TMP Submission 12 Attachment

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

TMP Submission 12 Attachment rescuing democracy Before you start to read this book, take this moment to think about making a donation to punctum books, an independent non-profit press, @ https://punctumbooks.com/support/ If you’re reading the e-book, you can click on the image below to go directly to our donations site. Any amount, no matter the size, is appreciated and will help us to keep our ship of fools afloat. Contri- butions from dedicated readers will also help us to keep our commons open and to cultivate new work that can’t find a welcoming port elsewhere. Our ad- venture is not possible without your support. Vive la open-access. Fig. 1. Hieronymus Bosch, Ship of Fools (1490–1500) rescuing democracy: how public deliberation can curb government failure. Copyright © 2016 Paul E. Smith. This work carries a Creative Com- mons by-nc-sa 4.0 International license, which means that you are free to copy and redistribute the material in any medium or format, and you may also remix, transform, and build upon the material, as long as you clearly attribute the work to the authors and editors (but not in a way that suggests the authors or punc- tum books endorses you and your work), you do not use this work for commer- cial gain in any form whatsoever, and that for any remixing and transformation, you distribute your rebuild under the same license. http://creativecommons. org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/ First published in 2016 by punctum books, Earth, Milky Way. www.punctumbooks.com isbn-13: 978-0-9982375-0-3 isbn-10: 0-9982375-0-7 Library of Congress Cataloging Data is available from the Library of Congress Book design: Vincent W.J. van Gerven Oei PAUL E. SMITH RESCUING DEMOCRACY How Public Deliberation Can Curb Government Failure To my grandchildren Jet, Thomas, Ella and Lila. May their generation — and those that follow — govern themselves better than ours does. Contents List of figures and tables 14 Acknowledgements 15 Synopsis 19 1. Signs of failure 35 part i Diagnosing dysfunction 2. Democratic dysfunction from fundamental structure 55 2.1 The function of democratic government · · · · · · · · 56 2.1.1 Social choice by democratic government · · · · · 64 2.2 Ambiguous delegation · · · · · · · · · · · · 69 · · 2.2.1 Obstructions to communicative democracy · · · 75· 2.2.2 Citizens as directors · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 81 2.2.3 Ignorant directors · · · · · · · · · · · · 84· · 2.2.3.1 Fairly stable motivations of citizens’ ignorance of public goods · · · · · · · · · · · 88· · 2.2.3.2 Relatively dynamic motivations of citizens’ ignorance of public goods · · · · · · · · 92 · · 2.2.4 Unconscious directors · · · · · · · · · · 95 · · 2.2.5 Failure in accountability and legitimacy · · · ·102 · 2.2.6 A less fundamental type of ambiguous delegation — supermajoritarianism · · · · · ·105 · 2.2.7 An objection to ambiguous delegation being seen as a major problem · · · · · · · · · 106 2.2.8 An overview of ambiguous delegation · · · · 108· 2.3 Excessive competition · · · · · · · · · · · 109· · 2.3.1 Competition distracts politicians from producing public goods · · · · · · · · · · · · 114 2.3.2 Competition tempts politicians to sell legislation · 115 2.3.3 Political competition intensified by commercial competition · · · · · · · · · 120· · 2.3.4 Exacerbation of political competition by ambiguous delegation · · · · · · · · · · · · 121 2.3.5 Minimizing the damage from competition · · · · 122 2.4 Excessive compromise · · · · · · · · · · · ·123 · · 2.5 Triple dysfunction · · · · · · · · · · · · ·126 · · 2.6 Checking the hypothesis by backward mapping from two democratic failures · · · · · · · · · 129 · · 2.6.1 Neglect of the long term in Australian politics · · 130 2.6.2 Recurrence of environmental policy failures · · · 134 2.7 Summary and implications · · · · · · · · · ·137 · · 3. Susceptibility to dysfunction: Types of democracy 141 3.1 The Nordic democracies · · · · · · · · · · · 142· · 3.2 The case of the United States · · · · · · · · · 146 · · 4. Susceptibility to dysfunction: Types of issue 159 4.1 Issue characteristics that create problems for liberal democratic governments · · · · · · · · · · 160 4.2 Three cases of irresponsibility by liberal democratic governments · · · · · · · · · · · · · 167 4.2.1 Size of population · · · · · · · · · · · ·170 · · 4.2.2 Global warming · · · · · · · · · · · · 176· · 4.2.3 Unemployment · · · · · · · · · · · · 186 · · 5. A pervasive symptom of dysfunction: Escalating the scarcity of natural capital 191 5.1 Illustrating the problem · · · · · · · · · · · 194 · · 5.1.1 Characteristics of the choice on economic growth that confuse democracies · · · · · · · · · · · 196 5.2 Two key concepts for the scarcity multiplier analysis · · 198 5.2.1 Inflating want by supply · · · · · · · · · 198 · · 5.2.2 Private goods bias · · · · · · · · · · · ·203 · · 5.3 The scarcity multiplier · · · · · · · · · · · ·206 · · 5.3.1 The mechanism · · · · · · · · · · · · 207 · · 5.3.2 Extreme scarcity from the private goods bias · · · 218 5.3.3 Three reinforcements of the scarcity multiplier · ·219 5.3.4 The influence of each iws system and their control · · · · · · · · · · · 223· · 5.3.5 Motivators of the scarcity multiplier other than politi- cal decisions to privatise public natural capital · · · 224 5.3.6 Costs and benefits of the multiplier · · · · · ·228 · 5.4 Implications of the scarcity multiplier · · · · · · 234 · 5.5 Conclusions for Part I · · · · · · · · · · · 242· · part ii Prescribing a remedy 6. The People’s Forum: A deliberative aid for liberal democracies 247 6.1 The mission, strategies and shape of the People’s Forum · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 250 · · 6.1.1 The focus of the Forum · · · · · · · · · · · 253 6.1.2 The structure of the poll · · · · · · · · · 255 · · 6.1.3 Voting process · · · · · · · · · · · · · 256 · · 6.1.4 Ballot paper · · · · · · · · · · · · · 258· · 6.1.5 The execution of the Forum’s strategies · · · · · · 260 6.2 Evaluating democratic institutions · · · · · · · ·262 · 6.2.1 Political equality goods · · · · · · · · · ·266 · · 6.2.2 Governmental goods · · · · · · · · · · 268 · · 6.2.3 Institutional goods · · · · · · · · · · ·270 · · 6.2.4 Evaluating goods of democratic institutions · · ·274 · 6.3 Five major functions of the People’s Forum · · · · ·275 · 6.3.1 Public deliberation of issues · · · · · · · · 275· · 6.3.2 Deliberating what is to be deliberated · · · · · · 277 6.3.3 Examining basics · · · · · · · · · · · 278· · 6.3.4 An element of meritocracy · · · · · · · · · · · 280 6.3.5 Economizing citizen effort · · · · · · · · ·285 · 6.3.6 Summary of anticipated contributions by five major functions of the Forum · · · · · · · 286· · 6.4 Initiating and running the Forum · · · · · · · 289 · · 6.5 The People’s Forum compared with principles and designs for deliberative democracy · · · · · · · · · ·291 · 6.5.1 The People’s Forum compared with principles for deliberative democracy and public management · 292 6.5.2 The People’s Forum compared with other proposed deliberative designs · · · · · · · · · · · · · 297 6.5.2.1 The Popular Branch · · · · · · · · · 297 · · 6.5.2.2 The People’s House · · · · · · · · · · 301 · · 6.5.2.3 Pyramidal democracy · · · · · · · · 305· · 6.5.2.4 Comparing the four designs and observations on five more · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 311 6.6 Perspectives on the promise of the People’s Forum · · ·320 7. Design details of the People’s Forum 325 7.1 Twelve functions of the People’s Forum · · · · · 325· · 7.2 Elements of the design of the People’s Forum and why they should produce its twelve functions · · · · · · ·327 · 7.2.1 Twenty-two elements of the design · · · · · ·327 · 7.2.2 Function 1 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 329 · · 7.2.3 Function 2 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 342 · · 7.2.4 Function 3 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 343 · · 7.2.5 Function 4 