Lessons from the Collapse of the Ruble Zone

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Lessons from the Collapse of the Ruble Zone Focus LESSONS FROM THE COLLAPSE tries, Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania, had already de- parted in August 1991. The formal division of the OF THE RUBLE ZONE Soviet Union occurred on 25 December 1991. It was clear-cut and rapid. Each new country kept all union ANDERS ÅSLUND* assets on its territory. The existing borders were rec- ognized and maintained. Russia accepted responsibil- When the Soviet Union collapsed in December 1991, ity for the Soviet Union’s substantial foreign debt, one single economic institution survived, namely the and assumed ownership of the far smaller foreign as- common currency, the ruble.1 The most radical Russian sets. Only two union institutions persisted, various reformers wanted to break it up, but they were defeat- Soviet military assets and the common currency, the ed by a multitude of opposing interest groups. As a re- ruble. sult, fifteen independent central banks started issuing ever larger ruble credits, which resulted in general hy- The Soviet economy had been out of control since the perinflation in 1992 and 1993, with annual inflation fourth quarter of 1990, as the Soviet economic system rates varying from 1,000–10,000 percent.2 In the fall of was falling apart. The economy suffered from all per- 1993, most countries left the ruble zone that ceased to ceivable ailments. Shortages of all goods and services exist when Russian departed. The countries that exited were pervasive, because of low state-regulated prices, the ruble the earliest, namely the Baltic states, per- while the government had lost control of both public formed the best, while the laggards suffered the most. expenditure and wages. Inflation was triple-digit, in spite of largely regulated prices and rationing was Many conditions at the end of ruble zone were pecu- wide. The Soviet budget deficit in 1991 was probably liar, but its collapse also displayed general features of 34 percent of GDP, but the Soviet national accounts a currency area. This extreme event can help us to dis- were not completed that year. The international cur- cern the mechanisms at work during the collapse of a rency reserves were literally depleted, and the USSR currency zone, especially when comparing with other had lost access to international financial markets be- similar events. Some of these developments are rele- cause of excessive public debt and large arrears. The vant for the Eurozone. Soviet economic system was collapsing, and GDP was falling by about 10 percent in 1991 (Åslund 1995 The first section of this article offers a brief presenta- and 2002). The situation was further complicated by tion of how the ruble zone collapsed. The second sec- the eleven newly-independent countries lacked cen- tion analyzes how the collapse of the ruble zone com- tral state institutions, notably central banks and min- pares with other currency zone failures. The third sec- istries of finance. The main problem, however, was tion draws overall lessons and specifically highlights probably a nearly complete dearth of economic points that matter for the Economic and Monetary knowledge everywhere apart from in Moscow and Union (EMU). Finally, what would happen if a debt- St. Petersburg. or country were to leave the Eurozone in distress? The curse of the ruble zone was that each of the 15 new republics had its own central bank that could What happened when the ruble zone collapsed? issue ruble credits. They had started doing so at the end of 1990, when the increasingly sovereign Soviet In December 1991, the Soviet Union broke up into republics established their central banks, but they twelve independent countries. The three Baltic coun- were caught in a prisoner’s dilemma. They would all be better off, if all of them restricted their issue of * The Atlantic Council, Wahington DC. money, but since they knew that the other central 1 I discussed this topic four years ago in Åslund (2012). 2 Hyperinflation is defined as inflation exceeding 50 percent a month banks would emit vast credits, none had a reason to for one month and the economy subsequently remaining in hyperin- flation for one year. hold back. CESifo Forum 4/2016 (December) 12 Focus An observer could have expected responsible politi- All of the former Soviet republics ended up on a tread- cians to stand up and call for an end to this hyperinfla- mill of rapid monetary expansion boosting inflation. tionary ruble zone, but its supporters overwhelmed its As prices surged, the velocity of money rose, so that opponents. The only people who really wanted to stop inflation increased more than monetary emission. the ruble zone were the Russian reformers around Inflation in the post-Soviet economies ranged from First Deputy Prime Minister Yegor Gaidar and the 640–3,000 percent in 1992, while in those economies Baltic leaders. In the fall of 1991, Gaidar (1993) had remaining in the ruble zone it ranged from 840– advocated a Russian ‘nationalisation of the ruble’. 