US Economists on Argentina's Depression Of

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

US Economists on Argentina's Depression Of Ignorance and Influence: U.S. Economists on Argentina’s Depression of 1998-2002 by Kurt Schuler Econ Journal Watch, August 2005 Appendix 2: Quotations To document statements in the main text, I have quoted at length from some sources. Copyright remains with the copyright holders. Important words or phrases from the quotations are highlighted in yellow; some of my comments are highlighted in blue. Where no page number is given, the article in question was either just one page long or I viewed it through an electronic source, such as Nexis or a Web browser, that did not list page numbers. Pierre-Richard Agénor (Lead Economist and Director of Macroeconomics and Policy Assessment Skills Program, World Bank) “The key elements of the [Convertibility] plan consisted of a fixed exchange rate and a change in the central bank charter. The exchange rate was fixed at 10,000 Australes per dollar, and future exchange rate changes were required to authorized by congress, rather than left to the discretion of the central bank. The Austral was made fully convertible for both current and capital account transactions, and use of the U.S. dollar as unit of account and means of exchange was legalized. More importantly, the central bank was legally enjoined from printing money to issue credit to the government. Money could be printed only to purchase foreign exchange. In effect, this converted the Argentine central bank into a semi-currency board. [Footnote to last sentence above] Several loopholes in the central bank legislation actually gave the Argentine central bank powers beyond those of a pure currency board. Government dollar-denominated debt held by the central bank could be counted (up to a maximum amount) as foreign exchange reserves, and the central bank’s monetary liabilities were permitted to exceed its stock of foreign exchange reserves—by [a] maximum of 20 percent from 1991 to 1995, and 33 percent subsequently—in exceptional circumstances, a measure that was intended to permit the bank to cope with financial distress in the domestic banking system. However, except during the Tequila crisis of 1995 (described below) the foreign exchange cover of the central bank’s monetary liabilities was maintained at 100 percent.” Agénor and Montiel (1999, pp. 386-7) Robert Z. Aliber (professor of international economics and finance, University of Chicago) “’As long as Brazil’s currency was slightly overvalued, Argentine firms weren’t having difficulties in Brazil. Now they are,’ said Robert Aliber, an international economist at the University of Chicago.” Aliber (1999) “Argentina’s attempt to link its peso one-to-one with the U.S. dollar has effectively failed after a 10-year attempt. The economic policy was a ‘fiscal disaster’ said Robert Aliber, professor 1 at University of Chicago’s Graduate School of Business, because of the mismatched exchange ratio. “’In some sense this has been a widely anticipated event,’ he said. To that end, U.S. institutions should be positioned to weather the effects.” Aliber (2001) “In effect, [under a currency board] the central bank gives up any semblance of monetary independence; the money supply increases when the country has a payments surplus and falls when the country has a payments deficit.” Aliber (2002, p. 9) (Aliber does not describe any particular country as having a currency board.) Mark Allen (deputy director, Policy Development and Review Department, International Monetary Fund; deputy director during Argentine crisis) “In most cases, downward adjustment in nominal wages and prices is slow, politically difficult, painful, and leads to a reduction in real growth (as evidenced by Argentina’s difficulties in implementing such policies under the constraints of its currency board.) … “Similarly, Argentina more recently introduced capital controls in combination with a freeze on bank deposits when exiting from its currency board arrangement and suspending payments on its sovereign debt.” Allen, Rosenberg, Keller, Setser, and Roubini (2002, pp. 29, 33) “The plan adopted in 1991 centered on the establishment of as firm a nominal exchange rate as possible, i.e., a currency board peg to the US dollar, macroeconomic policies consistent with this anchor, and a sweeping structural reform programme.” … “The Convertibility Law, involving most of the elements of a currency board,…. However, exchange rate-based stabilizations have a number of costs, including the danger that the residual inflation will push the real exchange rate to a point that it endangers competitiveness.” Allen (2003, pp. 121, 122-3) David E. Altig (vice president and director of research, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland) “In 1991, Argentina established a currency board that fixed a one-for-one exchange rate between pesos and the U.S. dollar. To guarantee free conversion at this rate, the Convertibility Law that established the currency board requires Argentina’s central bank to back the peso monetary base fully