How to Become an International Intellectual? the Case of Thomas Piketty and ”Capital in the Twenty-First Century” (Doi: 10.2383/86982)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How to Become an International Intellectual? the Case of Thomas Piketty and ”Capital in the Twenty-First Century” (Doi: 10.2383/86982) Il Mulino - Rivisteweb Constantin Brissaud, Jean-Michel Chahsiche How to Become an International Intellectual? The Case of Thomas Piketty and ”Capital in the Twenty-First Century” (doi: 10.2383/86982) Sociologica (ISSN 1971-8853) Fascicolo 1, gennaio-aprile 2017 Ente di afferenza: () Copyright c by Societ`aeditrice il Mulino, Bologna. Tutti i diritti sono riservati. Per altre informazioni si veda https://www.rivisteweb.it Licenza d’uso L’articolo `emesso a disposizione dell’utente in licenza per uso esclusivamente privato e personale, senza scopo di lucro e senza fini direttamente o indirettamente commerciali. Salvo quanto espressamente previsto dalla licenza d’uso Rivisteweb, `efatto divieto di riprodurre, trasmettere, distribuire o altrimenti utilizzare l’articolo, per qualsiasi scopo o fine. Tutti i diritti sono riservati. Symposium / Traveling Theories. The International Circulation of Social Thinkers and Their Works, edited by Gisèle Sapiro and Marco Santoro How to Become an International Intellectual? The Case of Thomas Piketty and “Capital in the Twenty-First Century” by Constantin Brissaud and Jean-Michel Chahsiche doi: 10.2383/86982 Interestingly, Professor Piketty has recently assembled a group of fifteen French economists (the so-called Piketty Group) that have joined forces with a group of German economists, known as the Glienicker Gruppe, to propose institutional changes that may help resolve the Euro Crisis and return Europe on the path of stability and integration. The parallel with Capital in the Twenty-First Century is uncanny. Professor Piketty has a talent for making bold statements replete with good intentions. Just as he presents his Capital as a dagger with which to slay the abomination of unbearable inequality […] Yanis Varoufakis 2014, 32 1. Introduction As pointed out by Abram de Swaan [2007], only a handful of intellectuals have been able to overcome the borders of their home states to gain international recognition. Following the best-selling record made by Capital in the Twenty-First Century in the United States of America (US) [2014] and in France [2013], and the “Pikettymania” that ensued, it seems that Thomas Piketty has joined this club of happy-few: in March 2016, his chronicles for French newspapers Le Monde and Libération were published in the US and in the United Kingdom with significant coverage by major media outlets such as the BBC, The Guardian, Bloomberg Magazine and The New York Times. Generally, Thomas Piketty’s views on economic current affairs are frequently quoted and commentated by those same medias. Sociologica, 1/2017 - Copyright © 2017 by Società editrice il Mulino, Bologna. 1 Brissaud and Chahsiche, How to Become an International Intellectual? As a result of the success of his 2013 book, Piketty’s position as a public intellec- tual well beyond France’s borders raises several interesting issues for the study of the international circulation of ideas and the sociology of intellectuals. First, the case of Thomas Piketty’s Capital opens the analysis of the the multi-level internationalization of several fields that are historically structured within the frame of the nation-state, such as the academic, intellectual and political fields. These fields – in which Thomas Piketty navigates – are subject to different dynamics and paces of internationalization. With regard to politics, European or international political careers are of little appeal for political élites compared to other top national careers [Bryder 1998; Beauvallet and Michon 2010]. On the contrary, economics became a globalized professional field in the post-World War II period, and managed to impose standardized tools for economic analysis, as well as policy making [Coats 2001; Fourcade 2006]. Linked with the rise of the nation-state in the Nineteenth century, intellectual spaces still remain fiercely national [Sapiro 2009]. However, through the market of translation, international circulation of authors and ideas have long been made possible [Heil- bron 1999; Sapiro 2008], yet not without some distortion due to different national political and intellectual contexts [Bourdieu 1996 and 2002; Sapiro and Bustamante 2009], as shown by the “French Theory” label in the US [Lamont 1987; Cusset 2008] and the early importation of John Rawls’ theory of justice and analytical philosophy in France [Pudal 2004; Hauchecorne 2011]. By differentiating Piketty the economist and Piketty the intellectual – scientific position and intellectual position – the multiple levels of internationalization become visible. As an economist, Thomas Piketty had international visibility among his peers long before the publishing of Capital in the Twenty-First Century. He had also been recognized in the intellectual field in France, as shown by his long running chron- icles in central newspapers such as Libération and Le Monde. In a profession that tends to be organized around policy making [Lebaron 2000; Fourcade 