Dynamic Oligopoly and Price Stickiness

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Dynamic Oligopoly and Price Stickiness DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY AND PRICE STICKINESS Olivier Wang Iván Werning WORKING PAPER 27536 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY AND PRICE STICKINESS Olivier Wang Iván Werning Working Paper 27536 http://www.nber.org/papers/w27536 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2020 In memory of Julio Rotemberg, who was ahead of his time, many times. We thank comments by Fernando Alvarez, Anmol Bhandari, Ariel Burstein, Glenn Ellison, Fabio Ghironi, Francesco Lippi, Simon Mongey, as well as seminar and conference participants at MIT, UTDT lecture in honor of Julio Rotemberg, EIEF Rome, SED 2018 meetings, Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank and NBER-SI 2020. All remaining errors are ours. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2020 by Olivier Wang and Iván Werning. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Dynamic Oligopoly and Price Stickiness Olivier Wang and Iván Werning NBER Working Paper No. 27536 July 2020 JEL No. E0,E3,E5 ABSTRACT How does market concentration affect the potency of monetary policy? The ubiquitous monopolistic-competition framework is silent on this issue. To tackle this question we build a model with heterogeneous oligopolistic sectors. In each sector, a finite number of firms play a Bertrand dynamic game with staggered price rigidity. Following an extensive Industrial Organization literature, we focus on Markov equilibria within each sector. Aggregating up, we study monetary shocks and provide a closed-form formula for the response of aggregate output, highlighting three measurable sufficient statistics: demand elasticities, market concentration, and markups. We calibrate our model to the empirical evidence on pass-through, and find that higher market concentration significantly amplifies the real effects of monetary policy. To separate the strategic effects of oligopoly from the effects this has on residual demand, we compare our model to one with monopolistic firms after modifying consumer preferences to ensure firms face comparable residual demands. Finally, the Phillips curve for our model displays inflation persistence and endogenous cost-push shocks. Olivier Wang New York University New York, NY 10012 [email protected] Iván Werning Department of Economics, E52-536 MIT 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 and NBER [email protected] 1 Introduction The recent rise in product-market concentration in the U.S. has been viewed as a driving force behind several macroeconomic trends. For instance, Gutiérrez and Philippon (2017) document an increase in the mean Herfindahl-Hirschman index since the mid-nineties, and argue that it has weakened investment. Autor, Dorn, Katz, Patterson and Van Reenen (2017) and Barkai (2020) relate the rising concentration of sales over the past 30 years in most US sectors to the fall in the labor share.1 What are the implications of trends in concentration or market power for the trans- mission of monetary policy? Do strategic interactions in pricing between increasingly large firms amplify or dampen the real effects of monetary shocks? The baseline New Keynesian model is not designed to address these questions. Following the recognition that some form of imperfect competition and pricing power is required to model nomi- nal rigidities, the New Keynesian literature has been built on the tractable paradigm of monopolistic competition, pervasive in other areas of macroeconomics and international trade. Under monopolistic competition, markups only depend on tastes, through con- sumers’ elasticity of substitution between competing goods, which leaves no room for changes in concentration to affect markups or monetary policy. In this paper, we provide a new framework to study the link between market structure and monetary policy. We generalize the standard New Keynesian model by allowing for dynamic oligopolistic competition between any finite number of firms in each sector of the economy, also allowing for heterogeneity across sectors. In each sector, firms compete by setting their prices, but they do so in a staggered and infrequent manner due to nom- inal rigidities. We use this model to study the aggregate real effects of monetary shocks and highlight the restrictions imposed by monopolistic competition. Departing from mo- nopolistic competition to study oligopoly poses new challenges, because it requires solv- ing a dynamic game with strategic interactions at the sectoral level and embedding it into a general equilibrium macroeconomic model. We focus on Markov equilibria of our dy- namic game, where the pricing strategy, or reaction function, of every firm is a function of the prices of its competitors. Despite these complexities, our first result derives a closed-form formula for the re- sponse of aggregate output to small monetary shocks. Our formula inputs the cross- sectoral distribution of three sufficient statistics: market concentration as captured by the effective number of firms within a sector, demand elasticities, and markups. The intu- 1Rossi-Hansberg, Sarte and Trachter(2020) document, however, that diverging trends in national and local measures of concentration. We will discuss how to interpret our results in light of these two views. 