Research at the University of California Transportation Center

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Research at the University of California Transportation Center Research at the University of California Transportation Center SPRING 1999 NUMBER 14 CONTENTS A CCESS No. 14 Spring 1999 2 Middle Age Sprawl: BART and Urban Development BY JOHN LANDIS AND ROBERT CERVERO 16 Access to Choice BY JONATHAN LEVINE 20 Splitting the Ties: The Privatization of British Rail BY JOSE´ A. GOMEZ´ -IBAÑEZ´ 26 Objects In Mirror Are Closer Than They Appear BY THEODORE E. COHN 32 Recent Papers in Print 41 THE ACCESS ALMANAC: Gas Tax Dilemma BY MARY HILL, BRIAN TAYLOR, AND MARTIN WACHS The University of California Transportation Center, founded in 1988, facilitates research, education, and public service for the entire UC system. Activities have centered on the Berkeley, Davis, Irvine, Los Angeles, Riverside, and Santa Barbara campuses. University of California Transportation Center 108 Naval Architecture Building Berkeley, CA 94720–1720 Tel: 510-643-5454 Fax: 510-643-5456 [email protected] http://socrates.berkeley.edu/~uctc Copyright © 1999 The Regents of the University of California Authors of papers reporting on UCTC research are solely responsible for their content. This research was sponsored by the US Department of Transportation and the California Department of Transportation, neither of which is liable for its content or use. Front Cover: Iron Oxide Magnified (2500X). Courtesy General Motors Research and Development Center. EDITORIAL The Land Use/Transportation Connection (cont’d) ACK IN THE 1950S and 1960S, a basic aim for the newly a higher level of region-wide accessibility. The additional proposed BART system was to curb urban sprawl. The accessibility at BART stations was but a small increment and Btrick was to reinforce major metropolitan centers and hence largely inconsequential. create new suburban subcenters. Because land adjacent to (2) In the absence of numerous transit riders living or BART’s station sites would be highly accessible, its planners working at stations, these sites are less attractive to real-estate expected they’d be powerful magnets attracting offices, shops, investors than are dispersed and spacious sites readily acces- and high-density housing. Those concentrations would make sible by automobile. for culturally enriched residential life and a more viable local (3) Unlike Metro’s complex network of intracity lines, economy. In turn, they’d attract riders to BART and thus help BART is essentially a suburban commuter railroad with two reduce traffic congestion. main lines reaching to outlying stations. Those stations are Our mid-’70s assessments of promised land use effects largely surrounded by paved lots offering free parking and were pessimistic, but probably premature, because land use occupying much of the adjacent land. changes are slow to show up. Now, some two decades later, it (4) As Jonathan Levine explains in his accompanying is possible to assess BART’s influence on Bay Area develop- article, so long as land use regulations continue to limit ment with greater precision and confidence. locational choice for families and businesses, the land market John Landis and Robert Cervero have conducted a new can’t respond to induce desired urban and travel patterns. series of land use studies around BART lines and stations, and Suburban centers along Washington Metro’s lines are they summarize their findings here. Their conclusions confirm direct products of active engagement by local governments those of the earlier assessment: Downtown San Francisco’s collaborating with private land developers. Together, they office employment has indeed expanded dramatically near changed land use regulations, exploited urban-redevelopment BART stations, but there has been only modest development options, created joint-development enterprises, and forged tax around other stations—whether urban, suburban, or exurban. and other financial incentives that encouraged high-density They find BART has had little influence on the location of either housing and high-rise office buildings. Metro thus became an population or employment. Indeed, growth rates were lowest in effective instrument for city-building. those suburban corridors served by BART, and suburban office In contrast, it seems that BART saw itself primarily as a construction favored places that lack BART service. railroad rather than as an agent of urban development. So it Patronage has also fallen short of expectations. Initial fore- didn’t actively work with local governments to change the casts expected 258,500 daily riders in 1975. Now, 24 years later zoning, or with real-estate developers and financial institutions and after a 30 percent increase in population, there may not yet to build at stations. The absence of intensive suburban centers be even that many riders on the original lines. then translated into too few riders. In turn, BART’s low patron- Metropolitan areas around the country have been building age was little inducement to concentrated suburban develop- or extending rail systems and, with some notable exceptions, ment. In further turn, continued low density meant continued experiencing similarly disappointing patronage and urbaniza- low patronage. tion effects. One exception is Washington’s Metro, whose Our experience here suggests it’s not enough just to install Orange Line route into Virginia is now a rapidly urbanizing rail transit. It should now be apparent that we can’t rely on corridor with a series of new, high-density subcenters trains alone to restructure the land market so that it sponta- surrounding stations. Although BART is several years older, neously induces desired urban forms or attracts sufficient nothing resembling such dense