2009; Pouch 2008; Hirschman and Popp Berman 2014] rather than intellectual stances on public debates, Piketty’s position as an intellectual in France is quite original, and yet not as completely isolated. Others, such as Philippe Aghion and Daniel Cohen in France or, Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz in the US, frequently take part in public debates. Moreover, in France, the field of public intellectuals tends to be dominated by non- academic thinkers, who vindicate a philosophical background.1 x 1 This is especially true of the “New philosophers,” who came to fame in the mid-1970s. While they gained considerable visibility through the heavy use of broadcast media (most notably television) and the frequent production of best-selling essays, the “New philosophers” (among which one counts such thinkers as Bernard-Henri Levy and André Glucksmann) retained little legitimacy from the more autonomous, academic-based part of the intellectual fields [Christofferson 2004]. 2 Sociologica, 1/2017 In this paper, we demonstrate how the reception of Capital in the Twenty-First Century enabled its author to gain new visibility as an intellectual, on an internation- al level. The first four sections of the article aim to define Piketty’s position in the field of economics and in the French intellectual field before the publication of Cap- ital in Twenty-First Century. In doing so, we intend to outline the long term social dynamics in which the production and the reception of Capital in Twenty-First Cen- tury is entangled: long before this book, Thomas Piketty was indeed already a dom- inant economist and a well-established intellectual in France with strong ties to the French political field, as well as to the American academic field due to his having been assistant professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) early in his career. The symbolic and social capital that Piketty accumulated throughout his career was then invested in the making of Capital in the Twenty-First Century. The last sections focus on the dynamics of internationalization by looking at the trends in media citations in several countries. We then show that the United-States function as the central instance of certification in the making of an international intellectual figure. 2. Part 1: The Economist Made Intellectual 2.1. Thomas Piketty in the Field of Economists According to Frédéric Lebaron’s sociology of French economists [Lebaron 2000 and 2005], Thomas Piketty holds a dominant position at the spiritual pole of the field. That is, his authority as an economist mostly derives from the ac- cumulation of scientific capital and peer recognition in the academic side of the discipline. He is then differentiated from those who retain little scientific legit- imacy, have led their career mostly outside academia, and depend on various forms of economic (many corporate companies, especially in the finance sector, now have a department for economic studies) or political power (for example, the once powerful economic section of the French Communist Party [Monneau 2016]). To this extent, whereas a wider audience discovered Piketty’s work on eco- nomic inequalities through Capital in Twenty-First Century and its media cover- age, the French economist was already a prominent figure in his discipline, highly and frequently cited in economics journals. According to the IDEAS citation in- dex, Thomas Piketty ranks sixth among French economists (first is Nobel Prize holder Jean Tirole). Professor at (and the first director of) the Paris School of Economics – the most cited economics French institution according to IDEAS – Thomas Piketty’s central position in the French field of economics is partly – if 3 Brissaud and Chahsiche, How to Become an International Intellectual? not mostly – due to the international capital he has accumulated throughout his career.2 Since the second half of the Twentieth century, the intellectual and institutional centre of economics has been located in the US, which provides most of the dominat- ing academic institutions, consecrated scholars, such as the vast majority of econom- ics Nobel Prize winners, and the most prominent scientific journals in the discipline [Lebaron 2002]. Marion Fourcade thus suggests that, in the economic profession, credentials (such as diplomas, teaching and research positions) acquired in the US and, to a lesser extent, in Europe, potentially have universal value, which means that they can be invested and rewarded outside of the country, the region or the profession that first issued them [Fourcade 2006, 152]. Strongly linked with the economic and political domination of the US, the rise of American economics as the centre of the discipline means that the top academic institutions, journals and economists in the US hold the same position in other national fields.3 In this respect, locating Thomas Piketty in the field of economists must take into account the peculiar sociology of the economics discipline. Frequently claimed to be the most advanced discipline among social sciences in terms of internationalization [Gingras 2002], economics is more accurately one of the most centralized disciplines, which means that national fields tend to be more dependant on the centre – here the U.S.
