Keynes on Inflation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Keynes on Inflation KEYNES ON INFLATION Thomas M. Humphrey Not the least of inflation’s consequences is the restrictive demand management policies to prevent damage done to the reputations of certain prominent it; that far from being an extreme nonmonetarist, economists. A case in point is John Maynard Keynes he shared the monetarists’ antipathy to inflation, (1883-1946). Once highly regarded for his brilliant endorsed their policy goal of price stability, and em- pathbreaking analysis of the causes of mass unem- ployed at least five monetarist concepts in his analysis ployment in the Great Depression of the 1930s, he is of inflation; and, finally, that far from advocating now given low marks for his views on inflation. full employment at any cost, he maintained that even Popular folklore has it that he was largely uncon- at high unemployment rates expansionary aggregate cerned with inflation from the start, that his subse- demand policy must be curbed to prevent inflation. quent preoccupation with unemployment led him to More precisely, this article demonstrates (1) that ignore it altogether, and that, as a result, he favored Keynes was always concerned with inflation, (2) expansionary measures to eliminate unemployment that this concern motivated hi’s advocacy of anti- regardless of their inflationary consequences. Since inflationary aggregate demand management policy on his death in 1946 his name (or at least the label at least two occasions (including once in the Great “Keynesian”) has been linked to such inflationist Depression of the 1930s), and (3) that there are slogans as “full employment at any cost” and “money enough monetarist elements in his analysis to qualify doesn’t matter.” It has also found an association him as at least a partial monetarist as far as inflation with the discredited concept of a stable enduring theory is concerned. trade-off between inflation and unemployment as well These points are documented in the following para- as with the equally discredited notion that the au- graphs, which summarize Keynes’ own views on thorities can peg interest rates and real economic inflation. As pertinent now as they were when he activity at any desired level simply by manipulating first presented them, his views are contained chiefly the policy instruments they command. On the policy in the following works: (1) Indian Currency and front his name is now popularly identified with ex- Finance (1913), (2) The Economic Consequences cessive government spending, mounting budget defi- of the Peace (1919), (3) policy advice given to the cits, inflationary money growth; and, in Britain at Chancellor of the Exchequer in February 1920, (4) least, with the idea that inflation can be contained A Tract on Monetary Reform (1923), (5) the two- with incomes policies and wage-price controls. In the volume A Treatise on Money (1930), and (6) a textbooks, his views are caricatured in. the stylized series of four newspaper articles published in The “Keynes versus the monetarists” manner as the Times in early 1937, one year after the publication opposite of the anti-inflationary views of the mone- of his famous The General Theory of Employment tarists. Small wonder that he has been widely per- Interest and Money (1936). Except for the General ceived as an inflationist and that our present inflation Theory, which deals mainly with unemployment and is often described as the legacy of Keynes.1 will not be examined here, these works are largely The purpose of, this article, however, it to show concerned with the problem of inflation. They are that the foregoing perceptions are wrong: that far examined in the order listed above to show the con- from being an inflationist, Keynes deplored inflation, sistency of Keynes’ anti-inflation attitudes over time. warned repeatedly of its evils, and recommended Early Writings 1 For a recent expression of this view see Buchanan and Keynes’ strong aversion to inflation is evident in Wagner [l] who assert that “Lord Keynes himself” must even his earliest work. It appears, for example, in “bear substantial responsibility” for our “apparently per- manent and perhaps increasing inflation” [1; p. 41. his Indian Currency and Finance (1913). There he “Without Keynes,” they write, “inflation would not be the clear and present danger to the free society that it emphatically rejects the argument that “a depreci- has surely now become. The legacy or heritage of Lord ating currency is advantageous . to trade,” con- Keynes is the . .intellectual legitimacy provided to . tending that any advantages derived from inflation deficit spending, inflation, and the growth of govern- ment” [1; p. 24]. are “only temporary” and that they “occur largely at FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 3 the expense of other members of the community” and a Press of which they are the proprietors” [6; and therefore do “not profit the country as a whole” p. 150]. By