“Irrationality During the Pandemic”

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

“Irrationality During the Pandemic” Final paper in: Pandemics in an Unequal World: Learning from COVID19 On the subject: “Irrationality during the Pandemic” by Panagiotis Paris Hiotis Professor: Sakiko Fukuda-Parr Fall 2020 Table of Contents Abstract 2 Introduction 2 The dual system theory 4 1. Action bias 5 2. Affect heuristic 6 3. Choice overload/Decision fatigue/Ego depletion 6 4. Confirmation bias 8 5. Framing effect 8 6. Halo effect 10 7. Messenger bias 11 8. Optimism bias - Overconfidence 12 9. Present bias 13 10. Social proof – Herding 14 11. Scarcity heuristic 15 12. Status quo bias 16 Nudges 17 Conclusion 19 Bibliography 20 1 Abstract In this paper, I will be examining the most common cognitive biases that are responsible for the many irrational behaviors that have taken place during the Covid-19 pandemic. I will be discussing irrationality during the pandemic, through the lens of the following biases and other heuristics: Action bias, affect heuristic, choice paralysis, confirmation bias, framing effect, halo effect, messenger effect, optimism bias - overconfidence, present bias, social proof – herding behavior, scarcity, status quo bias and defaults. I will also be mentioning the importance of nudges as well as how people take advantage of dark nudges (sludges) during these times of uncertainty. Examples will be given for irrational behavior caused by each of the following behavioral economics concepts, with some information on how to overcome these cognitive biases. Introduction In the past year, the Covid-19 pandemic has claimed many lives, and we have all faced many challenges. Amidst the chaos, certain actions gained attention and were labeled as “irrational”, examples including the hoarding of toilet paper1, increased spending and panic buying of products2, or simply not adhering to the protective measures and having large concerts and 1 https://eu.azcentral.com/story/opinion/op-ed/elviadiaz/2020/11/11/another-toilet-paper-shortage-hoarding- wont-save-you-covid-19/6250934002/ 2 https://voxeu.org/article/spending-dynamics-and-panic-buying-during-covid-19-first-wave 2 gatherings without any usage of masks and with no implementation of social distancing3. This behavior seems illogical, but with the help of behavioral science and behavioral economics, we have the necessary tools to dissect it, explain what causes it, and discuss how we can avoid similar irrational acts. In 1950s, Herbert Simon, utilized the term “bounded rationality”, by explaining that the human brain has a limit in terms of thinking capacity, information storing and processing. Forcing us to use certain heuristics, or mental shortcuts, to make some of our decisions. Heuristics4 are mental shortcuts, or commonly known as “rules of thumb”, that we utilize in order to simplify our decisions and take out some of the cognitive load of everyday thinking. Some of these heuristics include the availability heuristic, the affect heuristic and representativeness. Even though the aforementioned heuristics help with simplifying our decision-making process, they often are responsible for leading us to what is known as a cognitive bias. Cognitive biases are systematic errors in thinking that deviate from the rational perspective of formal norms. These can affect how we make decisions and judgements. The field of behavioral economics studies these heuristics and biases in order to explain economic decision making. The case behavioral economics makes is that humans are less rational and selfish than the traditional economic theory suggest (e.g., homo economicus5) due to being limited by bounded rationality and self-control issues. 3 https://www.francetvinfo.fr/sante/maladie/coronavirus/une-fete-de-la-musique-sans-trop-de-precautions-pour- oublier-le-coronavirus_4017437.html 4 https://www.verywellmind.com/what-is-a-heuristic-2795235 5https://www.oecd.org/economy/homo-economicus-an-uncertain-guide.htm 3 The dual system theory In his 2011 bestselling book, “Thinking, fast and slow”, Daniel Kahneman, makes the distinction of two systems of thinking in the human mind. Kahneman makes the case of a “fast”, intuitive system 1 that makes simple and easy decisions, with little thinking involved and utilizes impressions, intuitions, and a “slow” and deliberate system 2 that makes calculating informed decisions, by taking into account different data and options. An accurate example of the use of system 1 and 2 would be that of driving a car. The first few times we drive, our brain painstakingly stresses over every detail and deliberately focuses on every decision we make, using system 2. After we familiarize ourselves with the task, it becomes automatic and effortless, meaning it now utilizes system 1. System 1 is also the source of the aforementioned heuristics and biases discussed above, as the brain makes certain automated thoughts, and forms impressions instinctively through the utilization of the intuitive system 1. This is done to avoid cognitive strain and to leave space for what our brain considers more important mental tasks. Many of the biases and heuristics we will be analyzing shortly, are all products of such unconscious thinking that derives from system 1, while in order to recognize the bias and make a more informed and rational decision, we would have to use our system 2. We will now begin our detailed examination of the different biases and heuristics that are responsible for the irrational behavior during the pandemic. The effects will be presented in alphabetical order. 