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 349· · 7.2.6 Function 5 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 350 · · 7.2.7 Function 6 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 354· · 7.2.8 Function 7 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 355 · · 7.2.9 Function 8 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 355 · · 7.2.10 Function 9 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 355· · 7.2.11 Function 10 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 360 7.2.12 Function 11 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 361· · 7.2.13 Function 12 · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 363 7.3 Comments on design element E1 — the ballot paper · · 372 8. Likely reactions to the Forum 381 8.1 A closer look at the differing reactions of liberals and conservatives · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 383 8.2 The applicability of the People’s Forum to the polarized politics of the USA · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · 394 8.3 General prospects for the Forum · · · · · · · · 397· · 9. Supporting devices, performance indicators and trialling the People’s Forum 401 9.1 Devices that may synergize with the People’s Forum · · 402 9.2 Performance indicators for the People’s Forum · · · 415· 9.2.1 Indicators of achievement of mission (indicator types i & ii) · · · · · · · · · · · · 417 9.2.2 Indicators of execution of the first strategy (indicator type iii) · · · · · · · · · · · · · 418 9.2.3 Indicators of execution of the second strategy (indicator type iv) · · · · · · · · · · · ·419 · · 9.3 The inadequacy of small-scale trials of the People’s Forum · · · · · · · · · · · · · ·420 · · 9.3.1 Simulation instead of small-scale experiment · ·424 · 10. Conclusion 427 Afterword. A method for designing political institutions 439 The five strategies of the method 442 “Pushing and pulling” as science 448 Applying the five strategies 452 The method as a theory of institutional design 454 Appendix. Population growth and
Recommended publications
  • Investigating the Application of Structured Representations of Unstructured Content in Personalisation Tasks
    Investigating the application of structured representations of unstructured content in personalisation tasks Aonghus McGovern A thesis submitted to University of Dublin, Trinity College for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy March 12, 2019 Declaration This thesis is entirely the work of the author, except where otherwise stated, and has not been submitted for a degree to any other University. This thesis may be copied and lent to others by the University of Dublin. Aonghus McGovern March 12, 2019 ii Acknowledgements To James Cogley, who proofed my early drafts and gave me invaluable advice, I will be forever grateful. To Brendan, Jamie, Lucy, Nicole and Rebekah, the countless discussions we had in the lab will stay with me forever. To my parents, who raised me and supported me throughout my entire educational journey, I am deeply grateful. To my supervisor Vincent Wade, who made me into the researcher I am today, goes my sincerest gratitude. iii Abstract For personalisation approaches that analyse unstructured content, a common task is converting that unstructured content to a structured representation. Each structured representation has strengths and weaknesses, and the choice of representation should be made with respect to the personalisation task at hand. However, the way in which the choice of structured representations affects the personalisation that can be performed using that representation has not been clearly articulated. This is because personalisation approaches tend to focus on the success of their chosen personalisation task (e.g. recommendation accuracy) without examining how the characteristics of their chosen structured representation influenced this success. This motivates an investigation of of the characteristics of structured representations in the context of different personalisation tasks.