Recommended publications
  • Monopoly Capital and Capitalist Inequality: Marx After Piketty
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Monopoly Capital and Capitalist Inequality: Marx after Piketty Lambert, Thomas Northern Kentucky University January 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/69615/ MPRA Paper No. 69615, posted 20 Feb 2016 08:50 UTC Monopoly Capital and Capitalist Inequality: Marx after Piketty By Thomas E. Lambert Assistant Professor of Public Administration Northern Kentucky University Highland Heights, KY 41099 [email protected] 502-403-9795 (cell) Abstract This paper proposes that one major explanation of growing inequality in the United States (US) is through the use of the concept of economic surplus. The economic surplus is a neo-Marxian term which combines the traditional Marxian tenet of surplus value with other ways that surplus value can be invested in a mature, advanced capitalist economy. A rising economic surplus that is not absorbed through growing consumer spending, luxury spending or government spending results in stagnant wages and growing inequality via higher levels of underemployment and greater monopoly and monopsony power among a decreasing number of huge, powerful corporations. Therefore, the politics surrounding the growth of inequality in the US has to be understood first by understanding over accumulation of the economic surplus by those at the top of the US capitalist class. This research note gives estimates of the rising economic surplus over the last several decades in the US as well as how these correlate with the level of inequality. The growth of the economic surplus gives rise and form to the politics of inequality and austerity. As time goes by, the politics of inequality and austerity in the US will be manifested by greater corporate influence in the political system, greater political polarization, less government 1 effectiveness, and more debates about welfare spending, corporate taxation, taxes on upper income households, and taxes on wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Toward a Reconciliation Between Economics and the Social Sciences
    1 Toward a Reconciliation between Economics and the Social Sciences Lessons from Capital in the Twenty-First Century 1 Thomas Piketty I would like to see Capital in the Twenty-First Century as a work-in-progress of social science rather than a treatise about history or economics. It seems to me that too much time is lost within the social sciences on petty quarrels about boundaries and often rather sterile methodological positions. I believe that these oppositions between disciplines can and should be overcome, and that the best way to do so is to address big issues and see how far we can take them, using whatever combination of methods and disciplinary traditions that seems appropriate. I could not have hoped for a greater homage to my approach than this group of texts written by specialists from very different horizons and methodological perspectives.2 Within the framework of such a short article, it is impossible to respond to all of the points raised in this book and to do justice to the richness of these essays. I would simply like to attempt to clarify a small number of issues and refine certain elements that were undoubtedly insufficiently developed in my book, in particular from the perspective of the multidimensional history of capital and power relations, and regarding the role played by beliefs systems and economic models in my analysis. I will then turn to another important limitation of my book, namely the fact that it is too much Western-centered. Capital and the Social Sciences First of all, I would like to briefly summarize what I have tried to do in this work and how it fits into the history of the social sciences, where several research traditions and schools of thought intersect.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Introduction Pat Hudson and Keith Tribe Pat Hudson and Keith Tribe
    1 introduction Pat Hudson and Keith Tribe Pat Hudson and Keith Tribe Thomas Piketty’s Le Capital au XXIe siècle was first published in Paris during the summer of 2013. On the appearance of an English edition in March 2014 introduction it became an international blockbuster, being quickly translated into German, Spanish and Chinese. Sales of all copies by January 2015 were 1.5 million and rising, fuelled by popular concern about growing income inequality and the links between inequality and global economic instability. Thanks to Piketty, and to his large transnational team of colleagues, together with a spate of recent books on global wealth and income disparities, distribution is back at the centre of our concerns.1 piketty’s promise In light of the mass of new comparative data contained in Capital in the Twenty- First Century, and in associated publications and appendices, it is clear that some common long-run trends in inequality across the developed world had not been sufficiently recognized. In particular, Piketty emphasizes the notable increase in income-generating wealth of top income earners in recent decades, together with rising pay. His study of top incomes, and their genesis, has unsettled the widely held assumption that capital’s share in national income (via interest, divi- dends and capital gains) would always necessarily revert to a long-run constant. The social concentration of wealth through inheritance and its role in cumu- latively ratcheting up incomes, and thus further increasing wealth in the top 10 per cent or so of the population, is now in the spotlight.