making business a scapegoat and target [ 5 ; p. 2]. He takes an even tougher attitude in his of vilification and control, inflation reinforces anti- Economic Consequences of the Peace (1919), con- business attitudes and weakens support for what demning inflation in the harshest possible terms. Keynes called “the active and constructive element in He says : the whole capitalist society”2 [6; p. 149]. Finally, inflation tends to breed such misguided Lenin is said to have declared that the best way to remedies as “price regulation” and “profiteer- destroy the capitalist system was to debauch the currency. By a continuing process of inflation, hunting” that may do more damage than the inflation governments can confiscate, secretly and unob- itself. Keynes was especially critical of the tendency served, an important part of the wealth of their citizens. By this method they not only confiscate, of governments to resort to price controls, which in but they confiscate arbitrarily; and, while the his view lead to resource misallocation and a reduced process impoverishes many, it actually enriches supply of goods, thereby compounding inflationary some [6; pp. 148-9]. pressures.3 Regarding the disincentives to real out- He agrees with Lenin that inflation has the potenti- put occasioned by controls, he said that “the preser- ality of destroying the basis of capitalist society. vation of a spurious value for the currency, by the force of law expressed in the regulation of prices, Lenin was certainly right. There is no subtler, no contains in itself, however, the seeds of final eco- surer means of overturning the existing basis of society than to debauch the currency. The process nomic decay, and soon dries up the source of ultimate engages all the hidden forces of economic law on supply.” For, by freezing prices at what are likely the side of destruction, and does it in a manner to be disequilibrium levels, controls constitute “a which not one man in a million is able to diagnose [6; p. 149]. system of compelling the exchange of commodities at what is not their real relative value,” and this He then proceeds to specify at least four ways that “not only relaxes production but leads finally to the rapid inflation works to weaken the social fabric and waste and inefficiency of barter” [6; pp. 149-50]. to undermine the foundations of the capitalist free- Summarizing the foregoing harmful consequences market system. First, unforeseen inflation, he says, of inflation, he concludes that governments that allow results in a capricious and totally “arbitrary rear- inflation to get out of control do irreparable damage rangement of riches” that violates the principles of to the established social and economic order. In so distributive justice. Besides its inequities, inflation doing they are “carrying a step further the fatal also renders business undertakings riskier and thereby process which the subtle mind of Lenin had con- turns “the process of wealth-getting . into a gamble sciously conceived.” For, and a lottery.” In generating risk and injustice, infla- By combining a popular hatred of the class of tion “strikes not only at security, but at confidence in entrepreneurs with the blow already given to social the equity of the existing distribution of wealth” [6; security by the violent and arbitrary disturbance of contract and of the established equilibrium of p. 149]. Second, inflation violates long-term arrange- wealth which is the inevitable result of inflation. ments based on the assumed stability of the value of these governments are fast rendering impossible a money. In so doing, inflation disturbs contracts and continuance of the social and economic order. But they have no plan for replacing it [6; p. 150]. upsets “all permanent relations between debtors and creditors, which form the ultimate foundation of It would be difficult indeed to find a more damning capitalism” [6; p. 149]. Third, inflation generates indictment of inflation and inflationist policies than social discontent and directs it against businessmen that presented by Keynes. in The Economic Conse- whose windfall profits are wrongly perceived to be quences of the Peace. Anyone seeking evidence that the cause rather than the consequence of inflation. he was an inflationist will not find it there ; on the. This discontent is exploited by governments which contrary, not only does he display a marked aversion “being many of them . reckless . as well as weak, to inflation, but he also sees no compensating benefits seek to direct on to a class known as ‘profiteers’ the to offset its evils. popular indignation against the more obvious conse- quences of their vicious methods” [6; p. 149]. In 2 Note that the very inflationary evils denounced by other words, governments actually responsible for Keynes are likewise stressed by Buchanan and Wagner causing inflation seek to shift the blame onto busi- [l; pp. 61-5]. This in a book, ironically enough, pur- porting to show that Keynes was an inflationist.