concentrations has emerged riders. Once again, events have exposed the intrinsic interde- near its suburban stations (see photos on page 12). pendencies between land use and transportation, showing that Four explanations may account for the differences. we can’t treat the one without the other. (1) At the outset, more auto ownership and an extensive network of highways and freeways endowed the Bay Area with Melvin M. Webber MIDDLE AGE SPRAWL: BART and Urban Development BY JOHN LANDIS AND ROBERT CERVERO ART was the first American rail rapid transit system voters in Alameda, Contra Costa, and San Francisco counties. to be built in modern times, and its arrival was If, as many city planners and transit advocates believe, transit greeted with worldwide attention. BART is famous. investments like BART can substantially alter metropolitan devel- BIts fame is attached to its favorable image as the opment patterns, then transit’s role as “growth shaper” should be answer to the problems of the modern American metropolis. explicitly considered when making transit investment decisions. And the extent to which it has succeeded, or failed, to live up to If, on the other hand, transit’s effects on growth and urban form expectations is an important lesson for other cities wanting to are only marginal, then decisions regarding transit investments emulate it. should be primarily made either to relieve congestion or to BART is now middle-aged and certainly widely recognized enhance accessibility. as a part of the San Francisco Bay Area, but is it an important part? We wish here to summarize the results of a series of Do people in the Bay Area live and work in different locations and inquiries into BART’s effects on Bay Area growth and urban form, in different ways than they would if BART were not there? Can we undertaken as part of the BART@20 project. (Similar studies point to housing projects, office buildings, shopping centers, or were undertaken in the mid-1970s as part of the initial BART public buildings that would not have been built, or neighbor- Impact Study.) We review BART planners’ initial expectations hoods that would not have been revitalized but for BART’s regarding the system’s effects on the Bay Area and ask how presence? Does BART provide more people with more accessi- transit investments influence urban development. We explore bility to economic and social opportunities than they would BART’s effects on regional population and employment patterns, otherwise enjoy? Would the Bay Area without BART be the same residential and office-construction activity near BART stations, place it is today? the quality of BART’s influence on land use change and redevel- The answers to these questions may be more important opment, and BART’s effects on home prices, office rents, patron- today than in 1962, when BART’s construction was approved by age, and retail sales volume. John Landis and Robert Cervero are professors of city and regional planning at the University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720-1850 ([email protected] and [email protected]). Research assistants on the BART@20 and related projects were Carlos Castellanos, Bruce Fukuji, Wicaksono Sarosa, Will Huang, Subro Guhathakurta, David Loutsenheiser, Sourev Sen, and Ming Zhang. A C C E S S 2 INITIAL EXPECTATIONS AND PROCESSES OF CHANGE Third, BART would serve as a catalyst promoting redevelop- Initial Expectations ment and reinvestment in older areas of Oakland, Berkeley, and The politicians, planners, and business and civic leaders who Richmond, while promoting higher-density residential and advocated building BART in the 1950s and 1960s did so expect- mixed-use development in growing suburban jurisdictions. ing that BART would affect Bay Area development patterns in BART’s success in meeting this last objective would depend on three related ways. First and foremost, BART would relieve supportive land use
Recommended publications
  • American Capitalism
    AC/No.1/March 2016 American Capitalism STATES, NOT NATION: THE SOURCES OF POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT IN THE EARLY UNITED STATES Naomi R. Lamoreaux and John Joseph Wallis Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and Study of Business Enterprise States, Not Nation: The Sources of Political and Economic Development in the Early United States Naomi R. Lamoreaux, Yale University and NBER John Joseph Wallis, University of Maryland and NBER September 2015 Abstract: General histories of the United States focus almost exclusively on developments at the national level. Yet it is well known that most of the important changes that propelled political democratization and economic modernization in the nineteenth century occurred at the state level. The purpose of this paper is to shift the focus of attention to the states without losing sight of the larger story of which they were a part. We accomplish this goal by reexamining aspects of economic development that the states are conventionally acknowledged to have led—the creation of a banking system, the construction of transportation infrastructure, the promotion of corporations—and show that these developments were part and parcel of a more fundamental institutional shift from a “limited access” to an “open access” social order, to borrow the terminology that Douglass North, John Wallis, and Barry Weingast developed for their book Violence and Social Orders (2009). The United States was not born modern at the time of the American Revolution or even the Constitution. Rather, we contend, the institutional prerequisites for political and economic modernization took shape over the course of the first half of the nineteenth century through a series of mutually reinforcing political and economic changes that occurred at the state level.