11,000 percent in 1993. As hyperinflation caught on, The Western advisors of the Russian government con- GDP fell by 3–45 percent in 1992 alone. The Baltic curred, favouring a quick breakup of the ruble zone countries departed from the ruble zone in the summer (Lipton and Sachs 1993). This was also true of the of 1992, enabling them to restrain their credit issue. leading Western macroeconomists on this topic Even so, they faced inflation of around 1,000 percent (Sargent 1986) and Dornbusch (1992). in 1992, although that figure was much lower in 1993 (Åslund 2002). The post-Soviet republican leaders were painfully aware of their ignorance of monetary policy. The Not well-versed in monetary economics, post-Soviet countries most friendly to Russia – Belarus, Kazakhs - officials insisted that credits were not money, holding tan, Armenia, and Tajikistan – hoped for the survival back the printing of currency to impede inflation. The of the ruble zone and were prepared to submit to the printing presses were located only in Russia, which Russian central bank. The less friendly countries – started printing Russian rubles soon after independ- Ukraine, Moldova, Georgia, Azerbaijan, Turkmenis- ence. The other republics had to make do with their tan, and Uzbekistan – wanted to establish their own old Soviet ruble notes. Given that their printing had currencies, but after some time. In the meantime, they ended and prices skyrocket, cash was desperately wanted to benefit from cheap credit and raw materials short in supply. Several republics and regions started from Russia. The Balts took exception. They wanted printing their own coupons as a substitute currency. to establish their own national currencies and leave the While this was a great popular irritant, it was a side is- ruble zone as fast as possible, even if it would cost sue that did not have any great impact on monetary them greatly. Their saying went: “a national currency policy. is our best border fence to Russia” (Hansson 1993). Throughout the region, the old establishment fa- In the fall of 1992, the only one of the twelve coun- voured maintaining the ruble zone. The big state en- tries remaining in the ruble zone to hold back some- terprises wanted to sell without competition and be what was the Central Bank of Russia (CBR). Russia paid by the state through central bank credits. had current account surpluses with all of the other former Soviet republics, meaning that Russia provided Disappointingly, the international agencies involved financing to all of the other republics, which merely also preferred to keep the ruble zone. At this time, the repaid this with ruble credits issued by their central European Union (EU) was preparing for EMU, elab- banks. The IMF (1994) statistics for Russian financing orating on the Maastricht Treaty. Therefore, it sup- of the other former Soviet republics in 1992 are quite ported a joint currency zone. European interests dom- extraordinary. Russia financed 91 percent of Tajikis- inated the IMF, which sought a middle road of jointly tan’s GDP, 70 percent of Uzbekistan’s GDP and about agreed monetary policy without central control, but 50 percent of the GDP of Turkmenistan, Georgia, that option was never viable. Monetary discipline and Armenia. Belarus and Moldova received ‘only’ could only be ascertained if there was only one central 10 percent of their GDP. This cost Russia 11.7 percent bank solely responsible for issuing the ruble. (Sachs of its GDP of only 80 billion US dollars at the ex- and Lipton 1993; Åslund 2002) change rate of 1992. Impoverished Russia could not possibly continue this financing. The newly minted central bankers realised that the more credits they issued, the larger a share of the com- The Soviet Union had a highly centralised payments mon GDP they would extract. But presumably it was system, in which all payments went through the more convincing that friendly private bankers and com- Central Bank, which examined every single payment. modity traders were delighted to give them a commis- A handful of state banks had managed all payments. sion on the money that the central bankers lent them. The number of payments was limited because the 13 CESifo Forum 4/2016 (December) Focus number of state enterprises was not large, but as the the ruble zone by suddenly and independently declar- number of enterprises multiplied, payment delays ing all Soviet banknotes null and void at the end of surged. Nor did enterprises have any incentive to pay. July 1993. Panic broke out throughout the former Since they did not pay one another, they were all short Soviet Union as people queued up outside banks to of money. The arrears crisis was exacerbated by a use their old Soviet ruble banknotes.