    [Show full text]
  • Legislature by Lot: Envisioning Sortition Within a Bicameral System
    PASXXX10.1177/0032329218789886Politics & SocietyGastil and Wright 789886research-article2018 Special Issue Article Politics & Society 2018, Vol. 46(3) 303 –330 Legislature by Lot: Envisioning © The Author(s) 2018 Article reuse guidelines: Sortition within a Bicameral sagepub.com/journals-permissions https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329218789886DOI: 10.1177/0032329218789886 System* journals.sagepub.com/home/pas John Gastil Pennsylvania State University Erik Olin Wright University of Wisconsin–Madison Abstract In this article, we review the intrinsic democratic flaws in electoral representation, lay out a set of principles that should guide the construction of a sortition chamber, and argue for the virtue of a bicameral system that combines sortition and elections. We show how sortition could prove inclusive, give citizens greater control of the political agenda, and make their participation more deliberative and influential. We consider various design challenges, such as the sampling method, legislative training, and deliberative procedures. We explain why pairing sortition with an elected chamber could enhance its virtues while dampening its potential vices. In our conclusion, we identify ideal settings for experimenting with sortition. Keywords bicameral legislatures, deliberation, democratic theory, elections, minipublics, participation, political equality, sortition Corresponding Author: John Gastil, Department of Communication Arts & Sciences, Pennsylvania State University, 232 Sparks Bldg., University Park, PA 16802, USA. Email: [email protected] *This special issue of Politics & Society titled “Legislature by Lot: Transformative Designs for Deliberative Governance” features a preface, an introductory anchor essay and postscript, and six articles that were presented as part of a workshop held at the University of Wisconsin–Madison, September 2017, organized by John Gastil and Erik Olin Wright.
    [Show full text]
  • Crowdsourcing Applications of Voting Theory Daniel Hughart
    Crowdsourcing Applications of Voting Theory Daniel Hughart 5/17/2013 Most large scale marketing campaigns which involve consumer participation through voting makes use of plurality voting. In this work, it is questioned whether firms may have incentive to utilize alternative voting systems. Through an analysis of voting criteria, as well as a series of voting systems themselves, it is suggested that though there are no necessarily superior voting systems there are likely enough benefits to alternative systems to encourage their use over plurality voting. Contents Introduction .................................................................................................................................... 3 Assumptions ............................................................................................................................... 6 Voting Criteria .............................................................................................................................. 10 Condorcet ................................................................................................................................. 11 Smith ......................................................................................................................................... 14 Condorcet Loser ........................................................................................................................ 15 Majority ...................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Democracy Without Elections Mainz
    Democracy without Elections: Is electoral accountability essential for democracy? Felix Gerlsbeck [email protected] Paper prepared for the workshop “Democratic Anxiety. Democratic Resilience.” Mainz, 15-17 June 2017 DRAFT VERSION, PLEASE DO NOT CITE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION 1. Introduction The idea of choosing political decision-makers by sortition, that is, choosing them randomly from a pool of the entire population or from some qualified subset, through some form of lottery or other randomizing procedure, is familiar to democrats at least since ancient Athens. Apart from the selection of trial juries, however, sortition has all but disappeared from official decision-making procedures within contemporary democratic systems, and free, equal, and regular election through voting by the entire qualified population of candidates who put themselves forward for political office, has taken its place. Nevertheless, there has been renewed interest in the idea of reviving sortition-based elements within modern democratic systems over the last years: a number of democratic theorists see great promise in complementing elected decision-making institutions with those selected randomly. These proposals variously go under the names mini-publics, citizen juries, citizen assemblies, lottocracy, enfranchisement lottery, and even Machiavellian Democracy.1 The roots of this practice go back to ancient Athens. During the 5th century Athenian democracy, the equivalent of the parliamentary body tasked with deliberating 1 See for instance, Guerrero 2014; Fishkin 2009; Warren & Gastil 2015; Ryan & Smith 2014; Saunders 2012; López-Guerra 2014; López-Guerra 2011; McCormick 2011. 1 and drafting policy proposals, the boule, was chosen by lot from the citizens of Athens through a complex system of randomization.