with reserves dominated in U.S. dollars or in currencies easily converted into dollars. The central bank holds these reserves as dollar-denominated deposits or other interest-bearing instruments. “Although the new monetary institution created by the Convertibility Law is not a pure currency board, such an unadulterated arrangement is a useful benchmark from which to begin thinking about Argentina’s monetary structure. The monetary base of a country with a pure, dollar-backed currency board can change in response to adjustments in U.S. monetary policy, to shifts in overall demand for dollars, or to swings in the worldwide distribution of dollars. Holding all else constant, for example, a U.S. monetary expansion would raise the U.S. price level relative to the Argentine price level and put downward pressure on the peso price of dollars. To defend its peg, the Argentine currency board would trade pesos for dollars, effectively expanding its own monetary base in concert with the change in the supply of dollars. 2 “Though not a pure currency board, Argentina’s arrangement ties its monetary policy to that of the United States. By 1995, its inflation rate approached U.S. levels. By adopting a currency board, Argentina traded monetary independence for the credibility associated with Federal Reserve policies. … “Argentina contemplated these problems [of the tradeoff between rules versus discretion in monetary policy] when instituting its monetary reforms and, in contrast to a pure currency board, elected to retain some latitude for discretionary policies. The central bank may, for instance, hold up to one-third of its reserves in dollar-denominated Argentine government bonds, but it may not increase its holding of these bonds by more than 10 percent over the previous year’s average (except in emergencies and then only with congressional approval). Although the government has never used this provision, transacting in Argentine government debt allows the central bank to alter the monetary base.” Altig and Humpage (1999, pp. 2-3) “Even at the height of success, however, there were indications that the currency board was not an absolute panacea. The perception that the peso remained a relatively risky bet was hard to shake, and investors in peso-denominated securities demanded higher interest rates as compensation for bearing this risk. What’s more, the magnitude of the risk premia tended to be quite volatile, suggesting that the economy remained susceptible to speculative attack. “In January 1999, then-President Carlos Menem proposed complete dollarization, in effect eliminating the peso entirely. Although dollarization would have had little technical advantage over the existing currency board arrangement, many proponents of dollarization argued that markets had retained some residual doubt about the long-run viability of the board, doubts that only complete elimination of a circulating peso would vanquish. “But the drive for dollarization was not to be, and the fears that the currency board would prove unstable were all too prophetic. As of February 11, the peso was wholly untethered from the dollar, and the last vestiges of the currency board, in the process of being dismantled since late last year, were finally reduced to rubble. “The advocates of dollarization may have seen it coming. Argentina had begun the recession from which it has yet to recover in mid-1998, as fears mounted that the faltering Brazilian economy would place irreparable strains on the Argentine economy. The problems of the country, however, appear to be more fundamental than the details of its monetary arrangements. Writing in the January 9 edition of the Wall Street Journal, the Cato Institute's Brink Lindsey quoted a survey conducted by Harvard University and the World Economic Forum’s 2000 Global Competitiveness Report showing that, of 59 countries studied, Argentina ranks ‘40th in frequency of irregular payments to government officials; 54th in the independence of the judiciary; 55th [in] litigation costs; 45th for corruption of the legal system; and 54th in the reliability of police protection.’ (The questions of the survey were asked such that high numbers are bad.) “These statistics reveal an overwhelming fault in Argentina’s political infrastructure. It is not surprising that truly independent central banking could not be sustained in such an environment. As if to underscore the point, the disintegration of the currency board took shape in May 2001 when Fernando de la Rua dismissed Pedro Pou, the central bank governor, for resisting attempts to weaken the country’s promise of peso parity with the dollar. “In the case of Argentina, the reforms that gave rise to the currency board were not sufficient in the absence of broader institutional reform. But that fact should not mislead us into 3 the false belief that long-term prosperity can be achieved in Argentina (or any country) without a strong, stable, and credible monetary standard. A currency board, dollarization, or the like may not be a sufficient condition for prosperity, but it is certainly a necessary one.” Altig (2002a, p.