2 ition is based on the link between the steady state markup that can be sustained in an oligopolistic equilibrium and the slope of the reaction function of each firm to the prices of its competitors. All else equal, steeper reaction functions lead to higher equilibrium markups: each firm has little incentives to cut prices when it knows that this would lead its rivals to cut prices as well for some time. Inverting the logic, we can infer from high observed markups that reaction functions are steep and therefore complementarities in pricing are strong, which in turn implies a slow pass-through of monetary shocks into prices and therefore large real effects on output. In this way, our formula encapsulates a tight restriction between endogenous markups and stickiness, conditional on demand elasticities.2 While our key sufficient statistics, demand elasticities and markups, can be estimated at any given point in time, they are endogenous objects that change in reaction to shifts in fundamentals. To perform counterfactual experiments, we take a more structural ap- proach and solve numerically the oligopolistic equilibrium in terms of fundamentals. We use a flexible Kimball(1995) demand system that allows us to parametrize separately demand elasticities and superelasticities, as the latter can affect monetary policy trans- mission through variable markups even under monopolistic competition. In our main exercise, we vary the number of firms n in each sector while keeping pref- erence parameters fixed. We find that higher concentration (lower n) can significantly amplify or dampen the real effects of monetary policy, depending on how properties of the residual demand vary with n. When preferences are CES, higher concentration am- plifies monetary policy transmission, but the maximal effects, attained under duopoly, remain limited: the half-life of the price level in reaction to monetary shocks is around 40% higher than under monopolistic competition. With Kimball preferences and suffi- ciently high superelasticity, higher concentration dampens monetary policy transmission. Moreover, the dampening can be arbitrarily large. We use evidence on the heterogeneity in idiosyncratic cost pass-through across small and large firms from Amiti, Itskhoki and Konings (2019) to calibrate how concentration affects the shape of demand functions, and find substantial amplification. The rise in the average Herfindahl index observed in the U.S. since 1990 increases the response of output (and decreases the response of inflation) to monetary shocks by around 15%. What explains these results? The number of competitors in a market has an effect on firms’ strategic incentives, but also on the shape of the residual demand faced by each 2In the standard monopolistic competition model desired markups are constant and only a function of the demand elasticity. However, in a strategic environment the endogenous markup is no longer a simple function of the demand elasticity. 3 firm. We disentangle the two ways through which oligopolistic competition differs from monopolistic competition. On the one hand, “feedback effects” make each firm care about its rivals’ current and future prices when setting its price. On the other hand, “strategic ef- fects” arise because each firm realizes its current pricing decision can affect how its rivals will set their prices in the future. We isolate these two effects for each n, by comparing the oligopolistic model with n firms to a “non-strategic” benchmark economy featuring monopolistic competition and Kimball preferences modified to match the elasticity and superelasticity of the residual demand in the finite n model. We find that departures from monopolistic competition are mostly working through feedback effects, that is changes in the shape of residual demand. While strategic effects matter for the level of steady state markups, they only have a modest impact on monetary
Recommended publications
  • Unemployment in an Extended Cournot Oligopoly Model∗