Recommended publications
  • Country Profile, Russia
    Update November 2008 COUNTRY PROFILE, RUSSIA Introduction and Country Background 2 Banking Environment 4 Financial Authorities 7 Legal & Regulatory Issues 8 Market Dominant Banks 11 Clearing Systems 14 Payments & Collections Methods & Instruments 17 Electronic Banking 20 Cash Pooling Solutions 21 Tax Issues 22 Source and Contacts 27 Page 1 of 27 Country profile, Russia Introduction and Country Background Russia has the larg- Key Facts est population in Europe Moscow (Moskva)⎯ St Petersburg, Novosibirsk, Yekater- Capital - Major Cities inburg, Nizhniy Novgorod, Omsk, Samara, Kazan, Chely- abinsk, Rostov-on-Don, Ufa, Volgograd, Perm Area 17,075,200 km2 Population 141.9m (2008 estimate) Languages Russian, many minority languages Currency RUB (Russian Rouble) Telephone Code +7 National / Religious / 2009: 1-5 Jan, 6, 7, 8, 9 Jan; 23 Feb; 8,9 Mar; 1,9,11 Bank Holidays May; 12 Jun; 4 Nov. Extra bank day 11 Jan (Sun) Bank Hours 09:0018:00 (MonFri) Business Hours 10:00 (Mon-Sat) RTS Stock Exchange, Moscow Interbank Currency Ex- Stock Exchange change (MICEX) Moscow Stock Exchange (MSE) Leading Share Index RTS Index, S&P/RUX Composite Index, MICEX Index Strong economic Economic Performance growth, helped along by high oil prices, has 2004 2005 2006 2007 been the norm in re- Exchange Rate RUB/EUR1 35.7639 35.1897 34.1886 35.0297 cent years Exchange Rate RUB/USD1 28.8042 28.2960 27.2578 25.5515 Money Market Rate (%)1 3.3 2.7 3.4 6.03 Consumer Inflation (%)2 10.9 12.6 9.7 12.0 Unemployment Rate (%)3 8.5 8.3 7.6 5.9 GDP (RUB billions) 16,966 21,598
    [Show full text]
  • “Current Trends in the Russian Financial System”
    “CURRENT TRENDS IN THE RUSSIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM” Edited by Morten Balling Chapters by: Stephan Barisitz Zeljko Bogetic Zuzana Fungačova and Laura Solanko Peter Havlik Valery Invushin, Vladimir V. Osakovsky and Debora Revoltella Alexander Lehmann Ewald Nowotny Cyril Pineau-Valencienne Pekka Sutela A joint publication with the Austrian Society for Bank Research SUERF – The European Money and Finance Forum Vienna 2009 CIP CURRENT TRENDS IN THE RUSSIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM Editor: Morten Balling; Authors: Stephan Barisitz; Zeljko Bogetic; Zuzana Fungačova and Laura Solanko; Peter Havlik; Valery Invushin, Vladimir V. Osakovsky and Debora Revoltella; Alexander Lehmann; Ewald Nowotny; Cyril Pineau-Valencienne; Pekka Sutela Vienna: SUERF (SUERF Studies: 2009/2) ISBN-13: 978-3-902109-47-7 Keywords: Russia, rouble, oil price, banking, transition economics, global financial crisis, Central Bank of Russia JEL Classification Numbers: E5, O5, P2, Q43 © 2009 SUERF, Vienna Copyright reserved. Subject to the exception provided for by law, no part of this publication may be reproduced and/or published in print, by photocopying, on microfilm or in any other way without the written consent of the copyright holder(s); the same applies to whole or partial adaptations. The publisher retains the sole right to collect from third parties fees payable in respect of copying and/or take legal or other action for this purpose. TABLE OF CONTENTS Table of Contents 3 1. Introduction 7 2. Opening Remarks 13 3. Russian Finance: Drag or Booster for Future Growth? 23 1. References 39 4. Russian Banking in Recent Years: Gaining Depth in a Fragile Environment 43 1. Abstract 43 2. Introduction 44 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Digital Financial Services (Dfs) Working Group
    DIGITAL FINANCIAL SERVICES (DFS) WORKING GROUP Bringing policymakers together to discuss regulatory issues related to digital financial services (DFS), and promote DFS as a major driver of financial inclusion in emerging and developing countries. The DFS Working Group develops policy guidelines, conducts peer reviews, and actively engages the DFS and FinTech industry and global Standard-Setting Bodies (SSBs). WWW.AFI-GLOBAL.ORG #DFS #AFIWG AT A GLANCE KEY OBJECTIVES > Create an enabling policy and regulatory environment for transformational DFS at national levels; > Develop a shared understanding of the risk profiles of emerging digital financial services business models, which is essential in designing appropriate regulatory frameworks; > Stimulate discussion and learning on new approaches and good practices in DFS regulation by encouraging policymakers to exchange experiences; > Provide a platform for capturing, tracking and sharing information on innovative DFS, products, business models and appropriate new policy responses; > Establish linkages and