    [Show full text]
  • Research at the University of California Transportation Center
    Research at the University of California Transportation Center SPRING 1998 NUMBER 12 CONTENTS A CCESS No. 12 Spring 1998 2 Travel by Design? RANDALL CRANE 8 Traditional Shopping Centers RUTH L. STEINER 14 Simulating Highway and Transit Effects JOHN D. LANDIS 20 Cars for the Poor KATHERINE M. O’REGAN & JOHN M. QUIGLEY 26 Will Electronic Home Shopping Reduce Travel? JANE GOULD & THOMAS F. GOLOB 32 Recent Papers in Print The University of California Transportation Center, founded in 1988, facilitates research, education, and public service for the entire UC system. Activities have centered on the Berkeley, Davis, Irvine, Los Angeles, Riverside, and Santa Barbara campuses. University of California Transportation Center 108 Naval Architecture Building Berkeley, CA 94720–1720 Tel: 510-643-5454 Fax: 510-643-5456 [email protected] http://socrates.berkeley.edu/~uctc Copyright © 1998 The Regents of the University of California Authors of papers reporting on UCTC research are solely responsible for their content. This research was sponsored by the US Department of Transportation and the California Department of Transportation, neither of which is liable for its content or use. Front cover: Paris EDITORIAL Traditions and Neotraditions long-standing tradition has city planners in the role of a few of them. They describe changing commute patterns as creative designers of towns and cities. Perhaps that jobs move from central cities to suburbs. They ask how rail A role is best illustrated in the new town plans of Great transit might affect land use patterns. In turn, they ask how Britain with their carefully designed settings for modern life, Neotraditional land use patterns might affect daily travel complete with decent housing, spacious parks, nearby job behavior—how they might promote walking to shops, transit sites, and high-quality public facilities and services.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case for Discrimination
    THE CASE FOR DISCRIMINATION THE CASE FOR DISCRIMINATION WALTER E. BLOCK LVMI MISES INSTITUTE I owe a great debt of gratitude to Lew Rockwell for publishing this book (and for much, much more) and to Scott Kjar for a splendid job of editing. © 2010 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute and published under the Creative Commons Attribution License 3.0. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/ Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 mises.org ISBN: 978-1-933550-81-7 CONTENTS FORE W ORD B Y LLE W ELLYN H. ROCK W ELL , JR. vii PRE F ACE .. .xi PART ONE : DISCRIMINATION IS EVERY wh ERE . 1 1. Discrimination Runs Rampant . 3 2. Affirmative Action Chickens Finally Come Home to Roost. .6 3. Racism Flares on Both Sides. .9 4. Exclusion of Bisexual is Justified. 12 5. Catholic Kneelers . 14 6. Human Rights Commissions Interfere with Individual Rights. 16 7. Watch Your Language. .21 8. Sexist Advertising and the Feminists . 24 9. No Males Need Apply. .27 10. We Ought to Have Sex Education in the Schools. 29 11. Another Role for Women . 32 12. Female Golfer. 35 13. Silver Lining Part IV: Term Limits and Female Politicians. 38 14. Arm the Coeds. .42 15. Free Market Would Alleviate Poverty and Strengthen Family Relations. 46 16. Racism: Public and Private. 49 17. Stabbing the Hutterites in the Back. .52 PART TW O : TH E ECONOMICS O F DISCRIMINATION . .75 18. Economic Intervention, Discrimination, and Unforeseen Consequences. 77 19. Discrimination: An Interdisciplinary Analysis. 117 20.