4 1. Action bias This bias refers to the belief that performing an action gives people a certain amount of control over a specific situation. This bias is the opposite of another form of bias we will be discussing later on, the status quo bias that takes into account inertia and focuses on people’s tendency to stay in a certain situation and not act. Action bias takes the opposite approach and focuses on the illusion of control that such an action would create. An example of irrational behavior during the Covid-19 pandemic would be the tendency to stockpile on food and supplies, despite reassurances from experts that there is no danger of shortage. People choosing to over exaggerate, and stockpile food, medicine and other products deemed necessary during the pandemic such as masks and disinfectant gel, believe that by their action they will be better prepared against the unknown dangers of the pandemic, even though in reality the excessive queuing at supermarkets and other stores is putting them at further risk of contracting the disease. Fighting the action bias is challenging, as the sense of security and reassurance provided by hoarding and stockpiling food and other useful resources is an evolutionary trait that has existed in humans since their inception. At the same time, it is important to realize that scarcity of certain products is only going to be self- created, as more and more people fall prey to this bias and thus create shortages (e.g., toilet paper). By being a more rational consumer, while listening to the experts ensuring that there will be no shortage under normal conditions, such effects can be mitigated. 5 2. Affect heuristic The affect heuristic represents a relation between a reaction and the feelings caused by the said reaction. These feelings are quick and impulsive and thus dominated by our system 1 thinking. People tend to consider benefits of a behavior they like as high and the risks as low, whereas for a behavior they dislike they consider the benefits as low and the risks as high. The affect heuristic is dependent on a quick decision with little to no information or supplementary research on a subject. This behavior can affect the way that people react to medical procedures and treatments. In relation to Covid-19, the affect heuristic can have major influence on the adherence of Covid- 19 related measures such as mask-wearing, social distancing and hand washing. The association for example of not adhering to the Covid-19 related measures with contracting the disease can create a negative affect towards not adhering, thus pushing more people to comply with the necessary health measures. In the same light, creating a positive feeling in regard to being at home with family, can cause an increase in people staying indoors to help reduce the spread of the virus. Taking advantage of the affect heuristic and creating negative or positive emotions towards certain measures or behaviors, can prove of vital importance in fighting the virus. 3. Choice overload/Decision fatigue/Ego depletion In this section, we will be looking at choice overload, decision fatigue and ego depletion, as these three phenomena can justify the information overload that occurs as a result of the many information campaigns for Covid-19. Choice overload is based on studies that show how the existence of many difference choices, often paralyzes the consumer (decision paralysis) where 6 they choose to not take any action instead. In his book “The paradox of choice”, Barry Swartz mentions the “jam experiment”6 where consumers were more likely to make a purchase when there were 6 kinds of jam offered to them, than when there were 24. Certainly, the condition with 24 different kinds attracted more consumers, but fewer decided to finalize the purchase of a product. Decision fatigue refers to the psychological cost of making decisions and how long sessions of decision making can have a negative effect and produce bad choices. In the same vein, ego depletion, makes a case of a limited amount of self-control that works in the same way a muscle does. Tiring out the muscle can weaken our ability to exercise self-control, make safer choices and stay away from impulse. Studies conducted by the Behavioral Insights Team show the impact that too much information can have on Covid-19 related behavior. A randomized controlled trial (RCT) in Bangladesh 7 monitoring proper hand washing techniques, clearly reflects that information overload can have a negative effect on Covid -19 safety measures.