provide inputs, where appropriate, to global Standard-Setting bodies (SSBs) and other stakeholders seeking to establish proportionate supervisory practices for DFS. PLANNED ACTIVITIES > DFS and Consumer Protection Policy Model Subgroup (jointly with CEMCWG): Policy model on DFS and Consumer protection. > Data Protection & Privacy Subgroup: White paper - Data Protection & Privacy in the Age of Data Driven Financial Services. > QR Code Standardization Subgroup: Guideline Note on QR code standardization including case studies to understand different models and issues related to QR codes payments and standardization. > Digital Financial Literacy and Capability subgroup (jointly with CEMCWG): Guideline Note on Digital Financial Literacy and Capability. > Regulatory Sandboxes Subgroup: Toolkit on Regulatory Sandboxes. > Regtech Technical Taskforce (DFSWG Focal Points): Special Report: Regtech for Financial Inclusion.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Infrastructure
    CONFIDENTIAL FOR RESTRICTED USE ONLY (NOT FOR USE BY THIRD PARTIES) Public Disclosure Authorized FINANCIAL SECTOR ASSESSMENT PROGRAM Public Disclosure Authorized RUSSIAN FEDERATION FINANCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE TECHNICAL NOTE JULY 2016 Public Disclosure Authorized This Technical Note was prepared in the context of a joint World Bank-IMF Financial Sector Assessment Program mission in the Russian Federation during April, 2016, led by Aurora Ferrari, World Bank and Karl Habermeier, IMF, and overseen by Finance & Markets Global Practice, World Bank and the Monetary and Capital Markets Department, IMF. The note contains technical analysis and detailed information underpinning the FSAP assessment’s findings and recommendations. Further information on the FSAP program can be found at www.worldbank.org/fsap. THE WORLD BANK GROUP FINANCE & MARKETS GLOBAL PRACTICE Public Disclosure Authorized i TABLE OF CONTENT Page I. Executive Summary ........................................................................................................ 1 II. Introduction ................................................................................................................... 15 III. Payment and Settlement Systems ............................................................................. 16 A. Legal and regulatory framework .......................................................................... 16 B. Payment system landscape .................................................................................... 18 C. Systemically important payment systems
    [Show full text]
  • List of Certain Foreign Institutions Classified As Official for Purposes of Reporting on the Treasury International Capital (TIC) Forms
    NOT FOR PUBLICATION DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY JANUARY 2001 Revised Aug. 2002, May 2004, May 2005, May/July 2006, June 2007 List of Certain Foreign Institutions classified as Official for Purposes of Reporting on the Treasury International Capital (TIC) Forms The attached list of foreign institutions, which conform to the definition of foreign official institutions on the Treasury International Capital (TIC) Forms, supersedes all previous lists. The definition of foreign official institutions is: "FOREIGN OFFICIAL INSTITUTIONS (FOI) include the following: 1. Treasuries, including ministries of finance, or corresponding departments of national governments; central banks, including all departments thereof; stabilization funds, including official exchange control offices or other government exchange authorities; and diplomatic and consular establishments and other departments and agencies of national governments. 2. International and regional organizations. 3. Banks, corporations, or other agencies (including development banks and other institutions that are majority-owned by central governments) that are fiscal agents of national governments and perform activities similar to those of a treasury, central bank, stabilization fund, or exchange control authority." Although the attached list includes the major foreign official institutions which have come to the attention of the Federal Reserve Banks and the Department of the Treasury, it does not purport to be exhaustive. Whenever a question arises whether or not an institution should, in accordance with the instructions on the TIC forms, be classified as official, the Federal Reserve Bank with which you file reports should be consulted. It should be noted that the list does not in every case include all alternative names applying to the same institution.