    [Show full text]
  • 122 DAYS to Engage with the Coalition, If You Comments Create a Misconception to 2013 Haven’T Already – We Can Help with This
    THE POLICY UPDATE 1 | M a y 2013 CLIMATE GAMIFICATION …by CEO, Benjamin Haslem THE POLICY UPDATE The Climate Reality Project, founded and Members get bonus points when Earlier this year we released our first chaired by former US Vice President Al someone responds to a pasted comment newsletter, The Shell, under our new Gore, has decided to take on their and clicks back to Reality Drop. brand – Wells Haslem Strategic Public opponents at their own game and have Supporters say Reality Drop uses Affairs. We intend to publish it at least established an intriguing digital project: competitive gaming techniques to twice a year. Reality Drop. combat climate denial online. Just to make sure that we bring you as Peruse most online articles about climate It could provide an interesting model for much news as possible about what we are change, where people are invited to leave political parties during election up to and what has piqued our interest, comments, and you would be excused for campaigns. All sides of politics accuse the we’ve decided to create The Shell Policy thinking a large number of people not other parties of flooding online Update… a smaller version of The Shell only dismiss the reality or threat of man- comments with information critical of published every few months. made climate change but seem to be their opponents. Here is the first edition. Feel free to quite knowledgeable about it. Of course, this begs the question, is provide feedback and some of your They sprout all sorts of facts and figures Reality Drop any different from the very information, anecdotes and ideas for the and present unsubstantiated claims to people it is criticising? It too is providing next edition of the Policy Update.
    [Show full text]
  • Australian Broadcasting Authority
    Australian Broadcasting Authority annual report Sydney 2000 Annual Report 1999-2000 © Commonwealth of Australia 2000 ISSN 1320-2863 Design by Media and Public Relations Australian Broadcasting Authority Cover design by Cube Media Pty Ltd Front cover photo: Paul Thompson of DMG Radio, successful bidder for the new Sydney commercial radio licence, at the ABA auction in May 2000 (photo by Rhonda Thwaite) Printed in Australia by Printing Headquarters, NSW For inquiries about this report, contact: Publisher Australian Broadcasting Authority at address below For inquiries relating to freedom of information, contact: FOi Coordinator Australian Broadcasting Authority Level 15, 201 Sussex Street Sydney NSW 2000 Tel: (02) 9334 7700 Fax: (02) 9334 7799 .Postal address: PO Box Q500 Queen Victoria Building NSW 1230 Email: [email protected] Web site: www.aba.gov.au 2 AustJt"aHan Broadcasting Authority Level 1 S Darling Park 201 Sussex St Sydney POBoxQ500 Queen Victoria Building August 2000 NSW1230 Phone (02) 9334 7700 Fax (02) 9334 7799 Senator the Hon. RichardAlston E-mail [email protected] 'nister for Communications,Information Technology and the Arts DX 13012Marlret St Sydney liarnentHouse anberraACT 2600 In accordancewith the requirements of section 9 andSchedule 1 of the Commonwealth Authorities and Companies Act 1997, I ampleased to present, on behalfof the Members of the AustralianBroadcasting Authority, thisannual reporton the operations of the llthorityfor the year 1999-2000. Annual Report 1999-2000 4 Contents Letter of transmittal 3 Members' report
    [Show full text]
  • Graham Richardson
    Graham Richardson Former ALP minister and political powerbroker Graham ‘Richo’ Richardson has a reputation as one of Australia’s foremost political operators and right-wing powerbrokers, despite having retired from politics in 1994. Graham Richardson joined the Australian Labor Party in 1966 when he was seventeen and soon apprenticed himself to the powerbrokers in the NSW Right, some of the toughest men in the Labor Party. So began a successful and colourful political career that took him from Labor Party branch organiser to General Secretary of the Australian Labor Party (NSW Branch), Senator for New South Wales for the ALP and a senior minister in the Hawke and Keating governments, making him one of the Labor Party’s key figures until his retirement. In his 11 years in federal politics, Graham held the ministerial portfolios of Environment, Arts, Sport, Tourism, Territories, Social Security, Transport, Communications and Health. Richo came to personify political ruthlessness and established the NSW Right of the Labor Party as a formidable political force on the national scene. He became famous for the line “whatever it takes” in reference to Labor doing “whatever it takes” to retain power. This also became the title of his best-selling account of career politics, published in 1994. Known as a king-maker, Graham Richardson had a significant influence on a great many political careers. He was instrumental in replacing Bill Hayden as federal leader with Bob Hawke in 1983 then Hawke with Paul Keating in 1991. After leaving politics in 1994, Richo spent eight years working for various parts of the Packer empire.