    [Show full text]
  • Debatiendo Con Piketty.Indb
    M J . B Cuando se publicó en 2013, El capital en el siglo XXI se A J. Bradford DeLong es profesor de economía en la Una mirada plural de la desigualdad RSH R convirtió en un sorprendente bestseller. La principal ADFO Universidad de California en Berkeley, investigador A armación de este libro es que la riqueza crece más y sus consecuencias LL STEIN asociado en la Ocina Nacional de Investigación rápido que la producción económica, con lo cual, el RD Económica y miembro del Instituto para un Nuevo DE capital se concentra cada vez en menos individuos. El capital en el siglo XXI de Thomas Piketty es el libro sobre economía de más éxito de la Pensamiento Económico. Sus campos de trabajo son L BAUM Así se conrmó la sospecha de que el capitalismo no historia reciente. Su detallada explicación del aumento de la desigualdad en las últimas ONG DEBATIENDO la historia económica, la macroeconomía, el , HEA estaba funcionando. Sin embargo, a pesar de que la décadas suscitó un encendido debate político que aún hoy continúa y que probablemente crecimiento económico y las nanzas. También es tesis concordaba con la experiencia social y era marcará el futuro inmediato. Pero, ¿son ciertos los análisis de Piketty?, ¿acierta en su doctor en economía por la Universidad de Harvard. THE con aplicable a las nanzas globales, los economistas percepción de la desigualdad y los objetivos de crecimiento? Y, si es así, ¿cómo debería R acogieron la obra con gran hostilidad. desarrollarse la investigación económica a partir de sus estudios? ¿Cómo debemos plantear BOUSHEY Heather Boushey es directora ejecutiva y economista el debate actual? jefe del Centro para el Crecimiento Equitativo de En este extraordinario diálogo con Piketty y su obra, Washington.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Piketty Phenomenon 27 Arthur Goldhammer 2. Thomas Piketty Is Right 48 Robert M
    Contents Introduction 1 Capital in the Twenty- First Century, Three Years Later 1 J. Bradford DeLong, Heather Boushey, and Marshall Steinbaum I. Reception 1. The Piketty Phenomenon 27 Arthur Goldhammer 2. Thomas Piketty Is Right 48 Robert M. Solow 3. Why We’re in a New Gilded Age 60 Paul Krugman II. Conceptions of Capital 4. What’s Wrong with Capital in the Twenty- First Century’s Model? 75 Devesh Raval 5. A Po liti cal Economy Take on W / Y 99 Suresh Naidu 6. The Ubiquitous Nature of Slave Capital 126 Daina Ramey Berry 7. ­Human Capital and Wealth before and afterCapital in the Twenty- First Century 150 Eric R. Nielsen 8. Exploring the Effects of Technology on Income and Wealth In equality 170 Laura Tyson and Michael Spence 9. Income In equality, Wage Determination, and the Fissured Workplace 209 David Weil III. Dimensions of In equality 10. Increasing Capital Income Share and Its Effect on Personal Income In equality 235 Branko Milanovic Contents 11. Global In equality 259 Christoph Lakner 12. The Geographies ofCapital in the Twenty- First Century: In equality, Po liti cal Economy, and Space 280 Gareth A. Jones 13. The Research Agenda afterCapital in the Twenty- First Century 304 Emmanuel Saez 14. Macro Models of Wealth In equality 322 Mariacristina De Nardi, Giulio Fella, and Fang Yang 15. A Feminist Interpretation of Patrimonial Capitalism 355 Heather Boushey 16. What Does Rising In equality Mean for the Macroeconomy? 384 Mark Zandi 17. Rising In equality and Economic Stability 412 Salvatore Morelli IV. The Po liti cal Economy of Capital and Capitalism 18.