    [Show full text]
  • New Jersey Historic Roadway Study B) Design
    You Are Viewing an Archived Copy from the New Jersey State Library You Are Viewing an Archived Copy from the New Jersey State Library Table of Contents TABLE of CONTENTS Acknowledgements . i Preface . vii I. Introduction . 1 II. Approach . 3 III. Methodology . 5 A. Stage I: Develop Historic Overview . 5 B. Stage II: Establish Historic Signifi cance . 5 C. Stage III: Identifi cation of Signifi cant Roadways . 6 D. Integrity Thresholds . 11 IV. Terms . 13 V. Roadways that Span Multiple Eras . 15 VI. Historic Contexts and Signifi cant Roads . 17 A. Early Roads Era (ca. 1621 - ca. 1815) . 17 1. Introduction . 17 2. Early Roads Era Historic Context . 17 a) Background . 17 b) Nature of Early Roads Era Traffi c . 23 c) Early Roads Era Road Technology . 23 d) Early Roads Era Administrative Innovation . 24 e) Conclusion . 25 3. Early Roads Era Signifi cant Routes . 26 a) Criteria for Signifi cance . 26 b) Signifi cant Routes . 26 4. Early Roads Era Associated Resources . 29 5. Early Roads Era Integrity Thresholds . 30 a) Location . 30 b) Design . 30 c) Materials . 30 d) Workmanship . 30 e) Setting . 30 f) Feeling . 31 g) Association . 31 6. Early Roads Era Timeline . 31 7. Research Questions . 33 B. Internal Improvements Era (ca. 1790 - ca. 1889) . 34 1. Introduction . 34 2. Internal Improvements Era Historic Context . 35 a) Background . 35 b) Nature of Internal Improvements Traffi c . 39 c) Technology . 39 d) Internal Improvements Era Administrative Innovation . 40 e) Conclusion . 41 3. Internal Improvements Era Signifi cant Routes . 42 a) Criteria for Signifi cance . 42 b) Signifi cant Routes .
    [Show full text]
  • Tr a N S P O Rtation Research at the University of California
    Tr a n s p o r tation Research at the University of California F A L L 2 0 0 0 N U M B E R 1 7 C O N T E N T S A C C E S S NO. 1 7 F A L L 2 0 0 0 2 Brooklyn’s Boulevards ELIZABETH MACDONALD 9 A Question of Timing ROSELLA PICADO 1 4 Taking Turns: Rx for Congestion CARLOS DAGANZO 2 0 What Can a Trucker Do? AMELIA REGAN 2 6 The Road Ahead: Managing Pa v e m e n t s SAMER MADANAT 4 0 TH E AC C E SS AL M A N AC: The Parking of Nations DONALD SHOUP AND SETH STA R K 3 0 Papers in Pr i n t 3 7 Order Fo r m 3 8 Back Issues The University of California Tr a n s p o rtation Center, founded in 1988, facilitates re s e a rch, education, and public service for the entire UC system. Activities have centered on the Berkeley, Davis, Irvine, Los Angeles, Riverside, and Santa Barbara campuses. University of California Tr a n s p o r tation Center B e r k e l e y, CA 94720–1782 Fax: 5 1 0 - 6 4 3 - 5 4 5 6 a c c e s s @ u c l i n k 4 . b e r k e l e y. e d u h t t p : / / s o c r a t e s . b e r k e l e y.
    [Show full text]
  • States, Not Nation: the Sources of Political and Economic
    States, Not Nation: The Sources of Political and Economic Development in the Early United States Naomi R. Lamoreaux, Yale University and NBER John Joseph Wallis, University of Maryland and NBER Abstract: General histories of the United States focus almost exclusively on developments at the national level. Yet it is well known that most of the important changes that propelled political democratization and economic modernization in the nineteenth century occurred at the state level. The purpose of this paper is to shift the focus of attention to the states without losing sight of the larger story of which they were a part. We accomplish this goal by reexamining aspects of economic development that the states are conventionally acknowledged to have led—the creation of a banking system, the construction of transportation infrastructure, the promotion of corporations—and show that these developments were part and parcel of a more fundamental institutional shift from a “limited access” to an “open access” social order, to borrow the terminology that Douglass North, John Wallis, and Barry Weingast developed for their book Violence and Social Orders (2009). The United States was not born modern at the time of the American Revolution or even the Constitution. Rather, we contend, the institutional prerequisites for political and economic modernization took shape over the course of the first half of the nineteenth century through a series of mutually reinforcing political and economic changes that occurred at the state level. These prerequisites emerged first in a small handful of states where, for highly contingent reasons, seemingly intractable problems implementing democracy were solved by changing the institutions governing the interaction of politics and economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Case Study: Road Pricing in Practice David Levinson University of California, Berkeley
    CALIFORNIA PATH PROGRAM INSTITUTE OF TRANSPORTATION STUDIES UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY Case Study: Road Pricing in Practice David Levinson University of California, Berkeley California PATH Research Report UCB-ITS-PRR-97-38 This work was performed as part of the California PATH Program of the University of California, in cooperation with the State of California Business, Transportation, and Housing Agency, Department of Transportation; and the United States Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration. The contents of this report reflect the views of the authors who are responsible for the facts and the accuracy of the data presented herein. The contents do not necessarily reflect the official views or policies of the State of California. This report does not constitute a standard, specification, or regulation. Report for MOU 275 November 1997 ISSN 1055-1425 Road Pricing in Practice Levinson Case Study: Road Pricing in Practice funded as part of MOU 275 by David M. Levinson Institute of Transportation Studies McLaughlin Hall, Rm. 109 University of California at Berkeley Berkeley, CA 94720 home (address mail here): David M. Levinson 1822 Francisco St. #11 Berkeley, CA 94703 [email protected] http://www.ce.berkeley.edu/~dmlevins/ (510) 848-3057 ABSTRACT The history of turnpikes from their first deployment in the 17th century through their decline in the 19th century, and some restoration in the 20th century is analyzed with a view to understanding the systematic causes of these changes. Key factors posited to explain both the rise and decline include the length of trips using the roads, the size of the governing jurisdiction, the degree of excludability, and the transactions costs of collection - which dictate the size and scope of the free rider problem associated with financing.