Recommended publications
  • Monetary Policy in Economies with Little Or No Money
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY IN ECONOMIES WITH LITTLE OR NO MONEY Bennett T. McCallum Working Paper 9838 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9838 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2003 This paper was prepared for presentation at the December 16-17, 2002, meeting of the Hong Kong Economic Association. I am indebted to Marvin Goodfriend, Lok Sang Ho, Allan Meltzer, and Edward Nelson for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research ©2003 by Bennett T. McCallum. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including © notice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy in Economies with Little or No Money Bennett T. McCallum NBER Working Paper No. 9838 July 2003 JEL No. E3, E4, E5 ABSTRACT The paper's arguments include: (1) Medium-of-exchange money will not disappear in the foreseeable future, although the quantity of base money may continue to decline. (2) In economies with very little money (e.g., no currency but bank settlement balances at the central bank), monetary policy will be conducted much as at present by activist adjustment of overnight interest rates. Operating procedures will be different, however, with payment of interest on reserves likely to become the norm. (3) In economies without any money there can be no monetary policy. The relevant notion of a general price level concerns some index of prices in terms of a medium of account.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions by Irving Fisher
    THE DEBT-DEFLATION THEORY OF GREAT DEPRESSIONS BY IRVING FISHER INTRODUCTORY IN Booms and Depressions, I have developed, theoretically and sta- tistically, what may be called a debt-deflation theory of great depres- sions. In the preface, I stated that the results "seem largely new," I spoke thus cautiously because of my unfamiliarity with the vast literature on the subject. Since the book was published its special con- clusions have been widely accepted and, so far as I know, no one has yet found them anticipated by previous writers, though several, in- cluding myself, have zealously sought to find such anticipations. Two of the best-read authorities in this field assure me that those conclu- sions are, in the words of one of them, "both new and important." Partly to specify what some of these special conclusions are which are believed to be new and partly to fit them into the conclusions of other students in this field, I am offering this paper as embodying, in brief, my present "creed" on the whole subject of so-called "cycle theory." My "creed" consists of 49 "articles" some of which are old and some new. I say "creed" because, for brevity, it is purposely ex- pressed dogmatically and without proof. But it is not a creed in the sense that my faith in it does not rest on evidence and that I am not ready to modify it on presentation of new evidence. On the contrary, it is quite tentative. It may serve as a challenge to others and as raw material to help them work out a better product.
    [Show full text]
  • The Origins and Evolution of Progressive Economics Part Seven of the Progressive Tradition Series
    AP PHOTO/FILE AP This January 1935 photo shows a mural depicting phases of the New Deal The Origins and Evolution of Progressive Economics Part Seven of the Progressive Tradition Series Ruy Teixeira and John Halpin March 2011 WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG The Origins and Evolution of Progressive Economics Part Seven of the Progressive Tradition Series Ruy Teixeira and John Halpin March 2011 With the rise of the contemporary progressive movement and the election of President Barack Obama in 2008, there is extensive public interest in better understanding the ori- gins, values, and intellectual strands of progressivism. Who were the original progressive thinkers and activists? Where did their ideas come from and what motivated their beliefs and actions? What were their main goals for society and government? How did their ideas influence or diverge from alternative social doctrines? How do their ideas and beliefs relate to contemporary progressivism? The Progressive Tradition Series from the Center for American Progress traces the devel- opment of progressivism as a social and political tradition stretching from the late 19th century reform efforts to the current day. The series is designed primarily for educational and leadership development purposes to help students and activists better understand the foundations of progressive thought and its relationship to politics and social movements. Although the Progressive Studies Program has its own views about the relative merit of the various values, ideas, and actors discussed within the progressive tradition, the essays included in the series are descriptive and analytical rather than opinion based. We envision the essays serving as primers for exploring progressivism and liberalism in more depth through core texts—and in contrast to the conservative intellectual tradition and canon.
    [Show full text]
  • Money in the Economy: a Post-Keynesian Perspective
    Money in the Economy: A post-Keynesian perspective Jo Michell, SOAS, University of London Fundamental Uncertainty • Originates in Keynes’ theory of probability • “non-ergodic” = distinction between known probability distribution (known unknowns) and unknowable future (unknown unknowns) • Risk and uncertainty • Conventions and animal spirits • Decisions on investment and saving “Is our expectation of rain, when we start out for a walk, always more likely than not, or less likely than not, or as likely as not? I am prepared to argue that on some occasions none of these alternatives hold, and that it will be an arbitrary matter to decide for or against the umbrella. If the barometer is high, but the clouds are black, it is not always rational that one should prevail over the other in our minds, or even that we should balance them, though it will be rational to allow caprice to determine us and to waste no time on the debate” (Keynes, Treatise on Probability) Money • Mechanism to cope with uncertainty • Three functions: store of value, unit of account, means of payment • Liquidity • Means to transfer purchasing power in order to meet contractual obligations • Contrast with Classical view: money as a means of transaction. Why hold money? “Money, it is well known, serves two principal purposes. By acting as a money of account it facilitates exchange without its being necessary that it should ever itself come into the picture as a substantive object. In this respect it is a convenience which is devoid of significance or real influence. In the second place, it is a store of wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation and the Business Cycle
    Inflation and the business cycle Michael McMahon Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 1 / 68 To Cover • Discuss the costs of inflation; • Investigate the relationship between money and inflation; • Introduce the Romer framework; • Discuss hyperinflations. • Shocks and the business cycle; • Monetary policy responses to business cycles. • Explain what the monetary transmission mechanism is; • Examine the link between inflation and GDP. Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 2 / 68 The Next Few Lectures Term structure, asset prices Exchange and capital rate market conditions Import prices Bank rate Net external demand CPI inflation Bank lending Monetary rates and credit Policy Asset purchase/ Corporate DGI conditions Framework sales demand loans Macro prudential Household policy demand deposits Inflation expectations Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 3 / 68 Inflation Definition Inflation is a sustained general rise in the price level in the economy. In reality we measure it using concepts such as: • Consumer Price Indices (CPI); • Producer Price Indices (PPI); • Deflators (GDP deflator, Consumption Expenditure Deflator) Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 4 / 68 Inflation: The Costs If all prices are rising at same rate, including wages and asset prices, what is the problem? • Information: Makes it harder to detect relative price changes and so hinders efficient operation of market; • Uncertainty: High inflation countries have very volatile inflation; • High inflation undermines role of money and encourages barter; • Growth - if inflation increases by 10%, reduce long term growth by 0.2% but only for countries with inflation higher than 15% (Barro); • Shoe leather costs/menu costs; • Interaction with tax system; • Because of fixed nominal contracts arbitrarily redistributes wealth; • Nominal contracts break down and long-term contracts avoided.