    Unemployment in an Extended Cournot Oligopoly Model∗ Claude d'Aspremont,y Rodolphe Dos Santos Ferreiraz and Louis-Andr´eG´erard-Varetx 1 Introduction Attempts to explain unemployment1 begin with the labour market. Yet, by attributing it to deficient demand for goods, Keynes questioned the use of partial analysis, and stressed the need to consider interactions between the labour and product markets. Imperfect competition in the labour market, reflecting union power, has been a favoured explanation; but imperfect competition may also affect employment through producers' oligopolistic behaviour. This again points to a general equilibrium approach such as that by Negishi (1961, 1979). Here we propose an extension of the Cournot oligopoly model (unlike that of Gabszewicz and Vial (1972), where labour does not appear), which takes full account of the interdependence between the labour market and any product market. Our extension shares some features with both Negishi's conjectural approach to demand curves, and macroeconomic non-Walrasian equi- ∗Reprinted from Oxford Economic Papers, 41, 490-505, 1989. We thank P. Champsaur, P. Dehez, J.H. Dr`ezeand J.-J. Laffont for helpful comments. We owe P. Dehez the idea of a light strengthening of the results on involuntary unemployment given in a related paper (CORE D.P. 8408): see Dehez (1985), where the case of monopoly is studied. Acknowledgements are also due to Peter Sinclair and the Referees for valuable suggestions. This work is part of the program \Micro-d´ecisionset politique ´economique"of Commissariat G´en´eral au Plan. Financial support of Commissariat G´en´eralau Plan is gratefully acknowledged.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 16 Oligopoly and Game Theory Oligopoly Oligopoly
    Chapter 16 “Game theory is the study of how people Oligopoly behave in strategic situations. By ‘strategic’ we mean a situation in which each person, when deciding what actions to take, must and consider how others might respond to that action.” Game Theory Oligopoly Oligopoly • “Oligopoly is a market structure in which only a few • “Figuring out the environment” when there are sellers offer similar or identical products.” rival firms in your market, means guessing (or • As we saw last time, oligopoly differs from the two ‘ideal’ inferring) what the rivals are doing and then cases, perfect competition and monopoly. choosing a “best response” • In the ‘ideal’ cases, the firm just has to figure out the environment (prices for the perfectly competitive firm, • This means that firms in oligopoly markets are demand curve for the monopolist) and select output to playing a ‘game’ against each other. maximize profits • To understand how they might act, we need to • An oligopolist, on the other hand, also has to figure out the understand how players play games. environment before computing the best output. • This is the role of Game Theory. Some Concepts We Will Use Strategies • Strategies • Strategies are the choices that a player is allowed • Payoffs to make. • Sequential Games •Examples: • Simultaneous Games – In game trees (sequential games), the players choose paths or branches from roots or nodes. • Best Responses – In matrix games players choose rows or columns • Equilibrium – In market games, players choose prices, or quantities, • Dominated strategies or R and D levels. • Dominant Strategies. – In Blackjack, players choose whether to stay or draw.
    [Show full text]
  • A Supergame-Theoretic Model of Business Cycles and Price Wars During Booms
    working paper department of economics A SUPERGAME-THEORETIC MODEL OF BUSINESS CYCLES AND PRICE WARS DURING BOOMS Julio J. Rotemberg and Garth Saloner* M.I.T. Working Paper #349 July 1984 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 021 39 Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from IVIIT Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/supergametheoret349rote model of 'a supergame-theoretic BUSINESS CYCLES AOT) PRICE WARS DURING BOOMS Julio J. Rotemberg and Garth Saloner* ' M.I.T. Working Paper #349 July 1984 ^^ ""' and Department of Economics --P^^^i^J^' *Slo.n ;-..>>ool of Management Lawrence summers -^.any^helpful^^ .ei;ix;teful to ^ames.Poterba and ^^^^^^^ from the Mationax do conversations, Financial support is gratefully acknowledged.^ SEt8209266 and SES-8308782 respectively) 12 ABSTRACT This paper studies implicitly colluding oligopolists facing fluctuating demand. The credible threat of future punishments provides the discipline that facilitates collusion. However, we find that the temptation to unilaterally deviate from the collusive outcome is often greater when demand is high. To moderate this temptation, the optimizing oligopoly reduces its profitability at such times, resulting in lower prices. If the oligopolists' output is an input to other sectors, their output may increase too. This explains the co-movements of outputs which characterize business cycles. The behavior of the railroads in the 1880' s, the automobile industry in the 1950's and the cyclical behavior of cement prices and price-cost margins support our theory. (j.E.L. Classification numbers: 020, 130, 610). I. INTRODUCTION This paper has two objectives. First it is an exploration of the way in which oligopolies behave over the business cycle.
