAFT Class times and location Wednesday 10:30am -12:30pm Virtual synchronous Instructor: David Calnitsky Office Hours by appointment Department of Sociology Office: SSC 5402 Email: [email protected] Technical Requirements: Stable internet connection Laptop or computer Working microphone Working webcam “The philosophers have only interpreted the world, in various ways. The point, however, is to change it.” – Karl Marx That is the point, it’s true—but not in this course. This quote, indirectly, hints at a deep tension in Marxism. If we want to change the world we need to understand it. But the desire to change something can infect our understanding of it. This is a pervasive dynamic in the history of Marxism and the first step is to admit there is a problem. This means acknowledging the presence of wishful thinking, without letting it induce paralysis. On the other hand, if there are pitfalls in being upfront in your desire to change the world there are also virtues. The normative 1 goal of social change helps to avoid common trappings of academia, in particular, the laser focus on irrelevant questions. Plus, in having a set of value commitments, stated clearly, you avoid the false pretense that values don’t enter in the backdoor in social science, which they often do if you’re paying attention. With this caveat in place, Marxian social science really does have a lot to offer in understanding the world and that’s what we’ll analyze in this course. The goal is to look at the different hypotheses that broadly emerge out of the Marxian tradition and see the extent to which they can be supported both theoretically and empirically.
    [Show full text]
  • Raise the Minimum Wage He Minimum Wage Has Been an Important Part of Our Tnation’S Economy for 68 Years
    Hundreds of Economists Say: Raise the Minimum Wage he minimum wage has been an important part of our Tnation’s economy for 68 years. It is based on the principle Hard work of valuing work by establishing an hourly wage floor beneath which employers cannot pay their workers. In so doing, the minimum wage helps to equalize the imbalance in bargaining deserves power that low-wage workers face in the labor market. The minimum wage is also an important tool in fighting poverty. fair pay The value of the 1997 increase in the federal minimum wage has been fully eroded. The real value of today’s federal minimum wage is less than it has been since 1951. Moreover, the ratio of the minimum wage to the average hourly wage of non-supervisory workers is 31%, its lowest level since World War II. This decline is causing hardship for low-wage workers and their families. We believe that a modest increase in the minimum wage would improve the well-being of low-wage workers and would not have the adverse effects that critics have claimed. In particular, we share the view the Council of Economic Advisors expressed in the 1999 Economic Report of the President that "the weight of the evidence suggests that modest increases in the minimum wage have had very little or no effect on employment." While controversy about the precise employment effects of the minimum wage continues, research has shown that most of the beneficiaries are adults, most are female, and the vast majority are members of low-income working families.
    [Show full text]
  • The Politics of Helping the Poor
    The Politics of Helping the Poor Lane Kenworthy* June 15, 2010 What is most effective at increasing the absolute incomes of the poor in the world's affluent countries: economic growth or redistribution? Growth clearly matters. The standard of living of low-end households in rich nations is substantially higher than a century ago, and much of that improvement is due to economic growth. Indeed, over the long run the material circumstances of the poor necessarily depend more on economic growth than on redistribution. If the pie does not increase in size, a country could redistribute until everyone has an equal slice but then no further improvements would be possible. In the short- and medium-term, redistribution can help a great deal. Even in the United States, with its comparatively stingy welfare state, government trans- fers account for nearly half of the income of households in the bottom decile of the distribution. Public provision and subsidization of services — health care, education, child care, housing, transportation, retraining, job placement, and oth- ers — also helps. Services boost living standards directly, and they allow the poor to spend scarce income on other things that contribute to material well- being. In countries where low-end incomes have increased significantly in recent decades, is that due mainly to growth, to redistribution, or to both in equal meas- ure? Surprisingly, social scientists have made virtually no attempt to answer this question. Researchers studying the impact of growth and redistribution in rich countries have focused their attention almost exclusively on a distributional no- tion of poverty — relative poverty — rather than on absolute incomes.
    [Show full text]
  • Welfare States, Real Incomes, and Poverty
    Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 370 Welfare States, Real Incomes, and Poverty Lane Kenworthy February 04 Luxembourg Income Study (LIS), asbl Welfare States, Real Incomes, and Poverty Lane Kenworthy Department of Sociology Emory University Atlanta, GA 30322 Tel: 404-727-7538 E-mail: [email protected] Homepage: www.emory.edu/SOC/lkenworthy February 15, 2004 Forthcoming in Socio-Economic Review, 2004. This paper is a revised version of Lane Kenworthy, "An Equality-Incomes Tradeoff?" chapter 6 in Egalitar- ian Capitalism? Jobs, Incomes, and Equality in Affluent Countries. 2004 Russell Sage Foundation. Welfare States, Real Incomes, and Poverty Welfare state supporters typically contend that social-welfare programs boost the in- comes of low-earning households. Critics argue that, over time, such programs re- duce the growth of economic output and/or employment. As a result, redistribution may produce stagnant or even declining real incomes for those at the bottom. A number of recent cross-country empirical studies have found that welfare state gen- erosity is strongly associated with low relative poverty, but there has been virtually no cross-national analysis of welfare state effects on absolute poverty, which is at the heart of the critics' argument. I use Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) data to exam- ine the relationship between welfare state generosity and absolute poverty for work- ing-age households in Sweden, Germany, the United Kingdom, Canada, and the United States from the mid-1970s to 2000. Consistent with the critics' charge, the countries with the most generous welfare states experienced rising pretax-pretransfer absolute poverty. Yet the actual causal significance of welfare state generosity in this development is questionable.