    [Show full text]
  • Soviet Ruble, Gold Ruble, Tchernovetz and Ruble-Merchandise Mimeograph
    http://oac.cdlib.org/findaid/ark:/13030/kt258032tg No online items Overview of the Soviet ruble, gold ruble, tchernovetz and ruble-merchandise mimeograph Processed by Hoover Institution Archives Staff. Hoover Institution Archives Stanford University Stanford, California 94305-6010 Phone: (650) 723-3563 Fax: (650) 725-3445 Email: [email protected] © 2009 Hoover Institution Archives. All rights reserved. Overview of the Soviet ruble, YY497 1 gold ruble, tchernovetz and ruble-merchandise mimeograph Overview of the Soviet ruble, gold ruble, tchernovetz and ruble-merchandise mimeograph Hoover Institution Archives Stanford University Stanford, California Processed by: Hoover Institution Archives Staff Date Completed: 2009 Encoded by: Machine-readable finding aid derived from MARC record by David Sun. © 2009 Hoover Institution Archives. All rights reserved. Collection Summary Title: Soviet ruble, gold ruble, tchernovetz and ruble-merchandise mimeograph Dates: 1923 Collection Number: YY497 Collection Size: 1 item (1 folder) (0.1 linear feet) Repository: Hoover Institution Archives Stanford, California 94305-6010 Abstract: Relates to the circulation of currency in the Soviet Union. Original article published in Agence économique et financière, 1923 July 18. Translated by S. Uget. Physical Location: Hoover Institution Archives Languages: English Access Collection is open for research. The Hoover Institution Archives only allows access to copies of audiovisual items. To listen to sound recordings or to view videos or films during your visit, please contact the Archives at least two working days before your arrival. We will then advise you of the accessibility of the material you wish to see or hear. Please note that not all audiovisual material is immediately accessible. Publication Rights For copyright status, please contact the Hoover Institution Archives.
    [Show full text]
  • Russian America and the USSR: Striking Parallels by Andrei V
    Russian America and the USSR: Striking Parallels by Andrei V. Grinëv Translated by Richard L. Bland Abstract. The article is devoted to a comparative analysis of the socioeconomic systems that have formed in the Russian colonies in Alaska and in the USSR. The author shows how these systems evolved and names the main reason for their similarity: the nature of the predominant type of property. In both systems, supreme state property dominated and in this way they can be designated as politaristic. Politariasm (from the Greek πολιτεία—the power of the majority, that is, in a broad sense, the state, the political system) is formation founded on the state’s supreme ownership of the basic means of production and the work force. Economic relations of politarism generated the corresponding social structure, administrative management, ideological culture, and even similar psychological features in Russian America and the USSR. Key words: Russian America, USSR, Alaska, Russian-American Company, politarism, comparative historical research. The selected theme might seem at first glance paradoxical. And in fact, what is common between the few Russian colonies in Alaska, which existed from the end of the 18th century to 1867, and the huge USSR of the 20th century? Nevertheless, analysis of this topic demonstrates the indisputable similarity between the development of such, it would seem, different-scaled and diachronic socioeconomic systems. It might seem surprising that many phenomena of the economic and social sphere of Russian America subsequently had clear analogies in Soviet society. One can hardly speak of simple coincidences and accidents of history. Therefore, the selected topic is of undoubted scholarly interest.