    [Show full text]
  • GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58Th Street, Chicago, Ill
    THE PROCESS AND PROGRESS OF ECONOMICS Nobel Memorial Lecture, 8 December, 1982 by GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, Ill. 60637, USA In the work on the economics of information which I began twenty some years ago, I started with an example: how does one find the seller of automobiles who is offering a given model at the lowest price? Does it pay to search more, the more frequently one purchases an automobile, and does it ever pay to search out a large number of potential sellers? The study of the search for trading partners and prices and qualities has now been deepened and widened by the work of scores of skilled economic theorists. I propose on this occasion to address the same kinds of questions to an entirely different market: the market for new ideas in economic science. Most economists enter this market in new ideas, let me emphasize, in order to obtain ideas and methods for the applications they are making of economics to the thousand problems with which they are occupied: these economists are not the suppliers of new ideas but only demanders. Their problem is comparable to that of the automobile buyer: to find a reliable vehicle. Indeed, they usually end up by buying a used, and therefore tested, idea. Those economists who seek to engage in research on the new ideas of the science - to refute or confirm or develop or displace them - are in a sense both buyers and sellers of new ideas. They seek to develop new ideas and persuade the science to accept them, but they also are following clues and promises and explorations in the current or preceding ideas of the science.
    [Show full text]
  • Breaking the Mould: an Institutionalist Political Economy Alternative to the Neoliberal Theory of the Market and the State Ha-Joon Chang, May 2001
    Breaking the Mould An Institutionalist Political Economy Alternative to the Neoliberal Theory of the Market and the State Ha-Joon Chang Social Policy and Development United Nations Programme Paper Number 6 Research Institute May 2001 for Social Development The United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD) thanks the governments of Denmark, Finland, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom for their core funding. Copyright © UNRISD. Short extracts from this publication may be reproduced unaltered without authorization on condition that the source is indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to UNRISD, Palais des Nations, 1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland. UNRISD welcomes such applications. The designations employed in UNRISD publications, which are in conformity with United Nations practice, and the presentation of material therein do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of UNRISD con- cerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. The responsibility for opinions expressed rests solely with the author(s), and publication does not constitute endorse- ment by UNRISD. ISSN 1020-8208 Contents Acronyms ii Acknowledgements ii Summary/Résumé/Resumen iii Summary iii Résumé iv Resumen v 1. Introduction 1 2. The Evolution of the Debate: From “Golden Age Economics” to Neoliberalism 1 3. The Limits of Neoliberal Analysis of the Role of the State 3 3.1 Defining the free market (and state intervention) 4 3.2 Defining market failure 6 3.3 The market primacy assumption 8 3.4 Market, state and politics 11 4.
    [Show full text]
  • THE UN WOMEN GENDER and ECONOMICS TRAINING MANUAL © UN Women 2017
    TRAINING MANUAL THE UN WOMEN GENDER AND ECONOMICS TRAINING MANUAL © UN Women 2017. All rights reserved. This training manual on Gender and Economics is the result of extensive collaboration and consultation across UN Women. The preparation of the training manual was led by the Economic Empowerment Team in UN Women. Special thanks to Anuradha Seth and Mamadou Bobo Diallo for providing the leadership and support for this initiative. Invaluable support was provided by UN Women’s Training Centre and by the regional economic advisors for Europe & Central Asia and Asia & the Pacific. The contributions of Clemencia Munoz- Tamayo, Nilüfer Çagatay and Francisco Cos-Montiel are duly acknowledged. Thanks are also extended to Gabrielle Leite for production coordination, revision support and her attention to detail. The training manual benefited from the valuable inputs and feedback received from UN Women regional and country office programme staff: Sabawoon Ahmadzai (Afghanistan), May Babiker (Egypt), Erisa Cela (Albania), Ruangkhao Chanchai (Thailand), Alia El-Yassir (Turkey), Ramon Garlayee Garway (Liberia), Marie Laetitia Kayisire (Guinea Bissau), Jennet Kem (Sudan), Jamaluddin Khan (Pakistan), Loise Maina (Kenya), Enock Mugabi (Kenya), Amna Muharemovic (Bosnia and Herzegovina), Hadil Naser (Palestine), Da Barca Vieira Rosa Ondina Xavier (Mozambique), Dominika Stojanovska (Macedonia), Misrak Tamiru (Ethiopia), and Zhypargul Turmamatova (Kyrgyzstan). This initiative was made possible by financial support received from the Swiss Agency for Development