Recommended publications
  • Restoring Economic Growth in Argentina
    マーク色指定C10M100Y100 JBICI Research Paper No. 27 Restoring Economic Growth in Argentina January 2004 JBIC Institute Japan Bank for International Cooperation JBICI Research Paper No.27 Restoring Economic Growth in Argentina January 2004 JBIC Institute Japan Bank for International Cooperation JBICI Research Paper No. 27 Japan Bank for International Cooperation (JBIC) Published in January 2004 © 2004 Japan Bank for International Cooperation All rights reserved. This Research Paper is based on the findings and discussions of the JBIC. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the official position of the JBIC. No part of this Research Paper may be reproduced in any form without the express permission of the publisher. For further information please contact the Planning and Coordination Division of our Institute. Foreword About two years have passed since Argentina faced the onset of what Dr. Cline calls the 3D economic collapse: default, devaluation, and depression. In 2002 the country’s GDP contracted by 11 per cent, the worst on its record. Despite the substantial depreciation of the peso, however, hyperinflation was successfully avoided. And more recently the economy has shown a substantial recovery, particularly in the manufacturing sector. On the other hand, there has been no significant progress in the banking sector reform, which is listed by Dr. Cline as a key challenge for immediate future. Furthermore, the prospects remain opaque for the sovereign debt restructuring, which Dr. Cline deems crucial for reestablishing Argentina’s credit reputation and eventual capacity to return to credit markets. After the introduction chapter, the Chapter 2 of this paper surveys the arguments on the main cause of the 3D collapse.
    [Show full text]
  • BANCO MACRO S.A. (Incorporated in the Republic of Argentina) Global Medium-Term Note Program
    BASE PROSPECTUS US$700,000,000 BANCO MACRO S.A. (incorporated in the Republic of Argentina) Global Medium-Term Note Program We may from time to time issue notes in one or more series under our Global Medium-Term Note Program. The maximum aggregate principal amount of all notes we may have outstanding under this program at any time is limited to US$700,000,000 (or its equivalent in other currencies). We will describe the specific terms and conditions of each series of notes in a Final Terms. Notes issued under this program may: • be denominated in U.S. dollars or another currency or currencies; • have maturities of no less than 30 days from the date of issue; • bear interest at a fixed or floating rate or be issued on a non-interest bearing basis; and • provide for redemption at our option or at the holder’s option. We may redeem all, but not part, of a series of notes, at our option, upon the occurrence of specified Argentine tax events at a price equal to 100% of the principal amount plus accrued and unpaid interest. Unless otherwise specified in the Final Terms applicable to a series of notes, the notes will constitute our direct, unconditional, unsecured and unsubordinated obligations and will rank at all times at least pari passu in right of payment with all our other existing and future unsecured and unsubordinated indebtedness (other than obligations preferred by statute or by operation of law). We may apply to have the notes of a series listed on the Luxembourg Stock Exchange for trading on the Euro MTF, the market of the Luxembourg Stock Exchange, and listed on the Buenos Aires Stock Exchange (Bolsa de Comercio de Buenos Aires).