    [Show full text]
  • The Plank Roads of New York John Majewski Christopher Baer Daniel B. Klein August 19
    Market and Community in Antebellum America: The Plank Roads of New York John Majewski Christopher Baer Daniel B. Klein August 1991 Working Paper No. 47 TheUniversity of California TransportationCenter Universityof California Berkeley,CA 94720 The University of California Transportation Center The University of California Center activities. Researchers Transporlalioo Center (UCTC) at other universities within is one often regional units the region also have opportu- mandated by Congress and nities to collaborate on selec- established in Fall 1988 to ted studies. Currently faculty support research, education, at California Slate University, and training in surface trans- Long Beach, and at Arizona portation. The UC Center State University, Tempe, are serves federal Region IX and active participants. is supported by matching grants from the U.S. Depart- UCTC’seducational and ment of Transportation, the research programs are focused California State Department on strategic planning for of Transportation (Caltrans), improving metropolitan and tile University. accessibility, with emphasis on the special conditions in Based on the Berkeley Region IX. Particular attention Campus, UCTCdraws upon is directed to strategies for existing capabilities and using transportation as an resources of the Institutes of instrument of economic Transportation Studies at development, while also ac- Berkeley, Davis, and Irvine: commodating to the re- the Institute of Urban and gion’s persistent expansion Regional Development at and while maintaining and Berkeley; the Graduate enhancing the quality of School of Architecture and life there. Urban Planning at Los Angeles; and several aca- The Center distributes reports demic departments at tile on its research in working Berkeley, Davis, Irvine, and papers, monographs, and in Los Angeles campuses.
    [Show full text]
  • On Whom the Toll Falls: a Model of Network Financing by David Matthew Levinson B
    On Whom the Toll Falls: A Model of Network Financing by David Matthew Levinson B. (Georgia Institute of Technology) 1988 M. (University of Maryland) 1992 A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Engineering - Civil Engineering in the GRADUATE DIVISION of the UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY Committee in charge: Professor Mark M. Hansen, Chair Professor David Gillen Professor Carlos Daganzo Professor Elizabeth Deakin Spring 1998 The dissertation of David Matthew Levinson is approved: ________________________________________________________________________ Chair Date ________________________________________________________________________ Date ________________________________________________________________________ Date ________________________________________________________________________ Date University of California, Berkeley Spring 1998 On Whom the Toll Falls: A Model of Network Financing Copyright 1998 by David Matthew Levinson Abstract On Whom the Toll Falls: A Model of Network Financing by David Matthew Levinson Doctor of Philosophy in Civil Engineering University of California, Berkeley Professor Mark M. Hansen, Chair This dissertation examines why and how jurisdictions choose to finance their roads. The systematic causes of revenue choice are explored qualitatively by examining the history of turnpikes. The question is approached analytically by employing game theory to model revenue choice on a long road. The road is covered by a series of jurisdictions seeking to maximize local welfare. Jurisdictions are responsible for building and maintaining the local network. Complexity arises because local network users may not be local residents, and local residents may use non-local networks. Key factors posited to explain the choice of revenue mechanism include the length of trips using the road, the size of the governing jurisdiction, the degree of excludability, and the transaction costs of toll collection.
