Market Failure and Government Failure
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Entrepreneurial Error Does Not Equal Market Failure
Munich Personal RePEc Archive Entrepreneurial Error Does Not Equal Market Failure Bagus, Philipp and Howden, David and Huerta de Soto Ballester, Jesús 1 May 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86706/ MPRA Paper No. 86706, posted 19 May 2018 00:57 UTC This article can be cited as: Bagus, Philipp, David Howden and Jesús Huerta de Soto Ballester. 2018. “Entrepreneurial Error Does Not Equal Market Failure.” Journal of Business Ethics 149(2): 433-41. It can be found at: https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s10551-016-3123-9 Entrepreneurial Error Does Not Equal Market Failure Philipp Bagus Universidad Rey Juan Carlos Department of Applied Economics I and History and Economic Institutions (and Moral Philosophy) Paseo Artilleros s/n. Madrid, 28032, Spain [email protected] David Howden Saint Louis University – Madrid Campus Department of Business and Economics Avenida del Valle, 34 Madrid, 28003, Spain [email protected] Jesús Huerta de Soto Ballester Universidad Rey Juan Carlos Department of Applied Economics I and History and Economic Institutions (and Moral Philosophy) Paseo Artilleros s/n. Madrid, 28032, Spain [email protected] Abstract: Barnett and Block (forthcoming) claim that Bagus and Howden (2012b) support indirectly the concept of market failure. In this paper we show that maturity mismatching in an unhampered market may imply entrepreneurial error but cannot be considered a market failure. We demonstrate why fractional-reserve banking leads to business cycles even if there is no central bank and why maturity mismatching does not per se lead to clusters of errors in a free market. -
A Different Approach to Investment
1 A Different Approach to Investment Chris Leithner Leithner & Co. Pty Ltd Leithner Investments Pty Ltd Level 3, Benson House 2 Benson Street Toowong, Queensland, Australia [email protected] www.leithner.com.au Paper Prepared for The Montreal Economic Institute 19 May 2005 “The opinions expressed in this text do not necessarily represent those of the Montreal Economic Institute or of the members of its board of directors.” The opinions expressed are those of Chris Leithner exclusively. 2 When a commodity is perfectly uniform or homogeneous in quality, any portion may be indifferently used in place of an equal portion: hence, in the same market, and at the same moment, all portions must be exchanged at the same ratio. There can be no reason why a person should treat exactly similar things differently, and the slightest excess in what is demanded for one over the other will cause him to take the latter instead of the former … Hence follows what is undoubtedly true, with proper explanations, that in the same open market, at any one moment, there cannot be two prices for the same kind of article. Such differences as may practically occur arise from extraneous circumstances, such as the defective credit of the purchasers, their imperfect knowledge of the market, and so on. William S. Jevons The Theory of Political Economy (1871) Entrepreneurial judgment cannot be bought on the market. The entrepreneurial idea that carries on and brings profit is precisely that idea which did not occur to the majority. It is not correct foresight as such that yields profits, but foresight better than that of the rest. -
Government Failure Justin Jefferson, NSW Lawyer, Writes in “The Land
Government Failure Justin Jefferson, NSW lawyer, writes in “The Land”: “People blaming the current financial crisis on the ‘free market’ are displaying a failure to understand the issues. Capitalism means the private ownership and control of the means of production. By definition, government monopoly control of the money supply is not capitalist. Government control of interest rates is not capitalist. Government cartelization of the banking industry is not capitalist. Government policies to encourage borrowing are not capitalist. Government taking money from all of society to pay for hand-outs to home-buyers, is not capitalist. The current crisis shows precisely the reasons why free market economics oppose such monetary policies. Though they are intended to replace capitalism with a better and fairer system, they always involve plundering the population to pay for privileges for political favourites of the right or left wing. Government’s expansion of money and credit causes inflation, and economic miscalculation on a massive scale: ‘bubbles’. But really government cannot generate wealth from nothing - it can only consume or redistribute wealth that people produce by work or savings. Although everyone decries the bust, the damage is done during the boom, when monetary policy induces vast system-wide malinvestments. In the process known as the bust, it falls to ordinary people to experience the hardships of washing out these massive malinvestments and re-allocating capital to productive uses; while politicians carry on their Santa Claus act using public money to bail out political favourites.” . -
The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis Joel P
Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business Volume 17 Issue 1 Winter Winter 1997 The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis Joel P. Trachtman Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/njilb Part of the International Trade Commons Recommended Citation Joel P. Trachtman, The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis, 17 Nw. J. Int'l L. & Bus. 470 (1996-1997) This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business by an authorized administrator of Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. The Theory of the Firm and the Theory of the International Economic Organization: Toward Comparative Institutional Analysis Joel P. Trachtman* Without a theory they had nothing to pass on except a mass of descriptive material waiting for a theory, or a fire. 1 While the kind of close comparative institutional analysis which Coase called for in The Nature of the Firm was once completely outside the universe of mainstream econo- mists, and remains still a foreign, if potentially productive enterrise for many, close com- parative analysis of institutions is home turf for law professors. Hierarchical arrangements are being examined by economic theorists studying the or- ganization of firms, but for less cosmic purposes than would be served3 by political and economic organization of the production of international public goods. I. INTRODUCrION: THE PROBLEM Debates regarding the competences and governance of interna- tional economic organizations such as the World Trade Organization * Associate Professor of International Law, The Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Tufts University. -
Twelve Market and Government Failures Leading to the 2008–09 Financial Crisis
Twelve Market and Government Failures Leading to the 2008–09 Financial Crisis Guillermo de la Dehesa Occasional Paper 80 30 Group of Thirty, Washington, DC About the Author Guillermo de la Dehesa is Chairman of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Group of Thirty. ISBN I-56708-149-5 Copies of this paper are available for $10 from: The Group of Thirty 1726 M Street, N.W., Suite 200 Washington, D.C. 20036 Tel.: (202) 331-2472 Fax: (202) 785-9423 E-mail: [email protected] WWW: http://www.group30.org Occasional Paper No. 80 Twelve Market and Government Failures Leading to the 2008–09 Financial Crisis Guillermo de la Dehesa Published by Group of Thirty© Washington, DC 2010 Contents Introduction 5 Homeownership 9 Subprime Mortgages 11 Securitization 15 Investors 17 Rating Agencies 19 Banks 21 Regulation 27 Supervision 33 Risk Management 35 Over-the-Counter Derivatives Markets and Credit Default Swaps 37 Basel II 39 Systemic Risk 41 Conclusion 45 Group of Thirty Members 47 Group of Thirty Publications since 1990 51 Introduction There is a market failure when the market fails to allocate its resources in an efficient manner. This assumes one of four things: it did not consider the external costs and benefits (social efficiency), it failed to produce the goods and services at a minimum cost demanded by the consum- ers (allocation efficiency), it has not utilized the minimum quantity of resources possible in the production of goods and services (technical efficiency), or it has not produced the goods and services at the lowest possible manufacturing costs (industrial efficiency). -
Rethinking Individualism and Collectivism: Evaluation of Theoretical Assumptions and Meta-Analyses
Psychological Bulletin Copyright 2002 by the American Psychological Association, Inc. 2002, Vol. 128, No. 1, 3–72 0033-2909/02/$5.00 DOI: 10.1037//0033-2909.128.1.3 Rethinking Individualism and Collectivism: Evaluation of Theoretical Assumptions and Meta-Analyses Daphna Oyserman, Heather M. Coon, and Markus Kemmelmeier University of Michigan Are Americans more individualistic and less collectivistic than members of other groups? The authors summarize plausible psychological implications of individualism–collectivism (IND-COL), meta- analyze cross-national and within-United States IND-COL differences, and review evidence for effects of IND-COL on self-concept, well-being, cognition, and relationality. European Americans were found to be both more individualistic—valuing personal independence more—and less collectivistic—feeling duty to in-groups less—than others. However, European Americans were not more individualistic than African Americans, or Latinos, and not less collectivistic than Japanese or Koreans. Among Asians, only Chinese showed large effects, being both less individualistic and more collectivistic. Moderate IND-COL effects were found on self-concept and relationality, and large effects were found on attribution and cognitive style. To contemporary Americans, being an individualist is not only permanent bonds formed among similar others in traditional soci- a good thing; it is a quintessentially American thing. However, the eties (mechanical solidarity)—a collective focus. Max Weber term individualism itself appears to have its roots outside of the (1930) contrasted individual-focused Western European Protes- North American continent, namely in the French Revolution. It tantism with collective-focused Catholicism. He saw the former as appears that individualism was first used to describe the negative promoting self-reliance and pursuit of personal interests and the influence of individual rights on the well-being of the common- latter as promoting permanent and hierarchical relationships. -