    [Show full text]
  • Emmanuel Saez CV
    September 2021 EMMANUEL SAEZ University of California Department of Economics 530 Evans Hall #3880, Berkeley, CA 94720 E-mail: [email protected] http://www.econ.berkeley.edu/~saez/ Phone: 510-642-4631, FAX: 510-642-6615 DATE OF BIRTH: 11-26-1972 CITIZENSHIP: France and US EDUCATION: 1999 Ph.D. in Economics, MIT 1996 M.D. in Economics at DELTA, Paris, France 1994 B.A. in Mathematics at École Normale Supérieure, 45 Rue d’Ulm, Paris, France PROFESSIONAL EXPERIENCE: July 2005- present: Professor of Economics, University of California at Berkeley July 2010- present: Director, Center for Equitable Growth, http://ceg.berkeley.edu/, UC Berkeley July 2003- June 2005: Associate Professor of Economics, University of California at Berkeley July 2002- June 2003: Assistant Professor of Economics, University of California at Berkeley July 1999- June 2002: Assistant Professor of Economics, Harvard University HONORS AND AWARDS: 2019 Honorary degree, Harvard University 2014 John von Neumann Award from the Rajk Laszlo College, Budapest 2014 H.C. Recktenwald Prize in Economics from the University of Erlangen-Nuremberg, Germany 2010 MacArthur Foundation Fellow 2010 Best Young French Economist Prize, Le Monde, Cercle des Économistes 2009 John Bates Clark Medal from the American Economic Association 2003 Alfred P. Sloan Research Fellowship 2002 National Science Foundation CAREER grant award 1999 National Tax Association dissertation prize 1999 Review of Economic Studies Tour 1998 Alfred P. Sloan Doctoral Dissertation Fellowship INVITED LECTURES 2021 American
    [Show full text]
  • After Piketty?1
    The British Journal of Sociology 2014 Volume 65 Issue 4 After Piketty?1 A.B. Atkinson Abstract In this paper, I take Capital in the Twenty-First Century by Thomas Piketty as the starting point for a set of twelve policy proposals that could bring about a genuine shift in the distribution of income towards less inequality. In designing the set of proposals, I draw on the experience of reducing inequality in postwar Europe and on an analysis as to how the economic circumstances are now different in the twenty-first century, highlighting the role of technical change and the rise in capital emphasized by Piketty.The proposed measures span many fields of policy, and are not confined to fiscal redistribution, encompassing science policy, competition policy, public employment, a guaranteed return on small savings, a capital endow- ment, as well as more progressive taxation of income and wealth transfers, and a participation income. Inequality is embedded in our social structure, and the search for a significant reduction requires us to examine all aspects of our society. I focus on inequality within countries, and what can be achieved by national governments, with the UK specifically in mind. The primary audience is those concerned with policy-making in national governments, but implementation should not be seen purely in these terms.There are different levels of government, and certain proposals, particularly those concerned with taxation, may only be feasible if pursued by a group of countries in collaboration. The last of the twelve proposals – for a basic income for children – is specifically directed at the Euro- pean Union.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Piketty's Capital Idea
    Thomas Piketty’s capital idea prospectmagazine.co.uk/magazine/thomas-pikettys-capital-idea-economics-history-inequality-krugman- interview-review Tom Clark, Prospect, February 28, 2020 The French economist with a celebrated theory of inequality is back—this time with a theory of everything in 1,100 pages. But is he, Paul Krugman asks Prospect, sufficient a polymath to pull it off? by Tom Clark / February 28, 2020 / Leave a comment The history man: Piketty says economists’ neglect of the past makes them conservative. Eric Piermont/AFP via Getty Images Can a book change the world? Thomas Piketty looked as startled as anyone when his first doorstopper on inequality was greeted with this question six years ago. I remember the scholarly statistician’s transformation into a media sensation vividly, because the Guardian had me take a taxi with him around London to make a (possibly) comic video billed as “on tour with the rock-star economist.” Now the Frenchman is back, with a tome that is grander in size and scope, and he seems 1/9 less fazed by the interest and controversy that he generates, as befits his new project: exposing the “ideologies” that ensure that wealth begets wealth, and thereby entrench inequality. Things have been frenetic, and also testing in ways I hadn’t clocked when we spoke—with the resurfacing in the French press of stories about his being investigated for violence towards a former partner, 11 years ago. He is in end-of-day mode when we sit down for an hour—after a long day of briefings, media interviews and prepping for the LSE lecture he still has to give—but he looks if anything younger than he did when thrown into the limelight in 2014.