    [Show full text]
  • Efficiency Wages in Cournot-Oligopoly
    DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 12351 Efficiency Wages in Cournot-Oligopoly Marco de Pinto Laszlo Goerke MAY 2019 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 12351 Efficiency Wages in Cournot-Oligopoly Marco de Pinto IUBH University of Applied Science and IAAEU Trier Laszlo Goerke IAAEU, Trier University, IZA and CESifo MAY 2019 Any opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but IZA takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The IZA Institute of Labor Economics is an independent economic research institute that conducts research in labor economics and offers evidence-based policy advice on labor market issues. Supported by the Deutsche Post Foundation, IZA runs the world’s largest network of economists, whose research aims to provide answers to the global labor market challenges of our time. Our key objective is to build bridges between academic research, policymakers and society. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author. ISSN: 2365-9793 IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Schaumburg-Lippe-Straße 5–9 Phone: +49-228-3894-0 53113 Bonn, Germany Email: [email protected] www.iza.org IZA DP No. 12351 MAY 2019 ABSTRACT Efficiency Wages in Cournot-Oligopoly* In a Cournot-oligopoly with free but costly entry and business stealing, output per firm is too low and the number of competitors excessive, assuming labor productivity to depend on the number of employees only or to be constant.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Issues in Monetary Economics January 1970
    Some Issues in Monetary Economies* By DAVID I. FAND Public policies are continuously sought which will assist in guiding the economy between the perils of inflation and the dangers of unemployment and under-production. During the last five years the perils of inflation have become increasingly apparent, and during the past year stabilization actions have been taken to reduce the rate of advance of the price level. At the present time there is growing concern that these actions may lead the economy into a recession, What are the vehicles and avenues of stabilization policy which can best restore the econ- oniy to a satisfactory course, that is, a high and rising level of output and employment with a reasonably stable price level? Unfortunately, students of this problem are not in ~ubstan- tial agreement on an answer. Economists have tended to fall into two conflicting schools of thought regarding economic stabilization — the income-expenditure approach and the modern quantity theory of money approach. Until recently, the dominant school has been the modern version of the income-expendi- ture theory which has evolved from the work of John Maynard Keynes in the 1930’s. Policy- makers in the 1950’s and 1960’s generally adopted the theoretical framework of this school for the formulation of economic stabilization actions. Primary emphasis was given to fiscal actions — Federal government spending and taxing programs — in guiding the economy be- tween inflation and unemployment. During the last two decades, proponents of the modern quantity theory of money have increasingly challenged the basic propositions of the income- expenditure school.
    [Show full text]
  • The Post-Keynesian Economics of Credit and Debt Marc Lavoie
    The post-Keynesian economics of credit and debt Marc Lavoie Department of Economics, University of Ottawa November 2012 To take a not at all arbitrary example, a standard macroeconomic approach, the IS-LM model (don’t ask) told us that under depression-type conditions like those we’re experiencing, some of the usual rules would cease to apply: trillion-dollar budget deficits wouldn’t drive up interest rates, huge increases in the money supply wouldn’t cause runaway inflation. Economists who took that model seriously back in, say, early 2009 were ridiculed and lambasted for making such counterintuitive assertions. But their predictions came true. So yes, it’s possible to have social science with the power to predict events and, maybe, to lead to a better future. Paul Krugman, “Introduction” to Isaac Asimov, The Foundation Trilogy, The Folio Society, London, 2012, p. xv. Paul Krugman believes that it is enough to go back to the old IS-LM model to understand how the economy functions and to make predictions about what is about to happen. He is partially right and partially wrong. Certainly the current sophisticated models put forward by most of his mainstream colleagues did not allow for correct predictions. However, although we need to go back to macroeconomics before the new classical and rational expectations revolution, thus going beyond the representative agent with rational expectations (RARE as John King (2012) calls it), we certainly should not go back to the simple IS/LM model that Krugman is so enamoured with. The purpose of the session on the economics of credit and debt is to stimulate new thinking on credit and debt.