    [Show full text]
  • Instructor's Manual
    The Mathematics of Voting and Elections: A Hands-On Approach Instructor’s Manual Jonathan K. Hodge Grand Valley State University January 6, 2011 Contents Preface ix 1 What’s So Good about Majority Rule? 1 Chapter Summary . 1 Learning Objectives . 2 Teaching Notes . 2 Reading Quiz Questions . 3 Questions for Class Discussion . 6 Discussion of Selected Questions . 7 Supplementary Questions . 10 2 Perot, Nader, and Other Inconveniences 13 Chapter Summary . 13 Learning Objectives . 14 Teaching Notes . 14 Reading Quiz Questions . 15 Questions for Class Discussion . 17 Discussion of Selected Questions . 18 Supplementary Questions . 21 3 Back into the Ring 23 Chapter Summary . 23 Learning Objectives . 24 Teaching Notes . 24 v vi CONTENTS Reading Quiz Questions . 25 Questions for Class Discussion . 27 Discussion of Selected Questions . 29 Supplementary Questions . 36 Appendix A: Why Sequential Pairwise Voting Is Monotone, and Instant Runoff Is Not . 37 4 Trouble in Democracy 39 Chapter Summary . 39 Typographical Error . 40 Learning Objectives . 40 Teaching Notes . 40 Reading Quiz Questions . 41 Questions for Class Discussion . 42 Discussion of Selected Questions . 43 Supplementary Questions . 49 5 Explaining the Impossible 51 Chapter Summary . 51 Error in Question 5.26 . 52 Learning Objectives . 52 Teaching Notes . 53 Reading Quiz Questions . 54 Questions for Class Discussion . 54 Discussion of Selected Questions . 55 Supplementary Questions . 59 6 One Person, One Vote? 61 Chapter Summary . 61 Learning Objectives . 62 Teaching Notes . 62 Reading Quiz Questions . 63 Questions for Class Discussion . 65 Discussion of Selected Questions . 65 CONTENTS vii Supplementary Questions . 71 7 Calculating Corruption 73 Chapter Summary . 73 Learning Objectives . 73 Teaching Notes .
    [Show full text]
  • The Case for a Commonwealth Anti-Corruption And
    Closing the Gap: The Case for a Commonwealth Anti-Corruption and Misconduct Commission Brian Toohey Australasian Study of Parliament Group 2013 Conference: Perth, 2 – 4 October 2013 Commonwealth politicians and public servants want us to believe they differ from other mortals. They claim to be so incorruptible — unlike their state and local government counterparts — that they don’t need a watchdog. Even suspect state officials, it seems, are immune to temptation once they take a job in Canberra. The states either have, or are getting, formidable watchdogs to reduce the risk of corruption and misconduct among their officials. But the Gillard government in 2012 rejected a parliamentary committee’s recommendation that it should look at establishing a similar federal body. The commentators focused more attention on the lesser issue of whether federal politicians need a code of conduct after the alleged misdeeds of Labor’s Graig Thomson and the Liberal’s Peter Slipper. The general consensus seems it be that they don’t need oversight from a corruption body because “everyone knows right from wrong” — a not entirely reassuring claim in the circumstances. Although it was never clear why Australian Federal Police (AFP) was less susceptible to bribery than its state equivalents, the Howard government only established the Australian Commission for Law Enforcement Integrity (ACLEI) in 2006. The government confined the commission’s initial targets to the AFP, the Australian Crime Commission and Customs. While Labor’s justice minister, Jason Clare later added the quarantine service, AUSTRAC (the money tracking agency) and CrimTrac (the body that facilitates information sharing between various police and security agencies).