    [Show full text]
  • After Piketty: the Agenda for Economics and Inequality Edited by Heather Boushey, J
    LSE Review of Books: Book Review: After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality edited by Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong and Page 1 of 4 Marshall Steinbaum Book Review: After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality edited by Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong and Marshall Steinbaum In After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality, editors Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong and Marshall Steinbaum bring together contributors to reflect on the influence of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century and to draw attention to topics less explored in Piketty’s analysis. While this is a work of serious scholarship that is suited primarily to an academic audience, these reflections on inequality as an economic as well as moral, social and political issue are of significance for all, finds Asad Abbasi. After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality. Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong and Marshall Steinbaum (eds). Harvard University Press. 2017. Find this book: Life expectancy for people living around Canary Wharf is 89 years. For people at Canada Water, the next stop on the Jubilee line, life expectancy is 78 years. The life expectancy gap of eleven years between these two stations is equal to that between Switzerland and Bangladesh or between British women born in 2011 and British women born in the 1950s. What explains such a dramatic change in life expectancy within a two-minute tube journey? One probable answer is that London is an unequal city. The richest ten per cent in London own 62.8 per cent of the city’s total wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • Can Economics Save the World from Rising Geopolitical Incertitude?
    COVER COVER LEAD LEAD Can Economics Save the World from Rising Geopolitical Incertitude? By Naoyuki Haraoka There has been growing public distrust in the political leading thinkers as speakers who may not be prepared with ideas to provoke positive thinking about the future. one of the editors and contributors of After Piketty: The elites’ ability to deal with economic policy issues, such with answers but who could provoke new ideas among It will be seen that education is a crucial means for Agenda for Economics and Inequality, talks about the as continuous deflation, fiscal debt, expanding income the audience and participants. The elites and the general reducing the income gap between rich and poor. concern that income inequality today could be socially inequality, and increasing job insecurity from structural public must begin collaborating to find solutions to the Capacity building by self-education through reading a fixed by inheritance and thus result in reduced equality adjustments due to globalization. The general public geopolitical and economic uncertainties we face today, think tank’s publications or attending a policy seminar of opportunity. In particular, limited access to good have a reason to distrust them, because most of these and the key to this collaboration must be respect for organized by a think tank may help to mitigate the education would seriously hamper social mobility and elites are intellectuals, graduates of prestigious knowledge. excessive gap, and we hope our cover story helps to further increase income inequality. universities or graduate schools, who are having to face Knowledge must not be monopolized by political elites stimulate curiosity to learn about economics, in Another contributor to After Piketty: The Agenda for an unprecedented landscape which they have never but needs to be widely shared among the public.