    [Show full text]
  • Vulnerability and Contagion Risks... Fragile Vs. Anti-Fragile Countries
    Discussion Paper I CROSS ASSET Investment Strategy DP-40-2019 Emerging Markets: Vulnerability and contagion risks... Fragile vs. anti-fragile countries Document for the exclusive attention of professional clients, investment services providers and any other professional of the financial industry Emerging Markets: Vulnerability and contagion risks... Fragile vs. anti-fragile countries*/** PHILIPPE Abstract ITHURBIDE Global Head his article is aimed at analysing contagion of Research Twithin the emerging world in the past decades, and at presenting investment strategies with the collaboration of to limit negative effects of contagion and / or to MICKAËL benefit from it. BELLAÏCHE Senior Analyst, We first analyse nine very different cases of Global Research contagion (crises and sharp declines without crisis, with different triggers, with different contagion effects) which could be identified in the emerging world over the last 40 years: i) the Latin American debt crisis of the 1980’s, ii) the Mexican crisis of 1994, iii) the Asian Crisis of 1997, iv) the Russian Crisis of 1998, v) the Brazilian crisis of 1999, vi) the Argentine crisis of 1999-2001, vii) Fed tapering of QE in 2013, viii) the “boom and burst”crisis in Chinese stock markets in 2015-2016, and ix) restrictive trade and monetary policies in the United States in 2018. (*) A first version of this article has been prepared for an Amundi advisory board meeting (24 October 2018). The author wishes to thank all participants for their valuable comments. (**) This discussion paper is part of a pack of 3 articles on EM economies and EM markets. One of the three deals with the typology of EM economies (how to discriminate EM countries and EM markets), and another one deals with the hard and soft power of EM countries and with the question of leadership (US vs.
    [Show full text]
  • University of California Berkeley Department of Economics
    - - _ University of California Berkeley CENTER FOR INTERNATIONAL AND DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS RESEARCH Working Paper No. C93-009 Patterns in Exchange Rate Forecasts for 25 Currencies Menzie Chinn and Jeffrey Frankel January 1993 Department of Economics WITHDRAWN POU. AGRICULTURAL N OM CL. LIBRARY MAR 1 !' ben CIDER t CENTER FOR INTERNATIONAL AND DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS RESEARCH The Center for International and Development Economics Research is funded by the Ford Foundation. It is a research unit of the Institute of International Studies which works closely with the Department of Economics and the Institute of Business and Economic Research. CIDER is devoted to promoting research on international economic and development issues among Berkeley CIDER faculty and students, and to stimulating collaborative interactions between them and scholars from other developed and developing countries. INSTITUTE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH Richard Sutch, Director The Institute of Business and Economic Research is an organized research unit of the University of California at Berkeley. It exists to promote research in business and economics by University faculty. These working papers are issued to disseminate research results to other scholars. Individual copies of this paper are available through IBER, 156 Barrows Hall, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720. Phone (510) 642-1922, fax (510) 642-5018. UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT BERKELEY Department of Economics Berkeley, California 94720 - ,CENTER FOR INTERNATIONAL AND DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS RESEARCH Working Paper No. C93-009 Patterns in Exchange Rate Forecasts for 25 Currencies Menzie Chinn and Jeffrey Frankel January 1993 Key words: expectations, survey, forward rate, exchange rate JEL Classification: F31, 015 Abstract The properties of exchange rate forecasts are investigated, with a data set encompassing a broad cross section of currencies.
    [Show full text]
  • Stochastic Discount Factor Approach to International Risk-Sharing: Evidence from Fixed Exchange Rate Episodes
    Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Utrecht School of Economics Utrecht University Janskerkhof 12 3512 BL Utrecht The Netherlands telephone +31 30 253 9800 fax +31 30 253 7373 website www.koopmansinstitute.uu.nl The Tjalling C. Koopmans Institute is the research institute and research school of Utrecht School of Economics. It was founded in 2003, and named after Professor Tjalling C. Koopmans, Dutch-born Nobel Prize laureate in economics of 1975. In the discussion papers series the Koopmans Institute publishes results of ongoing research for early dissemination of research results, and to enhance discussion with colleagues. Please send any comments and suggestions on the Koopmans institute, or this series to [email protected] ontwerp voorblad: WRIK Utrecht How to reach the authors Please direct all correspondence to the first author. Metodij Hadzi-Vaskov Utrecht University Utrecht School of Economics Janskerkhof 12 3512 BL Utrecht The Netherlands. E-mail: [email protected] Clemens J.M. Kool Utrecht University Utrecht School of Economics Janskerkhof 12 3512 BL Utrecht The Netherlands. E-mail: [email protected] This paper can be downloaded at: http://www.koopmansinstitute.uu.nl Utrecht School of Economics Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Discussion Paper Series 07-33 Stochastic Discount Factor Approach to International Risk-Sharing: Evidence from Fixed Exchange Rate Episodes Metodij Hadzi-Vaskov Clemens J.M. Kool Utrecht School of Economics Utrecht University March 2008 Abstract This paper presents evidence of the stochastic discount factor approach to international risk-sharing applied to fixed exchange rate regimes.