    [Show full text]
  • Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics After World War I
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER June 2018 Working Paper 2018-06 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2018/06/ Suggested citation: Lopez, Jose A., Kris James Mitchener. 2018. “Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2018-06. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2018-06 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER* May 9, 2018 ABSTRACT. Fiscal deficits, elevated debt-to-GDP ratios, and high inflation rates suggest hyperinflation could have potentially emerged in many European countries after World War I. We demonstrate that economic policy uncertainty was instrumental in pushing a subset of European countries into hyperinflation shortly after the end of the war. Germany, Austria, Poland, and Hungary (GAPH) suffered from frequent uncertainty shocks – and correspondingly high levels of uncertainty – caused by protracted political negotiations over reparations payments, the apportionment of the Austro-Hungarian debt, and border disputes. In contrast, other European countries exhibited lower levels of measured uncertainty between 1919 and 1925, allowing them more capacity with which to implement credible commitments to their fiscal and monetary policies.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Monetary Policy in the New Keynesian Model: Evidence from Vietnam
    The role of monetary policy in the New Keynesian Model: Evidence from Vietnam By: Van Hoang Khieu William Davidson Institute Working Paper Number 1075 February 2014 The role of monetary policy in the New Keynesian Model: Evidence from Vietnam Khieu, Van Hoang Graduate Student at The National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies (GRIPS), Japan. Lecturer in Monetary Economics at Banking Academy of Vietnam. Email: [email protected] Cell phone number: +81-8094490288 Abstract This paper reproduces a version of the New Keynesian model developed by Ireland (2004) and then uses the Vietnamese data from January 1995 to December 2012 to estimate the model’s parameters. The empirical results show that before August 2000 when the Taylor rule was adopted more firmly, the monetary policy shock made considerable contributions to the fluctuations in key macroeconomic variables such as the short-term nominal interest rate, the output gap, inflation, and especially output growth. By contrast, the loose adoption of the Taylor rule in the period of post- August 2000 leads to a fact that the contributions of the monetary policy shock to the variations in such key macroeconomic variables become less substantial. Thus, one policy implication is that adopting firmly the Taylor rule could strengthen the role of the monetary policy in driving movements in the key macroeconomic variables, for instance, enhancing economic growth and stabilizing inflation. Key words: New Keynesian model, Monetary Policy, Technology Shock, Cost-Push Shock, Preference Shock. JEL classification: E12, E32. 1 1. Introduction Explaining dynamic behaviors of key macroeconomic variables has drawn a lot of interest from researchers.