Recommended publications
  • Critical Thinking and Debiasing: Experimentation in an Academic Writing Course
    JAPAN ASSOCIATION FOR LANGUAGE TEACHING JALT2019 • TEACHER EFFICACY, LEARNER AGENCY NOVEMBER 1–4, 2019 • NAGOYA, JAPAN Critical Thinking and Debiasing: Experimentation in an Academic Writing Course esearch and interest in cognitive heuristics (shortcuts in thinking) and cognitive Guy Smith R biases (thinking predispositions or tendencies) has grown rapidly in the past 10 to 15 years. What is known about cognitive biases today owes much to work drawn from International Christian University behavioral economics, social psychology, decision making, and error studies. Recently, the cognitive bias discussion has found a much wider audience with the publication John Peloghitis of popular science books such as Nudge by Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein (2008), International Christian University Predictably Irrational by Dan Ariely (2009), Daniel Kahneman’s Thinking, Fast and Slow (2011), and Robert Cialdini’s Pre-suasion (2016). These books provided the general public with a fascinating and, in some ways, unsettling look into how we think. The Reference Data: research demonstrated that judgments and decisions often emerge from taking thinking Smith, G., & Peloghitis, J. (2020). Critical thinking and debiasing: Experimentation in an academic shortcuts, relying on our intuitions and feelings, and attending to certain stimuli while writing course. In P. Clements, A. Krause, & R. Gentry (Eds.), Teacher efficacy, learner agency. ignoring others. Some of the biases that emerge from these cognitive processes include Tokyo: JALT. https://doi.org/10.37546/JALTPCP2019-51 confirmation bias (to look for or interpret information that confirms a previous belief), in- group bias (a tendency to favor members of your in-groups) and the aptly named ostrich In the last two decades, interest in cognitive biases has rapidly grown across various fields of effect (the tendency to ignore negative situations).
    [Show full text]
  • Contingent Reliance on the Affect Heuristic As a Function of Regulatory Focus
    Contingent Reliance on the Affect Heuristic as a Function of Regulatory Focus Michel Tuan Pham Tamar Avnet Results from four studies show that the reliance on affect as a heuristic of judgment and decision-making is more pronounced under a promotion focus than under a prevent ion focus. Two different manifestations of this phenomenon were observed. Studies 1–3 show that different type s of affective inputs are weighted more heavily under promotion than under prevention in person-impression formation, product evaluations, and social recommendations. Study 4 additionally shows that valuations performed under promotion are more scope- insensitive—a characteristic of affect-based valuations—than valuations performed under prevention. The greater reliance on affect as a heuristic under promotion seems to arise because promotion-focused individuals tend to find affective inputs more diagnostic, not because promotion increases the reliance on peripheral information per se. Although decision research has historically focused affective responses to make judgments and decisions, on the cognitive processes underlying decision making, to begin with? a growing body of research from multiple disciplines The purpose of this research is to test the suggests that affective processes play an important role hypothesis that an important determinant of the as well. In particular, there is strong evidence that reliance on affect as a heuristic for evaluations and decisions are often based on subjective affective decisions is the self-regulatory orientation of the responses to the options, which appear to be seen as decision-maker. Building on recent findings by Pham indicative of the options’ values (Bechara, Damasio, and Avnet (2004), we propose that the reliance on Tranel, & Damasio, 1997; Loewenstein, Weber, Hsee, affect as an evaluation heuristic is more pronounced & Welch, 2001; Pham, 1998; Schwarz & Clore, 1983).