    [Show full text]
  • International Borrowing and Macroeconomic Performance in Argentina
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Capital Controls and Capital Flows in Emerging Economies: Policies, Practices and Consequences Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-18497-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/edwa06-1 Conference Date: December 16-18, 2004 Publication Date: May 2007 Title: International Borrowing and Macroeconomic Performance in Argentina Author: Kathryn M. E. Dominguez, Linda L. Tesar URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c0156 7 International Borrowing and Macroeconomic Performance in Argentina Kathryn M. E. Dominguez and Linda L. Tesar 7.1 Introduction In the early 1990s Argentina was the darling of international capital markets and viewed by many as a model of reform for emerging markets. Early in his presidency, Carlos Menem embarked on a bold set of economic policies, including the adoption of a currency board that pegged the Ar- gentine peso to the dollar, a sweeping privatization program for state- owned enterprises, an overhaul of the banking system, and privatization of the public pension system. The business press marveled over the rapid turnaround in the Argentine economy. Although there were some concerns about the appropriateness and sustainability of the dollar anchor and whether the fiscal reforms were more rhetoric than reality, the policies ap- peared to have conquered inflation and set the country on a course of steady economic growth. By the end of the 1990s, however, Argentina’s situation had dramatically changed. The country had weathered the financial crises in Mexico and Asia, and, despite the volatility of capital flows, Argentina’s currency board remained intact and forecasts of future growth were relatively posi- tive.
    [Show full text]
  • Growth,Instability and the Convertibility Crisis in Argentina
    CEPAL CEPALREVIEW REVIEW 77 • AUGUST 77 2002 25 Growth, instability and the convertibility crisis in Argentina José María Fanelli Centro de Estudios de Estado The Argentine economy is currently going through the y Sociedad (CEDES), Buenos Aires deepest and most prolonged recession of the postwar period: [email protected] a devastating panorama that contrasts vividly with its significant growth in 1991-1998. In this article we will analyse the macroeconomic dimensions of the crisis which led to the abandonment of convertibility. Firstly, we will identify some structural weaknesses of the Argentine economy that are a source of macroeconomic instability. In particular, we will study the role of the imperfect access to international capital markets, the limited openness, the lack of financial depth and the nominal and policy rigidities, as well as the role of the errors in expectations and volatility. Secondly, we will examine the sequence of disturbances (shocks) in 1998-1999, concluding that the simultaneity of many of them aggravated their effects and that, under the convertibility régime, the economy was not prepared to face such consequences. Finally, we will briefly outline the policies that the country should apply in order to restore macroeconomic and financial stability. GROWTH, INSTABILITY AND THE CONVERTIBILITYAUGUST CRISIS2002 IN ARGENTINA • JOSÉ MARÍA FANELLI 26 CEPAL REVIEW 77 • AUGUST 2002 I Introduction The Argentine economy is currently undergoing the capacity is roughly the same as in late 1998, when the deepest and longest recessionary process of the postwar recession began. We frequently hear people saying period. This process began in late 1998 and, as time “How can this be happening if there was no war that passed and the successive stabilization attempts failed, destroyed our productive capacity!” the agents increasingly perceived that the country was In a nutshell, if we were to assume that per capita entering the obscure realm of economic depression.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomía Del Desarrollo