    [Show full text]
  • The Zombie Robot Argument Lurches on There Is No Evidence That Automation Leads to Joblessness Or Inequality
    The zombie robot argument lurches on There is no evidence that automation leads to joblessness or inequality Report • By Lawrence Mishel and Josh Bivens • May 24, 2017 • Washington, DC View this report at epi.org/126750 SECTIONS The media are full of stories about robots and automation destroying the jobs of the past and leaving us jobless in 1. The new narrative on the future; call it the coming Robot Apocalypse. We are robots • 4 also told that automation and technology are responsible 2. The estimated impact for the poor wage growth and inequality bedeviling the of robots is small, and American working class in recent decades, and that automation broadly looming automation will only accelerate and ratchet up defined does not these problems. Recent research by economists Daron explain recent labor Acemoglu of MIT and Pascual Restrepo of Boston market trends • 5 University is but the latest fuel for the automation media narrative (Acemoglu and Restrepo 2017a). 3. A&R’s claim that robots reduced What is remarkable about this media narrative is that there overall, national-level is a strong desire to believe it despite so little evidence to employment is support these claims. There clearly are serious problems in unconvincing because the labor market that have suppressed job and wage it relies on unrealistic growth for far too long; but these problems have their roots assumptions • 12 in intentional policy decisions regarding globalization, 4. Maybe there has not collective bargaining, labor standards, and unemployment been a robot levels, not technology. apocalypse yet; but This report highlights the paucity of the evidence behind what about the alleged robot apocalypse, particularly as joblessness and mischaracterized in the media coverage of the 2017 inequality in the Acemoglu and Restrepo (A&R) report.
    [Show full text]
  • Empowerment in the Workplace Hearing Joint Economic Committee Congress of the United States
    S. HRG. 113–336 EMPOWERMENT IN THE WORKPLACE HEARING BEFORE THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES ONE HUNDRED THIRTEENTH CONGRESS SECOND SESSION JUNE 18, 2014 Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee ( U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 88–592 WASHINGTON : 2014 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512–1800; DC area (202) 512–1800 Fax: (202) 512–2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402–0001 JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE [Created pursuant to Sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Congress] HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES SENATE KEVIN BRADY, Texas, Chairman AMY KLOBUCHAR, Minnesota, Vice Chair JOHN CAMPBELL, California ROBERT P. CASEY, JR., Pennsylvania SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont JUSTIN AMASH, Michigan CHRISTOPHER MURPHY, Connecticut ERIK PAULSEN, Minnesota MARTIN HEINRICH, New Mexico RICHARD L. HANNA, New York MARK L. PRYOR, Arkansas CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York DAN COATS, Indiana LORETTA SANCHEZ, California MIKE LEE, Utah ELIJAH E. CUMMINGS, Maryland ROGER F. WICKER, Mississippi JOHN DELANEY, Maryland PAT TOOMEY, Pennsylvania ROBERT P. O’QUINN, Executive Director NILES GODES, Democratic Staff Director (II) C O N T E N T S OPENING STATEMENTS OF MEMBERS Hon. Kevin Brady, Chairman, a U.S. Representative from Texas ...................... 1 Hon. John Delaney, a U.S. Representative from Maryland ................................. 3 Hon. Carolyn B. Maloney, a U.S. Representative from New York ...................... 5 WITNESSES Ms. Diana Furchtgott-Roth, Senior Fellow and Director, Economics, Manhat- tan Institute for Policy Research, Washington, DC .......................................... 8 Dr. Barbara Gault, Vice President and Executive Director, Institute for Wom- en’s Policy Research, Washington, DC ..............................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Corporatism and Unemployment in the 1980S and 1990S Author(S): Lane Kenworthy Source: American Sociological Review, Vol
    Corporatism and Unemployment in the 1980s and 1990s Author(s): Lane Kenworthy Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 67, No. 3 (Jun., 2002), pp. 367-388 Published by: American Sociological Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3088962 Accessed: 16-11-2015 12:19 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Sage Publications, Inc. and American Sociological Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Sociological Review. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 192.124.250.5 on Mon, 16 Nov 2015 12:19:08 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CORPORATISM AND UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE 1980S AND 1990S LANE KENWORTHY Emory University A number of studies have found an association between corporatist institutions and low unemployment in the 1970s and/or 1980s. Three gaps in our understanding of corporatism's labor market effects are addressed here: (1) Which of the two princi- pal forms of corporatism-corporatist wage-setting or union participation in eco- nomic policymaking, or both-generates these effects? (2) What are the causal mechanisms? (3) Did these effects continue in the 1990s in the face of globalization, restrictive monetary policy, growing dissension within labor movements, and related developments? The impact of corporatism across 16 affluent OECD countries in the 1980s and 1990s is assessed using pooled time-series cross-section analysis.