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3 Voting Systems
    Chapter 3 Voting Systems 3.1 Introduction We rank everything. We rank movies, bands, songs, racing cars, politicians, professors, sports teams, the plays of the day. We want to know “who’s number one?” and who isn't. As a lo- cal sports writer put it, “Rankings don't mean anything. Coaches continually stress that fact. They're right, of course, but nobody listens. You know why, don't you? People love polls. They absolutely love ’em” (Woodling, December 24, 2004, p. 3C). Some rankings are just for fun, but people at the top sometimes stand to make a lot of money. A study of films released in the late 1970s and 1980s found that, if a film is one of the 5 finalists for the Best Picture Oscar at the Academy Awards, the publicity generated (on average) generates about $5.5 mil- lion in additional box office revenue. Winners make, on average, $14.7 million in additional revenue (Nelson et al., 2001). In today's inflated dollars, the figures would no doubt be higher. Actors and directors who are nominated (and who win) should expect to reap rewards as well, since the producers of new films are eager to hire Oscar-winners. This chapter is about the procedures that are used to decide who wins and who loses. De- veloping a ranking can be a tricky business. Political scientists have, for centuries, wrestled with the problem of collecting votes and moulding an overall ranking. To the surprise of un- 1 CHAPTER 3. VOTING SYSTEMS 2 dergraduate students in both mathematics and political science, mathematical concepts are at the forefront in the political analysis of voting procedures.
    [Show full text]
  • Minimax Is the Best Electoral System After All
    1 Minimax Is the Best Electoral System After All Richard B. Darlington Department of Psychology, Cornell University Abstract When each voter rates or ranks several candidates for a single office, a strong Condorcet winner (SCW) is one who beats all others in two-way races. Among 21 electoral systems examined, 18 will sometimes make candidate X the winner even if thousands of voters would need to change their votes to make X a SCW while another candidate Y could become a SCW with only one such change. Analysis supports the intuitive conclusion that these 18 systems are unacceptable. The well-known minimax system survives this test. It fails 10 others, but there are good reasons to ignore all 10. Minimax-T adds a new tie-breaker. It surpasses competing systems on a combination of simplicity, transparency, voter privacy, input flexibility, resistance to strategic voting, and rarity of ties. It allows write-ins, machine counting except for write-ins, voters who don’t rate or rank every candidate, and tied ratings or ranks. Eleven computer simulation studies used 6 different definitions (one at a time) of the “best” candidate, and found that minimax-T always soundly beat all other tested systems at picking that candidate. A new maximum-likelihood electoral system named CMO is the theoretically optimum system under reasonable conditions, but is too complex for use in real-world elections. In computer simulations, minimax and minimax-T nearly always pick the same winners as CMO. Comments invited [email protected] Copyright Richard B. Darlington May be distributed free for non-commercial purposes 2 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Labour Intellectuals in Australia: Modes, Traditions, Generations, Transformationsã
    IRSH 50 (2005), pp. 1–26 DOI: 10.1017/S002085900400183X # 2005 Internationaal Instituut voor Sociale Geschiedenis Labour Intellectuals in Australia: Modes, Traditions, Generations, Transformationsà Terry Irving and Sean Scalmer Summary: The article begins with a discussion of labour intellectuals as knowledge producers in labour institutions, and of the labour public in which this distinctive kind of intellectual emerges, drawing on our previously published work. Next we construct a typology of three ‘‘modes’’ of the labour intellectual that were proclaimed and remade from the 1890s (the ‘‘movement’’ the ‘‘representational’’, and the ‘‘revolutionary’’), and identify the broad historical processes (certification, polarization, and contraction) of the labour public. In a case study comparing the 1890s and 1920s we demonstrate how successive generations of labour intellectuals combined elements of these ideal types in different ways to develop traditions of intellectual work. The article concludes with a sketch of the labour public after the crisis of the 1920s. It considers the rise of the ‘‘militant’’ intellectual in the 1930s, the role of publicists, planners and experts in the 1940s, the skill of ‘‘generalship’’ in the polarized 1940s and 1950s, the failure to meet the challenge of the new social movements in the 1970s, and the decline of the agitational, movement-identified intellectual. Australians have often been described as an anti-intellectual people – almost as often as the labour movement has itself been dubbed with this dreaded sobriquet. The Australian labour movement would therefore appear to be a doubly marginal location for the thinker – an anti- intellectual fragment of an anti-intellectual culture. Appearances are not always deceptive.
    [Show full text]