    [Show full text]
  • BRANKO MILANOVIC: CURRICULUM VITAE Visiting Presidential
    BRANKO MILANOVIC: CURRICULUM VITAE Visiting Presidential Professor, Graduate Center, City University of New York (2014- ) LIS Senior Scholar (2014 - ) Working on the issues of income inequality and globalization. 1991-2013, lead economist in the World Bank's research department. 1996-2007, adjunct professor at the SAIS Johns Hopkins University. 2003-2006, senior associate at Carnegie Endowment for International Peace in Washington. 2007-2013, College Park professor at University of Maryland, School of Public Policy. 2010-2011, visiting fellow at All Souls, Oxford and Universidad Carlos III in Madrid. Ph.D. in economics/statistics 1987, University of Belgrade (dissertation: Income inequality in Yugoslavia). Websites: https://www.gc.cuny.edu/stonecenter/Branko-Milanovic https://ideas.repec.org/e/pmi44.html Blog: Globalinequality http://glineq.blogspot.com/ (since May 2014: page views totals 889,000; February 2017) Twitter: @BrankoMilan (31k followers; February 2017) [Summary: More important publications: at least 200 citations according to Google Scholar, number of citation shown between brackets; total number of citations=11510; h index=49; i10 index=119 [accessed on February 25, 2017] 1. Worlds Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2005. [1917=1096+221+84+83+34] 2. “True World Income Distribution, 1988 and 1993: First Calculations Based on Household Surveys Alone”, Economic Journal, vol. 112, No. 476, January 2002, pp. 51-92 [1068=847+221] 3. “Income, Inequality, and Poverty during the Transition from Planned to Market Economy , Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1998. [988] 4. “The Median Voter Hypothesis, Income Inequality and Income Redistribution: An Empirical Test with the Required Data”, European Journal of Political Economy, vol.
    [Show full text]
  • Branko Milanovic: Curriculum Vitae
    BRANKO MILANOVIC: CURRICULUM VITAE Visiting Presidential Professor, Graduate Center, City University of New York (2014- ) LIS Senior Scholar (2014 - ) Working on the issues of income inequality, globalization, and global equity. 1991-2013, lead economist in the World Bank's research department. 1996-2007, adjunct professor at the SAIS Johns Hopkins University. 2003-2006, senior associate at Carnegie Endowment for International Peace in Washington. 2007-2013, College Park professor at University of Maryland, School of Public Policy. 2010-2011, visiting fellow at All Souls, Oxford and Universidad Carlos III in Madrid. Ph.D. in economics/statistics 1987, University of Belgrade (dissertation: Income inequality in Yugoslavia). Web: http://econ.worldbank.org/projects/inequality http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=149002 [Summary: More important publications: at least 200 citations according to Google Scholar, number of citation between brackets; total number of citations=9770; h index =47 (accessed on March 14, 2016] 1. Worlds Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2005. [1040=897+80+61] 2. “True World Income Distribution, 1988 and 1993: First Calculations Based on Household Surveys Alone”, Economic Journal, vol. 112, No. 476, January 2002, pp. 51-92 [1009=933+76] 3. “Income, Inequality, and Poverty during the Transition from Planned to Market Economy , Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1998. [915] 4. “The Median Voter Hypothesis, Income Inequality and Income Redistribution: An Empirical Test with the Required Data”, European Journal of Political Economy, vol. 16, No.3, September 2000, pp. 367-410. [514=447+67] 5. “Can We Discern the Effect of Globalization on Income Distribution? Evidence from Household Budget Surveys", World Bank Economic Review, No.
    [Show full text]