Interest Rates and Their Prospect in the Recovery

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Interest Rates and Their Prospect in the Recovery JAMES L. PIERCE Staff, Board of Governorsof the Federal Reserve System Interest Rates and Their Prospect in the Recovery MUCH CONCERN has been expressedin the financialpress and by otherob- serversabout the prospectsfor interestrates in 1975.The particularfear is that the sharpdeclines in short-terminterest rates in 1974will be followed by sharpincreases in both short- and long-termrates in 1975 under the pressureof the massivefederal deficits expected in 1975 and 1976. This paperaddresses two questions:First, has the movementin short- andlong-term interest rates since mid-1974 been unusualin light of the slow growthof money and the collapsein economicactivity? Second, will the large volumeof deficitfinancing, induced in part by the tax cuts, lend a strongupward push on interestrates in 1975?These can be two aspectsof the samequestion, because an unexpectedand fundamentalshift in the re- lationshipsamong interest rates, income, and moneymay cloud the impli- cationsof the deficitfor interestrates. The RecentBehavior of InterestRates andMoney Demand As figure1 demonstrates,short-term rates peaked in the summerof 1974, andhave since fallen steeply until quite recently. Long-term rates have also Note: The views expressedin this paper are my own and do not necessarilyagree withthose of the Board of Governors.I want to thank membersof the Brookings panel for their many constructivecomments on an earlierversion of this paper. 89 90 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1975 Figure 1. Selected Interest Rates, Monthly Averages, January 1974-March 1975 Percent 12 90-119-day commercial paper 10 Aaa utility bondsa % /~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 7 ' 3-month Treasury billsb 6 J F M A M J J A S 0 N D J F M 1974 1975 Sources: Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 61 (April 1975), pp. A 27, A 28; and two preceding issues. a. Recently offered series. b. Market yield. fallen from their peaks, but much more gradually; since November they have moved without a clear trend. These moveiiients were accompanied by an appreciable slowing in the growth of nominal income during 1974, which, however, remained positive until the first quarter of 1975. Real in- come fell throughout 1974, moving into a severe decline in the last quarter of 1974 and the first quarter of 1975. While the money stock (MI) grew fairly rapidly in the first half of 1974, after June its growth first slowed and then behaved erratically; on balance, it averaged only 1.4 percent (annual rate) from June through January, before speeding up during February and March. In light of these patterns, was the large decline in short-term interest rates and the much smaller decline in long-term rates to be expected? Was the erratic pattern of growth in Ml predictable? The answer to the first question is a qualified "yes" and to the second question a qualified "no." These answers arise from an examination of the residuals from regression James L. Pierce 91 equationsin the SMP(Social Science Research Council-M.I.T.-University of Pennsylvania)model that describethe behaviorof money demandand interestrates. If these equationsexhibit no unusualbehavior in theirpre- diction errors,one would infer that the behaviorof money and interest ratesduring the recessionwas to be expected.If, on the otherhand, the pre- dictionerrors are unusually large, one wouldconclude that recentfinancial developmentswere unexpected. The single-periodprediction errors from the money-demand(currency plus demanddeposit) equations in the SMP model for 1973 and 1974 are shownin figure2. Theequations used to formthe predictionsof M1 wereas follows: (1) ln MC = 0.22 ln PCE - 0.005 ln RTB + 0.88 ln MC- Standarderror = 0.003; sample period: 1955:4-1971:4. (2) ln -0.28ln MD1-0.06ln RTB-0.12ln RSD y y + 0.08 In RDIS -0.34 In N-0.05' RDIS ~ N Standarderror = 0.0068; sample period: 1955:2-1972:4. where MC = currencyheld by the nonbankpublic PCE = personal consumption expenditures RTB = interestrate on Treasurybills MD = demanddeposits held by the nonbankpublic Y= GNP RSD = interest rate on savings deposits RDIS = discountrate y/N = GNP per capitain 1958 dollars. Actual values of the exogenous variablesin these equations-real and nominalGNP and short-terminterest rates-were used to formthe predic- tions. As