Building the Entrepreneurial State: a New Framework for Envisioning and Evaluating a Mission-Oriented Public Sector
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Mazzucato, Mariana Working Paper Building the entrepreneurial state: A new framework for envisioning and evaluating a mission-oriented public sector Working Paper, No. 824 Provided in Cooperation with: Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Suggested Citation: Mazzucato, Mariana (2015) : Building the entrepreneurial state: A new framework for envisioning and evaluating a mission-oriented public sector, Working Paper, No. 824, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Annandale-on-Hudson, NY This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/109993 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen -
Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust Alan J
College of William & Mary Law School William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository Faculty Publications Faculty and Deans 2005 Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust Alan J. Meese William & Mary Law School, [email protected] Repository Citation Meese, Alan J., "Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust" (2005). Faculty Publications. 57. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/facpubs/57 Copyright c 2005 by the authors. This article is brought to you by the William & Mary Law School Scholarship Repository. https://scholarship.law.wm.edu/facpubs Journal of Competition Law and Economics 1(1), 21-95 doi: 10.1093/joclec/nhiOO7 MARKET FAILURE AND NON-STANDARD CONTRACTING: HOW THE GHOST OF PERFECT COMPETITION STILL HAUNTS ANTITRUST Alan . Meese* ABSTRACT Modem antitrust policy has a 'love hate' relationship with non-standard contracts that can overcome market failure. On the one hand, courts have abandoned various per se rules that once condemned such agreements outright, concluding that many non-standard contracts may produce benefits that are cognizable under the antitrust laws. 1 The prospect of such benefits, it is said, compels courts to analyze these agreements under the Rule of Reason, under which the tribunal determines whether a given restraint enhances or destroys competition.2 At the same time, courts, scholars, and the enforcement agencies have embraced methods of rule of reason analysis that are unduly hostile to such agreements.3 In particular, courts and others are too quick to view such agreements and the market outcomes they produce as manifestations of market power. -
Wealth Creation and the Entrepreneurial State: Building Symbiotic Public-Private Partnerships
Wealth Creation and the Entrepreneurial State: building symbiotic public-private partnerships Mariana Mazzucato1, UCL ABSTRACT The paper argues that building dynamic public-private partnerships that confront the innovation challenges of the future requires rethinking the ‘public’ part of the partnership away from a pure ‘market failure’ framework. This involves (1) justifying public policy in terms of market shaping and making (not only ‘fixing’); (2) admitting the risks involved in policies that are aimed at affecting not only the rate of growth but also its strategic ‘direction’ (often providing the investor of first resort) function; (3) socialising both the risks and rewards of the collective value creation process. 1 Introduction How should the wealth that an economy generates be distributed? Moral as well as economic arguments about who should be entitled to what—whether paid in wages, retained profits, or dividend payments—frequently seek to link rewards to contributions, for reasons of fairness or efficiency. But how these contributions are quantified depends first on how they are theorized. In this way, different theories of how value is created can be used to justify very different distributions of income and wealth. If entrepreneurs are believed to make extraordinary contributions to value creation, then maybe extraordinary rewards are justified? If hedge fund managers really do create more wealth than small nations, then might their initial rewards be both efficient and fair? In this paper we argue that the contribution to value creation by the state—the different parts of the public sector—has been problematically theorized. Understating the contribution of the state has meant that the contribution of other actors has been overstated, with consequences for the overall distribution of income and wealth. -
Fiscal Responsibility in Advanced Economies Through Investment for Economic Recovery from the COVID-19 Pandemic