    [Show full text]
  • The Monetary Legacy of the Soviet Union / Patrick Conway
    ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE are published by the International Finance Section of the Department of Economics of Princeton University. The Section sponsors this series of publications, but the opinions expressed are those of the authors. The Section welcomes the submission of manuscripts for publication in this and its other series. Please see the Notice to Contributors at the back of this Essay. The author of this Essay, Patrick Conway, is Professor of Economics at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. He has written extensively on the subject of structural adjustment in developing and transitional economies, beginning with Economic Shocks and Structural Adjustment: Turkey after 1973 (1987) and continuing, most recently, with “An Atheoretic Evaluation of Success in Structural Adjustment” (1994a). Professor Conway has considerable experience with the economies of the former Soviet Union and has made research visits to each of the republics discussed in this Essay. PETER B. KENEN, Director International Finance Section INTERNATIONAL FINANCE SECTION EDITORIAL STAFF Peter B. Kenen, Director Margaret B. Riccardi, Editor Lillian Spais, Editorial Aide Lalitha H. Chandra, Subscriptions and Orders Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Conway, Patrick J. Currency proliferation: the monetary legacy of the Soviet Union / Patrick Conway. p. cm. — (Essays in international finance, ISSN 0071-142X ; no. 197) Includes bibliographical references. ISBN 0-88165-104-4 (pbk.) : $8.00 1. Currency question—Former Soviet republics. 2. Monetary policy—Former Soviet republics. 3. Finance—Former Soviet republics. I. Title. II. Series. HG136.P7 no. 197 [HG1075] 332′.042 s—dc20 [332.4′947] 95-18713 CIP Copyright © 1995 by International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.
    [Show full text]
  • Priorities for the Central Bank of Russia
    Reinvigorating Growth Potential: Priorities for the Central Bank of Russia Professor and Head of International Organizations Research Institute, Higher School Marina Larionova of Economics, National Research University Researcher, Global Governance Research Center, International Organizations Andrey Shelepov Research Institute, Higher School of Economics, National Research University he pace of global recovery remains weak. More advocate different approaches. Some experts and than twelve months since the G-20 summit in certain authorities propose that the CBR should TLos Cabos, G-20 members are laboring their explicitly prioritize support for economic growth way towards “Strong, Sustainable and Balanced in its policy, stimulating the real sector of the econ- Growth” in a clouded world economic outlook, omy using all the instruments and resources it has. with the eurozone in a state of recession, a combi- These include lowering interest rates, depreciating nation of policy stalemate and across the board fis- the ruble, expanding refinancing instruments, and cal consolidation constraining growth in the U.S., slowing down financial supervision reform by de- and emerging markets and developing countries laying the adoption of Basel 2.5 and Basel III capital experiencing a clear slowdown compared to their frameworks. According to the competing second rapid pre-crisis expansion.1 A durable recovery that school of thought, the CBR should focus on infla- creates good jobs, which G-20 leaders agreed to co- tion targeting, consolidate its liquidity instruments, operate for in September 2009, proves to be an elu- raise flexibility of the ruble exchange rate with lim- sive objective. Fiscal consolidation acts as a drag on ited interventions to soften short-term fluctua- economic recovery and the G-20’s capacity to de- tions, strengthen the supervisory framework and liver on the growth and jobs agenda is questioned build a reliable, stress-resistant financial markets by its citizens.