figure2 clearlyreveals, the equationsseriously overstated M1 growthin the secondhalf of 1974.1What is more, the errorswere several timesgreater than those obtainedin earlierperiods.2 1. All the equation predictionsin this paper are single-periodpredictions that have set the rho termequal to zero. As a result,the equationsexhibit serially correlated errors. When actual predictionsare made, there is less concern in distinguishingthe role of structuralvariables from informationon the errorstructure and an estimatedvalue of rho is used. 2. As will be shown below, the predictionof the demand for demand deposits was responsiblefor the large errors;the currencypredictions were quite accurate. 92 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1975 Figure2. Actualand Predicted M1, Quarterly,1973 and 1974 Billions of dollars 300 290 Predicted - 280280 - Actual 270 260 - 250 I II III IV I II III lV 1973 1974 Sources: Actual-SMP data bank; predicted-SMP model, using money-demand equations (1) and (2) given in the text. Mi = currency plus demand deposits. Theerrors in the money-demandrelationships give someidea of whether the declinein interestrates in 1974was smallerthan would have been ex- pectedon the basis of past relationships.The equationsimply that-given the actualvalues of other exogenousvariables-Treasury bill rates of 8.8 percentand 8.3 percentin the third and fourth quarterswould have pro- duceda 6 percentincrease in M1at an annualrate. Actualbill ratesin the two quarterswere 8.2 and 7.4 percent,respectively, which should have yieldeda greatermoney demand;yet actualM1 growthwas only 2.0 and 2.2 percentin those quarters.3Thus, according to the money-demandequa- tions,actual bill rateswere sufficiently low to producean M1growth in ex- cess of 6 percent. Treatingthe errorsin the equationsas reductionsin the interceptof the money-demandequations-that is, treatingthem as if the money-demand equation"shifted" downward-makes it possibleto calculatethe interest 3. The quarterlyM1 figures used in the equations are averages of the two months surroundingthe end of the quarter;for example,the figurefor the fourth quarteris the averageof Decemberand January. James L. Pierce 93 ratesrequired to achievea 6 percentM1 growth. To do this, the intercepts of the currencyand demand-depositequations in the third and fourth quarterswere adjusted by each equation'serror in each quarter.With the adjustedequations, the Treasurybill ratesrequired to obtain6 percentM1 growthin the thirdand fourthquarters were 6.2 percentand 4.1 percent, respectively. Thelarge errors in predictingmoney demand are sufficient but not neces- saryto explainthe slowgrowth in M1.The demandfor moneyprovides pre- dictionsof themoney stock given short-term interest rates. With the interest ratesthat prevailedin the third and fourth quarters,the money-demand functionpredicted M1 growth higher than the actual. However,money growthneed not havebeen as slow as it was.If bankreserves had been sup- plied at a rate consistentwith more rapid growth in M1, interestrates would have fallen sufficientlyto equate money demand with the more rapidlygrowing supply and the money stock would have expandedmore rapidly.Thus, the issueis not that the declinein interestrates was so large butrather that it was not largeenough to spurmore rapid expansion in M1. Giventhe actualdecline in short-terminterest rates, the behaviorof long- termrates was not surprising.The model'sequation for the interestrate on newlyissued corporate bonds, taken as a measureof long-termrates, is 18 18 APCONQ+3~C (3) RNI = 0.76 + , b,RCP_j + E C PCON1 + 033 aRCP bo = 0.18, bi = 0.94; co = 4.83, i = 31.18, Standarderror = 0.17; sample period: 1954:4-1971:2. where RNI = interestrate on newlyissued Aaa utilitybonds RCP = commercial paper rate PCON = consumptionprices (percent change measured at annualrate) aRCP= a measureof the standarddeviation of RCP overthe previous eight quarters. The equationdid overpredictthe rate on new issuesin late 1973and 1974 by a substantialamount, the maximumerror being 1.4 percentagepoints in the first quarterof 1974. But the patternof predictionscaptured the up- surgein long-termrates in 1973and 1974and the moderatedecline in late 1974.The errorsmade duringthe periodappear to be explainable.In the equationa distributedlag on the percentagechange in consumptionprices 94 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1975 servesas a proxy for the expectedrate