Fiscal responsibility in advanced economies through investment for economic recovery from the COVID-19 pandemic Nicholas Stern and Dimitri Zenghelis Policy insight March 2021 The Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP) was established in 2008 to advance public and private action on climate change through rigorous, innovative research. The Centre is hosted jointly by the University of Leeds and the London School of Economics and Political Science. It is funded by the UK Economic and Social Research Council. www.cccep.ac.uk The Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment was established in 2008 at the London School of Economics and Political Science. The Institute brings together international expertise on economics, as well as finance, geography, the environment, international development and political economy to establish a world-leading centre for policy-relevant research, teaching and training in climate change and the environment. It is funded by the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment, which also funds the Grantham Institute – Climate Change and the Environment at Imperial College London. www.lse.ac.uk/grantham/ About the authors Nicholas Stern is IG Patel Professor for Economics and Government, and Chair of the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London School of Economics and Political Science. Dimitri Zenghelis is Project Leader on the Wealth Economy project at the Bennett Institute for Public Policy, University of Cambridge and a Visiting Senior Fellow to the Grantham Research Institute. Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank Ehtisham Ahmad, Amar Bhattacharya, Alex Bowen, Sam Fankhauser, Russell Jones, John Llewellyn, Annabel Manley, Bob Ward and Julia Wdowin for their invaluable comments on an earlier draft of this paper. -
Oliver Williamson and Elinor Ostrom
Submitted to Review of Political Economy A Nobel Prize for Governance and Institutions: Oliver Williamson and Elinor Ostrom PETER E. EARL* & JASON POTTS** School of Economics, University of Queensland, St Lucia, Brisbane, QLD4072, Australia * [email protected] (corresponding author) ** [email protected] Abstract This paper reviews the 2009 Nobel Prize in Economics jointly awarded to Oliver Williamson for his work on governance in organizations and the boundaries of the firm and to Elinor Ostrom for her work on the governance of common pool resources. We review the careers and research contributions of Williamson and Ostrom to the theory and analysis of economic institutions of governance. Both winners of this Prize for ‘economic governance’ are thoroughly deserved, yet like the Hayek-Myrdal Prize of 1974 their respective approaches, methods and findings are almost diametrically opposed. Williamson offers a top-down contracts-based solution to the incentive problems of opportunism in corporate governance, whereas Ostrom offers a bottom-up communication-based solution to the governance opportunities of community resources. We offer some critical comments on Williamson’s analytic work and discussion of the potential for further application of Ostrom’s case study based experimental methodology. We conclude with a suggested third nominee to make better sense of how these two great scholar’s works fit together, namely George Richardson. Keywords: Nobel Prize in Economics, opportunism, common pool resources, bounded rationality, institutions, governance JEL classification codes: B31, B52, D23, 1 1. Introduction The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (often referred to as the Nobel Prize in Economics) was jointly awarded in 2009 to Oliver Williamson and Elinor Ostrom for the study of institutions of governance: Williamson for work on institutions to overcome opportunism in firms with asset specificity; Ostrom for institutions of governance of common pool resources. -
Humanitarian Military Intervention: the Conditions for Success
Humanitarian military intervention is not an oxymoron but a central policy challenge of S our times. What are the conditions for success and failure? Taylor Seybolt’s thoroughly E documented and rigorously argued cases provide specific answers about when, Y B HUMANITARIAN where and how we should rescue war victims with military force. O Thomas G. Weiss L Presidential Professor of Political Science, City University of New York T MILITARY Taylor Seybolt’s book is essential reading for anyone interested in humanitarian H intervention. It is the leading study on when humanitarian intervention will produce U M humanitarian results, and when it will only make things worse. A INTERVENTION Stephen Van Evera N Professor of Political Science, Massachusetts Institute of Technology I T A THE CONDITIONS FOR Moving beyond debates about legality and legitimacy, this work is a systematic R I attempt to apply measures of success to humanitarian interventions. The difficulties A of this analysis are fully acknowledged—and fully engaged. The result is a carefully N SUCCESS AND FAILURE argued, richly detailed study, an original and important contribution to the literature. M I Jim Whitman L I Co-editor, Journal of Humanitarian Assistance T A Humanitarian Military Intervention focuses on the questions of when and how R Y military intervention in conflicts can achieve humanitarian benefits. It argues that an I intervention can be justified only when decision makers are reasonably sure that it N T will do more good than harm. As the measure of success, the book develops a E methodology to determine the number of lives saved.