    62 S E R I E I R E S macroeconomía del desarrollo Equilibrium real exchange rates, misalignment and competitiveness in the Southern Cone Peter J. Montiel Economic Development Division Santiago Chile, Dec ember 2007 This document was prepared by Peter J. Montiel, consultant of the Economic Development Division, Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC). The views expressed in this document, which has been reproduced without formal editing, are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Organization. United Nations Publication ISSN printed version 1680-8843 ISSN online version 1680-8851 ISBN: 978-92-1-121653-0 LC/L.2850-P Sales No.: E.07.II.G.174 Copyright © United Nations , December 2007. All rights reserved Printed in United Nations, Santiago de Chile Applications for the right to reproduce this work are welcomed and should be sent to the Secretary of the Publications Board, United Nations Headquarters New York, N.Y. 10017, U.S.A. Member States and their governmental institutions may reproduce this work without prior authorization, but are requested to mention the source and inform the United Nations of such reproduction. CEPAL - SERIE Macroeconomía del desarrollo N° 62 Contents Abstract ........................................................................................5 I. Introduction ................................................................................7 II. Sustainability in the real exchange rate ......................... 11 III. Fundamental determinants of equilibrium
    [Show full text]
  • Regulationist Macro-Models for Developing Countries. an Application to the Argentine New Development Pattern
    Panigo, Demian Tupac; Chena, Pablo Ignacio Regulationist Macro-Models for Developing Countries. An Application to the Argentine New Development Pattern Revue de la régulation 2012, nro. 11 Panigo, D.; Chena, P. (2012). Regulationist Macro-Models for Developing Countries. An Application to the Argentine New Development Pattern. Revue de la régulation (11). En Memoria Académica. Disponible en: http://www.memoria.fahce.unlp.edu.ar/art_revistas/pr.11195/pr.11195.pdf Información adicional en www.memoria.fahce.unlp.edu.ar Esta obra está bajo una Licencia Creative Commons Atribución-NoComercial-SinDerivadas 4.0 Internacional http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ Regulationist Macro-Models for Developing Cou... https://journals.openedition.org/regulation/9705 Revue de la régulation Capitalisme, institutions, pouvoirs Maison des Sciences de l'Homme - Paris Nord 11 | 1er semestre / Spring 2012 : Les capitalismes en Amérique latine. De l'économique au politique Dossier : Les capitalismes en Amérique latine. De l'économique au politique Regulationist Macro-Models for Developing Countries. An Application to the Argentine New Development Pattern Modèles macroéconomiques régulationistes pour des pays émergeant. Une application au nouveau mode du développement argentin Modelos macroeconómicos regulacionistas para países en desarrollo. Una aplicación al nuevo modelo de desarrollo argentino DEMIAN TUPAC PANIGO ET PABLO IGNACIO CHENA Résumés English Français Español In this paper we present a regulationst structural macroeconometric model (RSMM) to develop economic forecasts and examine different policy outcomes in Argentina. RSMM main characteristics involve cumulative causation dynamics where income distribution, macroeconomic volatility, credit rationing and productive heterogeneity conjugates to obtain a new instrument to precisely examine key macroeconomic and social variables.