    [Show full text]
  • Dangers of Deflation Douglas H
    ERD POLICY BRIEF SERIES Economics and Research Department Number 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks Pilipinas F. Quising Asian Development Bank http://www.adb.org Asian Development Bank P.O. Box 789 0980 Manila Philippines 2002 by Asian Development Bank December 2002 ISSN 1655-5260 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ERD Policy Brief Series is based on papers or notes prepared by ADB staff and their resource persons. The series is designed to provide concise nontechnical accounts of policy issues of topical interest to ADB management, Board of Directors, and staff. Though prepared primarily for internal readership within the ADB, the series may be accessed by interested external readers. Feedback is welcome via e-mail ([email protected]). ERD POLICY BRIEF NO. 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks and Pilipinas F. Quising December 2002 ecently, there has been growing concern about deflation in some Rcountries and the possibility of deflation at the global level. Aggregate demand, output, and employment could stagnate or decline, particularly where debt levels are already high. Standard economic policy stimuli could become less effective, while few policymakers have experience in preventing or halting deflation with alternative means. Causes and Consequences of Deflation Deflation refers to a fall in prices, leading to a negative change in the price index over a sustained period. The fall in prices can result from improvements in productivity, advances in technology, changes in the policy environment (e.g., deregulation), a drop in prices of major inputs (e.g., oil), excess capacity, or weak demand.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • The End of Modern Economic Growth As We Know It Jean-Pierre Dormois
    The End of Modern Economic Growth as We Know It Jean-Pierre Dormois To cite this version: Jean-Pierre Dormois. The End of Modern Economic Growth as We Know It. 2017, pp.1-9. halshs- 02862342 HAL Id: halshs-02862342 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-02862342 Submitted on 9 Jun 2020 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. The End of Modern Economic Growth as We Know It by Jean-Pierre Dormois Economic progress is behind us in the West, warns Robert J. Gordon in a 750 pages-tome which revisits the economic history of the U.S. in the last century and a half. Measuring the impact on living standards of the major technological breakthroughs of the “second industrial revolution,” he observes that sources of productivity growth seem to have dried since the 1970s oil shock and that the productivity-enhancing effects of the digital “revolution” have so far proved elusive. Reviewed: Robert J. Gordon, The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the Civil War, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 2016. Between 1870 and 1970, or more precisely between 1890 and 1940, the author demonstrates, the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • QE Equivalence to Interest Rate Policy: Implications for Exit
    QE Equivalence to Interest Rate Policy: Implications for Exit Samuel Reynard∗ Preliminary Draft - January 13, 2015 Abstract A negative policy interest rate of about 4 percentage points equivalent to the Federal Reserve QE programs is estimated in a framework that accounts for the broad money supply of the central bank and commercial banks. This provides a quantitative estimate of how much higher (relative to pre-QE) the interbank interest rate will have to be set during the exit, for a given central bank’s balance sheet, to obtain a desired monetary policy stance. JEL classification: E52; E58; E51; E41; E43 Keywords: Quantitative Easing; Negative Interest Rate; Exit; Monetary policy transmission; Money Supply; Banking ∗Swiss National Bank. Email: [email protected]. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of the Swiss National Bank. I am thankful to Romain Baeriswyl, Marvin Goodfriend, and seminar participants at the BIS, Dallas Fed and SNB for helpful discussions and comments. 1 1. Introduction This paper presents and estimates a monetary policy transmission framework to jointly analyze central banks (CBs)’ asset purchase and interest rate policies. The negative policy interest rate equivalent to QE is estimated in a framework that ac- counts for the broad money supply of the CB and commercial banks. The framework characterises how standard monetary policy, setting an interbank market interest rate or interest on reserves (IOR), has to be adjusted to account for the effects of the CB’s broad money injection. It provides a quantitative estimate of how much higher (rel- ative to pre-QE) the interbank interest rate will have to be set during the exit, for a given central bank’s balance sheet, to obtain a desired monetary policy stance.
    [Show full text]
  • The Interaction Between Monetary and Fiscal Policy: Insights from Two Business Cycles in Israel
    The interaction between monetary and fiscal policy: insights from two business cycles in Israel Kobi Braude and Karnit Flug1 Abstract Comparing the two significant recessions Israel experienced over the last decade, we highlight the importance of sustained fiscal discipline and credible monetary policy during normal times for expanding the set of policy options available at a time of need. In the first recession Israel was forced to conduct a contractionary fiscal and monetary policy, whereas in the second one it was able to pursue an expansionary policy. The difference in the effect of the policy response between the two recessions is sizable: it exacerbated the first recession while it helped to moderate the second one. Keywords: Fiscal policy, fiscal discipline, public debt, monetary policy, counter-cyclical policy, business cycles JEL classification: E52, E62, H6 1 Bank of Israel. We thank Stanley Fischer and Alon Binyamini for helpful comments and Noa Heymann for her research assistance. BIS Papers No 67 205 Introduction Over the last decade Israel experienced two significant business cycles. The monetary and fiscal policy response to the recession at the end of the decade was very different from the response to recession of the early 2000s. In the earlier episode, following a steep rise in the budget deficit and a single 2 percentage point interest rate reduction, policy makers were forced to make a sharp reversal and conduct a contractionary policy in the midst of the recession. In the second episode, monetary and fiscal expansion was pursued until recovery was well under way. This note examines the factors behind the difference in the policy response to the two recession episodes.
    [Show full text]