of inflation.The behaviorof this pricevariable was not an appropriatemeasure of expectedinflation because of the rapidrise in consumptionprices relative to other pricesduring the period.This variableprobably accounts for much of the overpredictionof the long-termrate in 1973and 1974. MONEY DEMAND While the declinesin interestrates may not be surprisinglylarge, the sizableerrors in predictingmoney demand in the secondhalf of 1974remain to be explained.The searchfor explanationsis frustratingand perhaps fruitless,particularly because the errorsmay have resultedfrom largeran- dom disturbances.An effortto "explain"the errorsis alwaysan exercisein ex post theorizing,which is often difficultto distinguishfrom pure ra- tionalization.If the ex post argumentsappear to be compelling,it is crucial to test the role of thesefactors not only in the currentsituation but also at othertimes when they
Recommended publications
  • QE Equivalence to Interest Rate Policy: Implications for Exit
    QE Equivalence to Interest Rate Policy: Implications for Exit Samuel Reynard∗ Preliminary Draft - January 13, 2015 Abstract A negative policy interest rate of about 4 percentage points equivalent to the Federal Reserve QE programs is estimated in a framework that accounts for the broad money supply of the central bank and commercial banks. This provides a quantitative estimate of how much higher (relative to pre-QE) the interbank interest rate will have to be set during the exit, for a given central bank’s balance sheet, to obtain a desired monetary policy stance. JEL classification: E52; E58; E51; E41; E43 Keywords: Quantitative Easing; Negative Interest Rate; Exit; Monetary policy transmission; Money Supply; Banking ∗Swiss National Bank. Email: [email protected]. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of the Swiss National Bank. I am thankful to Romain Baeriswyl, Marvin Goodfriend, and seminar participants at the BIS, Dallas Fed and SNB for helpful discussions and comments. 1 1. Introduction This paper presents and estimates a monetary policy transmission framework to jointly analyze central banks (CBs)’ asset purchase and interest rate policies. The negative policy interest rate equivalent to QE is estimated in a framework that ac- counts for the broad money supply of the CB and commercial banks. The framework characterises how standard monetary policy, setting an interbank market interest rate or interest on reserves (IOR), has to be adjusted to account for the effects of the CB’s broad money injection. It provides a quantitative estimate of how much higher (rel- ative to pre-QE) the interbank interest rate will have to be set during the exit, for a given central bank’s balance sheet, to obtain a desired monetary policy stance.
    [Show full text]
  • Interest-Rate-Growth Differentials and Government Debt Dynamics
    From: OECD Journal: Economic Studies Access the journal at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/19952856 Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics David Turner, Francesca Spinelli Please cite this article as: Turner, David and Francesca Spinelli (2012), “Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, Vol. 2012/1. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2012-5k912k0zkhf8 This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. OECD Journal: Economic Studies Volume 2012 © OECD 2013 Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics by David Turner and Francesca Spinelli* The differential between the interest rate paid to service government debt and the growth rate of the economy is a key concept in assessing fiscal sustainability. Among OECD economies, this differential was unusually low for much of the last decade compared with the 1980s and the first half of the 1990s. This article investigates the reasons behind this profile using panel estimation on selected OECD economies as means of providing some guidance as to its future development. The results suggest that the fall is partly explained by lower inflation volatility associated with the adoption of monetary policy regimes credibly targeting low inflation, which might be expected to continue. However, the low differential is also partly explained by factors which are likely to be reversed in the future, including very low policy rates, the “global savings glut” and the effect which the European Monetary Union had in reducing long-term interest differentials in the pre-crisis period.