    [Show full text]
  • Greater Ability of Governments to Build and Maintain Public
    Ratio Working Paper No. 30 America’s Toll Roads Heritage: The Achievements of Private Initiative in the 19th Century Daniel B. Klein John Majewski Box 3203 Besöksadress: ratio.se 103 64 Stockholm Sveavägen 59, 4tr 0 America’s Toll Roads Heritage: The Achievements of Private Initiative in the 19th Century By Daniel B. Klein and John Majewski1 Abstract: Private toll roads shaped and accommodated trade and migration routes, leaving social and political imprints on the communities that debated and supported them. Private road building came and went in waves throughout the 19th century and across the country. All told, between 2,500 and 3,200 companies successfully financed, built, and operated their toll road. Although most of these roads operated for only a fraction of the 100+ period, the combined mileage of private toll roads that operated at any point in time would be in range of 30,000 to 52,000 miles. The paper explores the character, methods, and purposes of the private toll roads, and draws lessons for the privatization of highways today. JEL codes: N71, N91, L92. Keywords: toll roads, turnpikes, plank roads, privatization, free riding, regulation. Acknowledgements: The authors are grateful to Gabriel Roth, Alex Tabarrok, and Christopher Baer for many helpful comments, and to Bill Sundstrom and Alex Field for useful suggestions. The authors also acknowledge Christopher T. Baer, Chi Yin, and Gordon J. Fielding for their contributions to this paper by way of co-authoring works upon which it is partly based. 1 Daniel Klein, Department of Economics, Santa Clara University, Santa Clara, CA, 95053, and Ratio Institute, Stockholm, Sweden; Email: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • The Transportation Revolution
    Midterm Details You'll get your referee reports back at the end of class (I'll make some general comments right now) The top number is your score out of 10 on the summary section, the second number is your score out of 10 on the critiques, the third number is just your total score out of 20 You'll get midterms back on Tuesday The second referee report is due November 2 (on \A Nation of Immigrants: Assimilation and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass Migration" by Abramitzky, Boustan and Eriksson) J. Parman (College of William & Mary) American Economic History, Fall 2018 October 18, 2018 1 / 55 The Transportation Revolution J. Parman (College of William & Mary) American Economic History, Fall 2018 October 18, 2018 2 / 55 Transportation in the Early Nineteenth Century One of the big benefits the United States retained from British mercantalist policies was well developed ocean transportation Inland transportation was pretty much limited to navigable rivers (roads were terrible) What this meant was that port cities were in a position to thrive and grow right from the start For economic growth in the interior, better transportation would need to be developed to connect people living in the interior to markets J. Parman (College of William & Mary) American Economic History, Fall 2018 October 18, 2018 3 / 55 Transportation in the Early Nineteenth Century J. Parman (College of William & Mary) American Economic History, Fall 2018 October 18, 2018 4 / 55 Transportation in the Early Nineteenth Century Transportation Costs, 1815 Mode of Transportation Cost per Ton-Mile Road $0.30 River, Upstream $0.06 River, Downstream $0.01 Ocean <$0.01 J.
    [Show full text]
  • The Civil Engineering of Canals and Railways Before 1850 1St Edition Pdf, Epub, Ebook
    THE CIVIL ENGINEERING OF CANALS AND RAILWAYS BEFORE 1850 1ST EDITION PDF, EPUB, EBOOK Michael M Chrimes | 9781351892643 | | | | | The Civil Engineering of Canals and Railways before 1850 1st edition PDF Book Hixon for a number of years was supervisor of the Morris canal between Drakeville and Lincoln Park, but has not been connected with the canal for several years. Somewhere between 50 to 70 percent of these succeeded in building and operating toll roads. Ferrand : Lock Tender and Canal Collector. By , with the surname spelled Parliment, the family is living in Dover, Edward is listed with the occupation Engineer. No less important than plank road economics and technology were the public policy changes that accompanied plank roads. The estimates of success rates and average road length in the third and fourth columns are extrapolations from components that have been studied with more care. Slaght : Brakes on Plane Car. Private Horton participated on the July 18, assault on Ft. Private Everts death date and burial location are unknown. Throughout the 18th and 19th centuries, the lack of an efficient, safe transportation network kept populations - and trade - largely confined to coastal areas. The labor requirement could be avoided if the worker paid a fee of John Henry Peer : Boatman. When the Erie Canal was completed in it roughly followed the alignment of the upper route and greatly reduced travel on the competing turnpikes Baer, Klein, and Majewski Thomas Smith : Boatman. Born New Jersey, October, c. Jacob Palmer : Boatman Canal. In the face of exemptions and shunpiking, turnpike operators sometimes petitioned authorities for a toll hike, stiffer penalties against shunpikers, or the relocating of the toll gate.
    [Show full text]