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamic Oligopoly with Network Effects*
    Dynamic Oligopoly with Network Effects* By Nicholas Economides**, Matt Mitchell*** and Andrzej Skrzypacz**** July 2005 Abstract We analyze oligopolistic competition in a multi-period dynamic setting for goods with network effects. Two or more infinitely-lived firms produce incompatible products differentiated in their inherent quality. Consumers live for a single period and receive the network effect of the previous period’s sales. We show existence and characterize Markov perfect equilibria that are unique given market shares at the beginning of time and fast convergence to the long run equilibrium. We find that, generally, small network effects help the higher quality firm realize higher prices, sales, and profits. Intermediate network effects lead eventually to monopoly of the firm that provides the higher inherent quality, irrespective of original market shares. Strong network effects lead to a stable monopoly equilibrium in the long run which is achieved by the firm of sufficiently high starting market share. Although the case of monopoly resulting under strong network effects and determined by original market shares has been understood in the academic literature and drives the traditional theory of “tilting” of networks to monopoly, our finding that, for intermediate network effects, the resulting monopoly is only determined by inherent quality is new and qualitatively different than traditional theories of titling to monopoly. We also find that, in the case of not-too-high network effects, the dominance of the high quality firm is accentuated as consumers become more patient. Finally, we analyze the impact of the intensity of network effects on the number of firms that survive at the long run equilibrium.
    [Show full text]
  • Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
    Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly Chapter Outline 1. Monopolistic Competition a. Product Differentiation b. Price and Output Determination c. Economic Efficiency 2. Oligopoly a. Oligopoly Models b. Game Theory c. Economic Performance d. Industrial Concentration Monopolistic Competition Monopolistic Competition – industry with many firms, easy entry, and product differentiation. Product Differentiation – creating a product with distinct positive identities in consumers minds. Demand Curve – downward sloping, more elastic than monopoly but less elastic than perfect competition Price and output determination in the short-run: looks identical to the monopoly case. Price and output determination in the long-run: because of entry of other firms profits will not be greater than zero. Therefore, there will be zero economic profits in the long-run. Efficiency: 1. Productive Efficiency – min AC, does not hold 2. Allocative Efficiency – P = MC, does not hold Oligopoly Models Oligopoly – industry with few firms, difficult entry, mutual interdependence, and standardized or differentiated product. Collusion – the act of working together to restrict output. Cartels act like monopolists in the output market. Cartel – the firms that collude. -- Prevailing output and price is that of the monopolist. Cournot Model – duopoly where each firm assumes that output of the other firms are given and the firms maximize profits. -- Prevailing output is between monopolist and perfect competition. Kinked Demand – oligopoly where each firm believes that their competitors will match price decreases but not their price increases. Chapter 13 Page 1 of 2 Case / Fair -- Results in downwardly sticky prices at the current price. Price-Leadership Model – model where the large firm (dominant) sets market price and all the smaller firms match the leaders price.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of the Business Cycle on Oligopoly Coordination: Evidence from the U.S
    The Journal of Applied Business Research – Second Quarter 2008 Volume 24, Number 2 The Effects Of The Business Cycle On Oligopoly Coordination: Evidence From The U.S. Aluminum Industry David I. Rosenbaum, University of Nebraska-Lincoln Sheng-Ping Yang, Black Hills State University ABSTRACT Haltiwanger and Harrington (1991) among others explore a theoretical study on the effects of demand fluctuations on the degree of oligopoly coordination. They specify that demand movements are deterministic as the assumption of independent, identically distributed demand shocks in each period is excluded. This paper empirically examines the hypothesis implied by the Haltiwanger and Harrington in which current prices and margins vary directly with expected future demand. We also explore the time series properties of demand shocks. Various lag structures are introduced into the estimation. The model is applied to the U.S. aluminum industry. Results support the predictions of the theoretical models. 1. INTRODUCTION altiwanger and Harrington (1991) among others explore a theoretical study on the effects of demand fluctuations on the degree of oligopoly coordination. They relax the assumption of independent, H identically distributed (i.i.d.) demand shocks from Rotemberg and Saloner’s model (1986) by allowing demand to follow a deterministic cycle in which both the level of demand and the expected direction of demand are allowed to change over time. The model indicates that an important factor influencing the incentive to cheat is the projected future path of demand. Consequently, they find that current prices and margins respond to expected demand and that firms behave most competitively in the early stages of a recession.
    [Show full text]