    [Show full text]
  • A Task-Based Taxonomy of Cognitive Biases for Information Visualization
    A Task-based Taxonomy of Cognitive Biases for Information Visualization Evanthia Dimara, Steven Franconeri, Catherine Plaisant, Anastasia Bezerianos, and Pierre Dragicevic Three kinds of limitations The Computer The Display 2 Three kinds of limitations The Computer The Display The Human 3 Three kinds of limitations: humans • Human vision ️ has limitations • Human reasoning 易 has limitations The Human 4 ️Perceptual bias Magnitude estimation 5 ️Perceptual bias Magnitude estimation Color perception 6 易 Cognitive bias Behaviors when humans consistently behave irrationally Pohl’s criteria distilled: • Are predictable and consistent • People are unaware they’re doing them • Are not misunderstandings 7 Ambiguity effect, Anchoring or focalism, Anthropocentric thinking, Anthropomorphism or personification, Attentional bias, Attribute substitution, Automation bias, Availability heuristic, Availability cascade, Backfire effect, Bandwagon effect, Base rate fallacy or Base rate neglect, Belief bias, Ben Franklin effect, Berkson's paradox, Bias blind spot, Choice-supportive bias, Clustering illusion, Compassion fade, Confirmation bias, Congruence bias, Conjunction fallacy, Conservatism (belief revision), Continued influence effect, Contrast effect, Courtesy bias, Curse of knowledge, Declinism, Decoy effect, Default effect, Denomination effect, Disposition effect, Distinction bias, Dread aversion, Dunning–Kruger effect, Duration neglect, Empathy gap, End-of-history illusion, Endowment effect, Exaggerated expectation, Experimenter's or expectation bias,
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Session 17
    42nd Annual National Conference of Regulatory Attorneys Nashville, Tennessee May 5-8, 2019 Outline & Materials Session 17 - Bridge Over Troubled Water: The Arch of Ethics It is easy to fall into ethically-troubled waters. Here, a series of lively skits will show us some of the daily challenges facing attorneys who practice before the fictitious Nirvana Public Utility Commission. The situations portrayed leave us to question: Will these lawyers slip into the muddy waters or steady themselves by clinging to the Model Rules of Professional Conduct? Legal Instruction: Richard Collier, Esq. Skit Production: Eve Moran, Esq. _________________________________________________________________________ Skit I - Things Are Jumping At The Bluebird Bar & Grill Resources: Ex Parte Statutes - Tennessee (Tenn. Code Ann. § 4-5-304) Model Rule 3.5 A lawyer shall not: (a) seek to influence a judge, juror, prospective juror or other official by means prohibited by law; (b) communicate ex parte with such a person during the proceeding unless authorized to do so by law or court order; (c) communicate with a juror or prospective juror after discharge of the jury if: (1) the communication is prohibited by law or court order; (2) the juror has made known to the lawyer a desire not to communicate; or (3) the communication involves misrepresentation, coercion, duress or harassment; or (d) engage in conduct intended to disrupt a tribunal. Model Rule 8.4 It is professional misconduct for a lawyer to: (a) violate or attempt to violate the Rules of Professional Conduct,
    [Show full text]
  • Identifying Present Bias from the Timing of Choices∗
    Identifying Present Bias from the Timing of Choices∗ Paul Heidhues Philipp Strack DICE Yale February 22, 2021 Abstract A (partially naive) quasi-hyperbolic discounter repeatedly chooses whether to com- plete a task. Her net benefits of task completion are drawn independently between periods from a time-invariant distribution. We show that the probability of complet- ing the task conditional on not having done so earlier increases towards the deadline. Conversely, we establish non-identifiability by proving that for any time-preference pa- rameters and any data set with such (weakly increasing) task-completion probabilities, there exists a stationary payoff distribution that rationalizes the agent's behavior if she is either sophisticated or fully naive. Additionally, we provide sharp partial identifica- tion for the case of observable continuation values. ∗We thank seminar and conference audiences, and especially Nageeb Ali, Ned Augenblick, Stefano DellaVigna, Drew Fudenberg, Ori Heffetz, Botond K}oszegi, Muriel Niederle, Philipp Schmidt-Dengler, Charles Sprenger, Dmitry Taubinsky, and Florian Zimmermann for insightful and encouraging comments. Part of the work on this paper was carried out while the authors visited briq, whose hospitality is gratefully acknowledged. Philipp Strack was supported by a Sloan fellowship. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3386017 1 Introduction Intuition and evidence suggests that many individuals are present-biased (e.g. Frederick et al., 2002; Augenblick et al., 2015; Augenblick and Rabin, 2019). Building on work by Laibson (1997) and others, O'Donoghue and Rabin (1999, 2001) illustrate within the quasi-hyperbolic discounting model that present bias, especially in combination with a lack of understanding thereof, leads individuals to procrastinate unpleasant tasks and to precrastinate pleasant experiences.