    [Show full text]
  • Underpinning of Soviet Industrial Paradigms
    Science and Social Policy: Underpinning of Soviet Industrial Paradigms by Chokan Laumulin Supervised by Professor Peter Nolan Centre of Development Studies Department of Politics and International Studies Darwin College This dissertation is submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy May 2019 Preface This dissertation is the result of my own work and includes nothing which is the outcome of work done in collaboration except as declared in the Preface and specified in the text. It is not substantially the same as any that I have submitted, or, is being concurrently submitted for a degree or diploma or other qualification at the University of Cambridge or any other University or similar institution except as declared in the Preface and specified in the text. I further state that no substantial part of my dissertation has already been submitted, or, is being concurrently submitted for any such degree, diploma or other qualification at the University of Cambridge or any other University or similar institution except as declared in the Preface and specified in the text It does not exceed the prescribed word limit for the relevant Degree Committee. 2 Chokan Laumulin, Darwin College, Centre of Development Studies A PhD thesis Science and Social Policy: Underpinning of Soviet Industrial Development Paradigms Supervised by Professor Peter Nolan. Abstract. Soviet policy-makers, in order to aid and abet industrialisation, seem to have chosen science as an agent for development. Soviet science, mainly through the Academy of Sciences of the USSR, was driving the Soviet industrial development and a key element of the preparation of human capital through social programmes and politechnisation of the society.
    [Show full text]
  • RUB Russia Rouble Payments
    Rouble Payments Payment Instructions – July 2021 Nordea customers can effect payments in roubles required to provide more extensive information than in (RUB). Rouble payments, however, need specific ordinary payment orders. codification. Russian banks are under obligation to monitor that As in all payments, the beneficiary’s name and payments are made in accordance with the instructions address, including the city, should be given. In and exchange regulations issued by the Central Bank addition, payments in RUB require INN, BIK and VO of Russia. codes: The following rouble payments are possible: • The INN code (tax payer identification code) is for residents of Russia and is required for • Services and foreign trade transactions companies (consists of 10 digits) and for • Expenses of representative offices in Russia individual entrepreneurs (consists of 12 digits). • Taxes and similar charges First provide the INN in the field beneficiary • Share capital; loan capital and interests name. Then provide both the beneficiary's • Other payments mentioned in the VO payment name and address in the field beneficiary code list address. • For RUB payments from Denmark and It generally takes two banking days for a rouble Norway provide the BIK (9 digits starting with payment to arrive at Nordea if sent from Moscow / St 04) in format //RU04nnnnnnn/ followed by the Petersburg, but usually a few days more if sent from clearing account number with the Central other locations. Bank of Russia (20 digits starting with 3) in the field beneficiary bank name. Types of rouble accounts Example: Non-residents may open an unlimited number of //RU04nnnnnnn/3nnnnnnnnnnnnnnnnnnn. accounts in one or several authorized banks in Russia.
    [Show full text]
  • Download Article (PDF)
    Advances in Economics, Business and Management Research, volume 128 International Scientific Conference "Far East Con" (ISCFEC 2020) Information Security Ensuring in the Financial Sector as Part of the Implementation of the National Program “Data Economy Russia 2024” K Horian1, E Gorian2 1HorianSis Studio, Vladivostok, 690014, Russian Federation 2Vladivostok State University of Economics and Service, 41, Gogol str., Vladivostok, 690014, Russian Federation E-mail: [email protected] Abstract. The object of the research is the relations arising from the implementation of the National Program “Data Economy Russia 2024” in the aspect of ensuring information security in the financial sector of Russia. The role of the state financial regulator in the implementation of this program is determined, taking into account the peculiarities of its legal status. The key documents that form the regulatory and legal mechanisms for ensuring the information security of the financial and banking sector of Russia are examined. The content of the activity of the center of competence of the federal project “Information Security” is determined and the need to determine the Bank of Russia as the center of competence is justified. Despite the serious constitutional and legal status and experience of practical management of processes to ensure the security of financial institutions, the potential of the financial regulator is not fully used in the National Program “Data Economy Russia 2024”, although the tasks assigned to the center of competence in information security are of a public nature and accordingly must be performed by the relevant subject. As the confirmation and logical continuation of the main role declared by the legislation in ensuring the stability of the financial system the Bank of Russia should be maintained as the center of competence of the federal project, since the financial regulator has all the organizational and legal powers and material resources (FinCERT) for this words.
    [Show full text]