    [Show full text]
  • Interest Rates and Expected Inflation: a Selective Summary of Recent Research
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Explorations in Economic Research, Volume 3, number 3 Volume Author/Editor: NBER Volume Publisher: NBER Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/sarg76-1 Publication Date: 1976 Chapter Title: Interest Rates and Expected Inflation: A Selective Summary of Recent Research Chapter Author: Thomas J. Sargent Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c9082 Chapter pages in book: (p. 1 - 23) 1 THOMAS J. SARGENT University of Minnesota Interest Rates and Expected Inflation: A Selective Summary of Recent Research ABSTRACT: This paper summarizes the macroeconomics underlying Irving Fisher's theory about tile impact of expected inflation on nomi­ nal interest rates. Two sets of restrictions on a standard macroeconomic model are considered, each of which is sufficient to iniplv Fisher's theory. The first is a set of restrictions on the slopes of the IS and LM curves, while the second is a restriction on the way expectations are formed. Selected recent empirical work is also reviewed, and its implications for the effect of inflation on interest rates and other macroeconomic issues are discussed. INTRODUCTION This article is designed to pull together and summarize recent work by a few others and myself on the relationship between nominal interest rates and expected inflation.' The topic has received much attention in recent years, no doubt as a consequence of the high inflation rates and high interest rates experienced by Western economies since the mid-1960s. NOTE: In this paper I Summarize the results of research 1 conducted as part of the National Bureaus study of the effects of inflation, for which financing has been provided by a grait from the American life Insurance Association Heiptul coinrnents on earlier eriiins of 'his p,irx'r serv marIe ti PhillipCagan arid l)y the mnibrirs Ut the stall reading Committee: Michael R.
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory
    2021 A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory Steven Globerman fraserinstitute.org Contents Executive Summary / i 1. Introducing Modern Monetary Theory / 1 2. Implementing MMT / 4 3. Has Canada Adopted MMT? / 10 4. Proposed Economic and Social Justifications for MMT / 17 5. MMT and Inflation / 23 Concluding Comments / 27 References / 29 About the author / 33 Acknowledgments / 33 Publishing information / 34 Supporting the Fraser Institute / 35 Purpose, funding, and independence / 35 About the Fraser Institute / 36 Editorial Advisory Board / 37 fraserinstitute.org fraserinstitute.org Executive Summary Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is a policy model for funding govern- ment spending. While MMT is not new, it has recently received wide- spread attention, particularly as government spending has increased dramatically in response to the ongoing COVID-19 crisis and concerns grow about how to pay for this increased spending. The essential message of MMT is that there is no financial constraint on government spending as long as a country is a sovereign issuer of cur- rency and does not tie the value of its currency to another currency. Both Canada and the US are examples of countries that are sovereign issuers of currency. In principle, being a sovereign issuer of currency endows the government with the ability to borrow money from the country’s cen- tral bank. The central bank can effectively credit the government’s bank account at the central bank for an unlimited amount of money without either charging the government interest or, indeed, demanding repayment of the government bonds the central bank has acquired. In 2020, the cen- tral banks in both Canada and the US bought a disproportionately large share of government bonds compared to previous years, which has led some observers to argue that the governments of Canada and the United States are practicing MMT.
    [Show full text]
  • Downward Nominal Wage Rigidities Bend the Phillips Curve
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Downward Nominal Wage Rigidities Bend the Phillips Curve Mary C. Daly Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Bart Hobijn Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, VU University Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute January 2014 Working Paper 2013-08 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2013/wp2013-08.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Downward Nominal Wage Rigidities Bend the Phillips Curve MARY C. DALY BART HOBIJN 1 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO VU UNIVERSITY AMSTERDAM, AND TINBERGEN INSTITUTE January 11, 2014. We introduce a model of monetary policy with downward nominal wage rigidities and show that both the slope and curvature of the Phillips curve depend on the level of inflation and the extent of downward nominal wage rigidities. This is true for the both the long-run and the short-run Phillips curve. Comparing simulation results from the model with data on U.S. wage patterns, we show that downward nominal wage rigidities likely have played a role in shaping the dynamics of unemployment and wage growth during the last three recessions and subsequent recoveries. Keywords: Downward nominal wage rigidities, monetary policy, Phillips curve. JEL-codes: E52, E24, J3. 1 We are grateful to Mike Elsby, Sylvain Leduc, Zheng Liu, and Glenn Rudebusch, as well as seminar participants at EIEF, the London School of Economics, Norges Bank, UC Santa Cruz, and the University of Edinburgh for their suggestions and comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Fact Sheet on Interest Rate Restrictions
    Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation FACT SHEET Interest Rate Restrictions The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) published a final rule to revise its regulations relating to interest rate restrictions on banks that are less than well capitalized. PROMOTES FLEXIBILITY AND RESPONSIVENESS ACROSS ECONOMIC CYCLES – The final rule promotes flexibility for institutions subject to the interest rate restrictions and ensures that those institutions will be able to compete for deposits regardless of the interest rate environment. • The final rule defines the “National Rate Cap” as the higher of (1) the national rate plus 75 basis points; or (2) for maturity deposits, 120 percent of the current yield on similar maturity U.S. Treasury obligations and, for nonmaturity deposits, the federal funds rate, plus 75 basis points. • By establishing two methods for calculating the national rate cap, the FDIC ensures that deposit interest rate caps are durable under both high-rate or rising-rate environments and low-rate or falling-rate environments. MORE COMPREHENSIVE NATIONAL RATE – The final rule defines the National Rate to include credit union rates for the first time. • “National Rate” is defined as the weighted average of rates paid by all IDIs and credit unions on a given deposit product, for which data are available, where the weights are each institution’s market share of domestic deposits. PROMOTES TRANSPARENCY – The final rule calculates the National Rate Cap based on similar maturity U.S. Treasury obligations and the federal funds rate, which are both publicly available, and thus, represent a more transparent calculation for bankers and the public. REDUCES REGULATORY BURDEN – The final rule provides a new simplified process, as opposed to the current two-step process, for institutions that seek to offer a competitive rate when the prevailing rate in an institution’s local market area exceeds the national rate cap.
    [Show full text]
  • Retirement Implications of a Low Wage Growth, Low Real Interest Rate Economy
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RETIREMENT IMPLICATIONS OF A LOW WAGE GROWTH, LOW REAL INTEREST RATE ECONOMY Jason Scott John B. Shoven Sita Slavov John G. Watson Working Paper 25556 http://www.nber.org/papers/w25556 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2019 This research was supported by the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation through grant #G-2017-9695. We are grateful for helpful comments from John Sabelhaus and participants at the 2018 SIEPR Conference on Working Longer and Retirement. We thank Kyung Min Lee for excellent research assistance. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. At least one co-author has disclosed a financial relationship of potential relevance for this research. Further information is available online at http://www.nber.org/papers/w25556.ack NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2019 by Jason Scott, John B. Shoven, Sita Slavov, and John G. Watson. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Retirement Implications of a Low Wage Growth, Low Real Interest Rate Economy Jason Scott, John B. Shoven, Sita Slavov, and John G. Watson NBER Working Paper No. 25556 February 2019 JEL No. D14,H55,J26 ABSTRACT We examine the implications of persistent low real interest rates and wage growth rates on individuals nearing retirement.
    [Show full text]
  • Interest Rate Expectations and the Slope of the Money Market Yield Curve
    Interest Rate Expectations and the Slope of the Money Market Yield Curve Timothy Cook and Thomas Hahn l What determines the relationship between yield This paper surveys the recent literature on the and maturity (the yield curve) in the money market? determinants of the yield curve. It begins by review- A resurgence of interest in this question in recent ing the expectations theory and recent empirical tests years has resulted in a substantial body of new of the theory. It discusses two general explanations research. The focus of much of the research has been for the lack of support for the theory from these tests. on tests of the “expectations theory.” According to Finally, the paper discusses in more detail the the theory, changes in the slope of the yield curve behavior of market participants that might influence should depend on interest rate expectations: the more the yield curve, and the role that monetary policy market participants expect rates to rise, the more might play in explaining this behavior. positive should be the slope of the current yield curve. The expectations theory suggests that vari- I. ation in the slope of the yield curve should be THE EXPECTATIONS THEORY systematically related to the subsequent movement Concepts in interest rates. Much of the recent research has focused on whether this prediction of the theory is Two concepts central to the tests of the expecta- supported by the data. A surprising finding is that tions theory reviewed below are the “forward rate parts of the yield curve have been useful in forecasting premium” and the “term premium.” Suppose an in- interest rates while other parts have not.
    [Show full text]
  • What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates?