    [Show full text]
  • The Art of Thinking Clearly
    For Sabine The Art of Thinking Clearly Rolf Dobelli www.sceptrebooks.co.uk First published in Great Britain in 2013 by Sceptre An imprint of Hodder & Stoughton An Hachette UK company 1 Copyright © Rolf Dobelli 2013 The right of Rolf Dobelli to be identified as the Author of the Work has been asserted by him in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means without the prior written permission of the publisher, nor be otherwise circulated in any form of binding or cover other than that in which it is published and without a similar condition being imposed on the subsequent purchaser. A CIP catalogue record for this title is available from the British Library. eBook ISBN 978 1 444 75955 6 Hardback ISBN 978 1 444 75954 9 Hodder & Stoughton Ltd 338 Euston Road London NW1 3BH www.sceptrebooks.co.uk CONTENTS Introduction 1 WHY YOU SHOULD VISIT CEMETERIES: Survivorship Bias 2 DOES HARVARD MAKE YOU SMARTER?: Swimmer’s Body Illusion 3 WHY YOU SEE SHAPES IN THE CLOUDS: Clustering Illusion 4 IF 50 MILLION PEOPLE SAY SOMETHING FOOLISH, IT IS STILL FOOLISH: Social Proof 5 WHY YOU SHOULD FORGET THE PAST: Sunk Cost Fallacy 6 DON’T ACCEPT FREE DRINKS: Reciprocity 7 BEWARE THE ‘SPECIAL CASE’: Confirmation Bias (Part 1) 8 MURDER YOUR DARLINGS: Confirmation Bias (Part 2) 9 DON’T BOW TO AUTHORITY: Authority Bias 10 LEAVE YOUR SUPERMODEL FRIENDS AT HOME: Contrast Effect 11 WHY WE PREFER A WRONG MAP TO NO
    [Show full text]
  • Retention and Transfer of Cognitive Bias Mitigation Interventions: a Systematic Literature Study
    SYSTEMATIC REVIEW published: 12 August 2021 doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2021.629354 Retention and Transfer of Cognitive Bias Mitigation Interventions: A Systematic Literature Study J.E. (Hans) Korteling, Jasmin Y. J. Gerritsma and Alexander Toet* Netherlands Organisation for Applied Scientific Research (TNO) Human Factors, Soesterberg, Netherlands Cognitive biases can adversely affect human judgment and decision making and should therefore preferably be mitigated, so that we can achieve our goals as effectively as possible. Hence, numerous bias mitigation interventions have been developed and evaluated. However, to be effective in practical situations beyond laboratory conditions, the bias mitigation effects of these interventions should be retained over time and should transfer across contexts. This systematic review provides an overview of the literature on retention and transfer of bias mitigation interventions. A systematic search yielded 52 studies that were eligible for screening. At the end of the selection process, only 12 peer-reviewed studies remained that adequately studied retention over a period of at least 14 days (all 12 studies) or transfer to different tasks and contexts (one study). Edited by: Eleven of the relevant studies investigated the effects of bias mitigation training using Rick Thomas, Georgia Institute of Technology, game- or video-based interventions. These 11 studies showed considerable overlap United States regarding the biases studied, kinds of interventions, and decision-making domains. Most Reviewed by: of them indicated that gaming interventions were effective after the retention interval and Elizabeth Veinott, that games were more effective than video interventions. The study that investigated Michigan Technological University, United States transfer of bias mitigation training (next to retention) found indications of transfer across Dan Diaper, contexts.