    [Show full text]
  • Pdfthe Argentine Experience
    What Lessons Can Be Learned from Recent Financial Crises? The Argentine Experience Pedro Pou Unfortunately, Argentina has an abundant history of financial crises. The only advantage I can see from this painful experience is that it means that occasionally I get invitations to extremely interesting events such as this one, and I must congratulate the organizers for putting together such an excellent program in such a beautiful place. I will just mention three episodes of Argentina’s recent financial experience and try to draw from them the main lessons as I see them: (1) the banking crisis of 1982, (2) the hyperinflationary experience of 1989-90, and (3) the banking crisis of 1995. These three crises are so different, that understanding them should aid in our understanding of financial crises in general. The 1980-82 crisis might be referred to as a crisis of “generalized moral hazard” and was similar to the 1989 crisis in that they were both clearly crises of solvency. However, the main difference was that while the 1980-82 crisis was due to the insolvency of the private sector, the 1989 crisis was due to government insolvency. Finally, the 1995, or “tequila” crisis, was a totally different kind of crisis, since it was a crisis of liquidity not of solvency. The 1980-82 banking crisis: generalized moral hazard It has been suggested by many that the crisis of 1982 was provoked 141 142 Pedro Pou in large part due to inconsistent macroeconomic policies applied in the period before the crisis and, in particular, to inconsistent fiscal and exchange rate policies.1 However, although the macroeconomic policy stance was cer- tainly a contributory factor, Fernández (1983) has argued forcefully that the problems were amplified by the inherent instability of the financial system.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberal Globalization and the Argentine Great Depression: Deconstructing the Discourses of the IMF and Private Finance
    Introduction Neoliberal globalization and the Argentine Great Depression: deconstructing the discourses of the IMF and private finance By Christian Hernandez A thesis submitted to the University of Birmingham for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science and International Studies College of Social Sciences The University of Birmingham November 2017 Word count: 79,734 University of Birmingham Research Archive e-theses repository This unpublished thesis/dissertation is copyright of the author and/or third parties. The intellectual property rights of the author or third parties in respect of this work are as defined by The Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 or as modified by any successor legislation. Any use made of information contained in this thesis/dissertation must be in accordance with that legislation and must be properly acknowledged. Further distribution or reproduction in any format is prohibited without the permission of the copyright holder. Abstract Despite the waning prominence of the vast and diverse literature on globalization, the debate remains unresolved, as globalization’s logics continue to buttress neoliberal economics (Hay & Smith, 2013; Smith, 2005). As Cameron and Palan posited thirteen years ago, “the spread of globalization in practice continues unabated” (2004). Of importance herein is how neoliberal globalization is understood, as a concept and in material terms (Marsh, 2009), as well as how it has spread spatiotemporally (Peck & Tickell, 2012). Contributing to constructivist globalization scholarship, this thesis argues that ideas are central to how “material reality” or “globalization in practice” is shaped and understood (Schmidt, 2013). Henceforth, it interrogates the space for alternatives to globalization’s logics by focusing on the ways ideas shape policy and normative understandings by (respectively) examining the IMF-Argentine consultations (1976-2006), and the discourses of the financial press (1997-2006).
    [Show full text]
  • Documentos De Trabajo
    UNIVERSIDAD DEL CEMA Buenos Aires Argentina Serie DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO Área: Economía e Historia A BRIEF HISTORY OF HYPERINFLATION IN ARGENTINA Emilio Ocampo Abril 2021 Nro. 787 www.cema.edu.ar/publicaciones/doc_trabajo.html UCEMA: Av. Córdoba 374, C1054AAP Buenos Aires, Argentina ISSN 1668-4575 (impreso), ISSN 1668-4583 (en línea) Editor: Jorge M. Streb; asistente editorial: Valeria Dowding [email protected] A Brief History of Hyperinflation in Argentina Emilio Ocampo* Abstract A fiscal deficit of 8.5% of GDP, limited access to credit locally and internationally, country risk premiums at default levels and money supply growing at 80% annually, have led some analysts to predict that Argentina might be heading into a ―3-digit modern hyperinflation.‖ Although this opinion is not widely held, the consensus inflation forecast for 2021 is 47%, a level significantly below any definition of hyperinflation but high by global standards (above the 98th percentile). Even more worrisome, over the last decade inflation has shown a persistent upward trend and since January 2019 has averaged 45%. Given all of the above, it is worthwhile investigating when Argentina experienced it and why. This paper attempts to answer the first part of this question. According to a widely accepted view there was only one hyperinflation between 1989 and 1990. This paper argues that Argentina experienced four hyperinflationary episodes that were part of a long-term cycle that started in 1945. Keywords: Argentina, Inflation, Extreme Inflation, Hyperinflation. JEL Codes: E31, N16 Resumen Un déficit fiscal de 8,5% del PBI, acceso limitado al crédito local e internacional, una prima de riesgo país que implica una alta probabilidad de cesación de pagos y una oferta monetaria que crece a una tasa anual de 80%, han llevado a algunos analistas a sostener que la Argentina se encamina a una "hiperinflación moderna de 3 dígitos".
    [Show full text]