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates? Gauti B. Eggertsson Staff Report no. 402 November 2009 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the author and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author. What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates? Gauti B. Eggertsson Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 402 November 2009 JEL classification: E52 Abstract Tax cuts can deepen a recession if the short-term nominal interest rate is zero, according to a standard New Keynesian business cycle model. An example of a contractionary tax cut is a reduction in taxes on wages. This tax cut deepens a recession because it increases deflationary pressures. Another example is a cut in capital taxes. This tax cut deepens a recession because it encourages people to save instead of spend at a time when more spending is needed. Fiscal policies aimed directly at stimulating aggregate demand work better. These policies include 1) a temporary increase in government spending; and 2) tax cuts aimed directly at stimulating aggregate demand rather than aggregate supply, such as an investment tax credit or a cut in sales taxes. The results are specific to an environment in which the interest rate is close to zero, as observed in large parts of the world today.
    [Show full text]
  • Liquidity Provision, Interest Rates, and Unemployment!
    Published in the Journal of Monetary Economics, Volume 65, 80-101, July 2014 Liquidity Provision, Interest Rates, and Unemployment Guillaume Rocheteau and Antonio Rodriguez-Lopez Department of Economics University of California, Irvine Final version: March 2014 Abstract The e¤ective liquidity supply of the economy— the weighted-sum of all assets that serve as media of exchange— matters for interest rates and unemployment. We formalize this idea by adding an over-the-counter market with collateralized trades to the Mortensen-Pissarides model. An increase in public liquidity through a higher supply of real government bonds raises the real interest rate, crowding out private liquidity and increasing unemployment. If unemployment is ine¢ ciently high, keeping liquidity scarce can be socially optimal. A liquidity crisis a¤ecting the acceptability of private assets as collateral widens the rate-of-return di¤erence between private and public liquidity, also increasing unemployment. JEL Classi…cation: D82, D83, E40, E50 Keywords: unemployment, liquidity, interest rates This paper was prepared for the Carnegie-Rochester-NYU Conference Series on Public Policy on “A Century of Money, Banking, and Financial Instability”(November 15-16, 2013 in Pittsburgh, PA). We thank Marvin Goodfriend (the editor) and our discussant, Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau, for comments and suggestions. We also thank Jean- Paul Carvalho, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Edouard Schaal, Mike Woodford, Cathy Zhang, and seminar participants at Bundesbank, UC Riverside, UC Santa Barbara, the University of Melbourne, the University of Paris 2, the 2013 Summer Workshop on Money, Banking, Payments, and Finance at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and the Philadelphia Search-and-Matching Workshop at the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.
    [Show full text]
  • The Relationship Between Nominal Interest Rates and Inflation
    Journal of Multinational Financial Management 11 (2001) 269–280 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase The relationship between nominal interest rates and inflation: international evidence G. Geoffrey Booth a,*, Cetin Ciner b a 315 Eppley Center, Eli Broad Graduate School of Management, Michigan State Uni6ersity, E. Lansing, MI 48824, USA b Northeastern Uni6ersity, Boston MA, USA Received 16 March 1999; accepted 22 May 2000 Abstract This paper examines the long-run bivariate relationship between the short-term Eurocur- rency interest rate and the inflation rate for nine European countries and the US. Applica- tion of cointegration methods reveals that in the majority of cases, there is a one-to-one relationship between Eurocurrency rates and rationally expected inflation. Moreover, the 1-month Eurocurrency rate contains information about the future path of the inflation rate. This finding supports the belief that market participants incorporate a predictable portion of the inflation rate into the nominal interest rate. © 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: E43; G15 Keywords: Interest rates; Inflation; Common trend 1. Introduction In a recent contribution, Crowder and Hoffman (1996) examine the long-run dynamic relationship between the short-term nominal interest rate and inflation. Consistent with the implications of the Fisher hypothesis (FH), using quarterly data * Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-517-3531745; fax: +1-517-4321080. E-mail address: [email protected] (G.G. Booth). 1042-444X/01/$ - see front matter © 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S1042-444X(01)00030-5 270 G.G. Booth, C. Ciner / J. of Multi. Fin. Manag.
    [Show full text]