    [Show full text]
  • Addressing Present Bias in Movie Recommender Systems and Beyond
    Addressing Present Bias in Movie Recommender Systems and Beyond Kai Lukoffa aUniversity of Washington, Seattle, WA, USA Abstract Present bias leads people to choose smaller immediate rewards over larger rewards in the future. Recom- mender systems often reinforce present bias because they rely predominantly upon what people have done in the past to recommend what they should do in the future. How can recommender systems over- come this present bias to recommend items in ways that match with users’ aspirations? Our workshop position paper presents the motivation and design for a user study to address this question in the domain of movies. We plan to ask Netflix users to rate movies that they have watched in the past for thelong- term rewards that these movies provided (e.g., memorable or meaningful experiences). We will then evaluate how well long-term rewards can be predicted using existing data (e.g., movie critic ratings). We hope to receive feedback on this study design from other participants at the HUMANIZE workshop and spark conversations about ways to address present bias in recommender systems. Keywords present bias, cognitive bias, algorithmic bias, recommender systems, digital wellbeing, movies 1. Introduction such as Schindler’s List [2]. Recommender systems (RS), algorithmic People often select smaller immediate re- systems that predict the preference a user wards over larger rewards in the future, a would give to an item, often reinforce present phenomenon that is known as present bias bias. Today, the dominant paradigm of rec- or time discounting. This applies to deci- ommender systems is behaviorism: recom- sions such as what snack to eat [1,2], how mendations are selected based on behavior much to save for retirement [3], or which traces (“what users do”) and they largely ne- movies to watch [2].
    [Show full text]
  • Mechanisms in Risky Choice Framing
    Mechanisms in Risky Choice Framing Affective Responses and Deliberative Processing Liva Jenny Martinussen Master of Philosophy in Psychology, Cognitive Neuroscience Department of Psychology University of Oslo April 2016 II Mechanisms in Risky Choice Framing: Affective Responses and Deliberative Processing By Liva Jenny Martinussen Department of Psychology UNIVERSITY OF OSLO III © Liva Jenny Martinussen 2016 Mechanisms in Risky Choice Framing: Affective responses and Deliberative Processing Author: Live Jenny Martinussen http://www.duo.uio.no/ IV Summary Author: Liva Jenny Martinussen Supervisors: Anine Riege (Supervisor) and Unni Sulutvedt (Co-Supervisor) Title: Mechanisms in Risky Choice Framing: Affective Responses and Deliberative Processing Background: The risky choice framing effect is a decision making bias, where people tend to be risk-averse when options are presented as gains and risk-seeking when options are presented as losses, although the outcomes are objectively equivalent. The mechanisms involved in risky choice framing effects are still not fully understood. Several individual differences are assumed to moderate the processing of framing tasks and the magnitude of framing effects. Objectives: The aim of the current study was to investigate the framing effect across six framing task in a within-subject design, and explore whether gain and loss frames were associated with different levels of affective responses and deliberative processing. An additional aim was to investigate how individual differences in emotion management ability and numeracy affected performance and processing of framing tasks. Method: The study was an independent research project and the author collected all the data. Eye-tracking technology was employed; number of fixations, duration of fixations, repeated inspections of options and pupil dilations were recorded from 80 predominantly young adults while performing on six framing tasks.