    [Show full text]
  • Inequality and Decision Making: Imagining a New Line of Inquiry
    Inequality and Decision Making: Imagining a New Line of Inquiry David Moss Anant Thaker Howard Rudnick Working Paper 13-099 June 14, 2013 Copyright © 2013 by David Moss, Anant Thaker, Howard Rudnick Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author. Inequality and Decision Making: Imagining a New Line of Inquiry David Moss Anant Thaker Howard Rudnick* December 2011 Revised June 2013 Abstract The substantial increase in inequality in the United States over the past three decades has provoked considerable debate, with some analysts characterizing rising inequality as among the greatest threats facing the nation and others dismissing it as little more than a hiccup – or even celebrating it as a favorable development – in the progress of American capitalism. Despite numerous claims in popular venues that high inequality has slowed growth, precipitated financial instability, and profoundly distorted the nation’s political system, our review of the literature finds no academic consensus on the consequences of inequality for the health of the economy or the democracy, or for nearly any other macro-level outcome. With the academic community reaching inconclusive and conflicting findings, we suggest that careful empirical study of possible mechanisms by which income inequality may exert macro-level effects is warranted. We suggest further that that one potential mechanism that may be especially worthy of investigation relates to possible effects of high or rising inequality on individual decision making. Drawing on nascent research, we examine a handful of pathways through which inequality may plausibly influence individual decisions.
    [Show full text]
  • Labor Standards and Institutions to Promote Wage Growth
    POLICY PROPOSAL 2018-07 | FEBRUARY 2018 Strengthening Labor Standards and Institutions to Promote Wage Growth Heidi Shierholz MISSION STATEMENT The Hamilton Project seeks to advance America’s promise of opportunity, prosperity, and growth. We believe that today’s increasingly competitive global economy demands public policy ideas commensurate with the challenges of the 21st Century. The Project’s economic strategy reflects a judgment that long-term prosperity is best achieved by fostering economic growth and broad participation in that growth, by enhancing individual economic security, and by embracing a role for effective government in making needed public investments. Our strategy calls for combining public investment, a secure social safety net, and fiscal discipline. In that framework, the Project puts forward innovative proposals from leading economic thinkers — based on credible evidence and experience, not ideology or doctrine — to introduce new and effective policy options into the national debate. The Project is named after Alexander Hamilton, the nation’s first Treasury Secretary, who laid the foundation for the modern American economy. Hamilton stood for sound fiscal policy, believed that broad-based opportunity for advancement would drive American economic growth, and recognized that “prudent aids and encouragements on the part of government” are necessary to enhance and guide market forces. The guiding principles of the Project remain consistent with these views. Strengthening Labor Standards and Institutions to Promote Wage Growth Heidi Shierholz Economic Policy Institute FEBRUARY 2018 This policy proposal is a proposal from the author(s). As emphasized in The Hamilton Project’s original strategy paper, the Project was designed in part to provide a forum for leading thinkers across the nation to put forward innovative and potentially important economic policy ideas that share the Project’s broad goals of promoting economic growth, broad-based participation in growth, and economic security.
    [Show full text]
  • American University Working Paper Series 1 WAGE STAGNATION, RISING INEQUALITY and the FINANCIAL CRISIS of 2008
    American University Working Paper Series 1 WAGE STAGNATION, RISING INEQUALITY AND THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2008 Jon D. Wisman* ABSTRACT: The most widely embraced explanations of the financial crisis of 2008 have centered upon inadequate regulation stemming from laissez-faire ideology, combined with low interest rates. Although these widely-acknowledged causal factors are true, beneath them lie deeper determining forces that have received less notice: wage stagnation and a dramatic increase in inequality in the U.S. over the preceding 35 years. Wage stagnation and heightened inequality generated three dynamics that made the economy vulnerable to systemic dysfunction. The first is that they constrained consumption, reducing profitable investment potential in the real economy, and thereby encouraging an every wealthier elite to flood financial markets with credit, helping keep interest rates low, encouraging the creation of new credit instruments and greater indebtedness, and fueling speculation. The second dynamic is that consumption externalities were generated, forcing individuals to struggle harder to find ways to maintain the welfare of their families and maintain their relative social status. The consequence was that over the preceding three decades household saving rates plummeted, households took on ever- greater debt, and worked longer hours. The third dynamic is that, as the rich took larger shares of income and wealth, they gained more command over ideology and hence politics. Reducing the size of government, cutting taxes on the
    [Show full text]