    [Show full text]
  • Infographic I.10
    The Digital Health Revolution: Leaving No One Behind The global AI in healthcare market is growing fast, with an expected increase from $4.9 billion in 2020 to $45.2 billion by 2026. There are new solutions introduced every day that address all areas: from clinical care and diagnosis, to remote patient monitoring to EHR support, and beyond. But, AI is still relatively new to the industry, and it can be difficult to determine which solutions can actually make a difference in care delivery and business operations. 59 Jan 2021 % of Americans believe returning Jan-June 2019 to pre-coronavirus life poses a risk to health and well being. 11 41 % % ...expect it will take at least 6 The pandemic has greatly increased the 65 months before things get number of US adults reporting depression % back to normal (updated April and/or anxiety.5 2021).4 Up to of consumers now interested in telehealth going forward. $250B 76 57% of providers view telehealth more of current US healthcare spend % favorably than they did before COVID-19.7 could potentially be virtualized.6 The dramatic increase in of Medicare primary care visits the conducted through 90% $3.5T telehealth has shown longevity, with rates in annual U.S. health expenditures are for people with chronic and mental health conditions. since April 2020 0.1 43.5 leveling off % % Most of these can be prevented by simple around 30%.8 lifestyle changes and regular health screenings9 Feb. 2020 Apr. 2020 OCCAM’S RAZOR • CONJUNCTION FALLACY • DELMORE EFFECT • LAW OF TRIVIALITY • COGNITIVE FLUENCY • BELIEF BIAS • INFORMATION BIAS Digital health ecosystems are transforming• AMBIGUITY BIAS • STATUS medicineQUO BIAS • SOCIAL COMPARISONfrom BIASa rea• DECOYctive EFFECT • REACTANCEdiscipline, • REVERSE PSYCHOLOGY • SYSTEM JUSTIFICATION • BACKFIRE EFFECT • ENDOWMENT EFFECT • PROCESSING DIFFICULTY EFFECT • PSEUDOCERTAINTY EFFECT • DISPOSITION becoming precise, preventive,EFFECT • ZERO-RISK personalized, BIAS • UNIT BIAS • IKEA EFFECT and • LOSS AVERSION participatory.
    [Show full text]
  • Poverty and Decision-Making
    Poverty and decision-making How behavioural science can improve opportunity in the UK Kizzy Gandy, Katy King, Pippa Streeter Hurle, Chloe Bustin and Kate Glazebrook October 2016 1 © Behavioural Insights Ltd Acknowledgements Many people contributed to this report. Particular thanks go to David Halpern, Andy Hollingsworth, Raj Chande, Tiina Likki, Ben Curtis and Susannah Hume from the Behavioural Insights Team who provided expert advice on the literature and policy context. Many people inside government also provided review, and several leading academic were an invaluable source of insights and knowledge, particularly Eldar Shafir, Jonathan Morduch and Evrim Altintas. Finally, we thank the Joseph Rowntree Foundation for providing useful guidance along the way and for their enthusiasm and support for our intellectual ambition. 2 © Behavioural Insights Ltd Contents Glossary of terms ............................................................................................. 6 Executive summary ............................................................................................ 7 Chapter 1 - Introduction: applying behavioural science to the study of poverty .... 11 Section 1.1 Background and principal audiences for the report .................. 11 Section 1.2 Report aims and research questions ....................................... 11 Section 1.3 The psychology of decision-making ........................................ 12 Section 1.4 Structure of the report .......................................................... 14 Chapter 2
    [Show full text]
  • Health Insurance & Behavioral Economics
    Health Insurance & Behavioral Economics Alan C. Monheit, Ph.D. Rutgers University School of Public Health Rutgers Center for State Health Policy National Bureau of Economic Research Standard Model Underlying Consumer Choice • In the standard economic model of consumer choice, individuals are characterized as “. lightning quick calculators of pleasure and pain.” • Built on very strong behavioral assumptions: – Rationality – Full information on attributes of commodities and their substitutes. – Easy to assess the benefits & costs of consumption alternatives. – Individuals are constrained by a budget. – More choice is welfare enhancing. • These assumptions of rationality & full information carry over to the standard or benchmark model of health insurance choice. Center for State Health Policy Benchmark Model of Health Insurance Choice • Key assumptions: – Individuals are risk averse: • Prefer a loss with certainty rather than a gamble with the same expected loss. • Will incur a certain loss to obtain an uncertain flow of benefits. • Are willing to pay a “risk premium” above an actuarially fair insurance premium. – Can accurately assess the probability of future losses. – Can accurately assess income losses from adverse events. – Can accurately assess the benefits & costs of purchasing or not purchasing insurance. Center for State Health Policy Implications from the Standard Model • Value of the standard model is that it provides testable predictions about health insurance choices: – More risk averse individuals will purchase more insurance than those who are less risk averse. – Generally, as the probability of a loss increases, individuals will purchase more insurance. However, • Individuals will not purchase insurance for very large or very small probabilities of income loss. – More insurance is purchased as the expected income loss increases.
    [Show full text]