1 MACROECONOMICS Should Policy Be Active Or Passive?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

1 MACROECONOMICS Should Policy Be Active Or Passive? In this chapter, you will learn… C H A P T E R 14 …about two policy debates: Stabilization Policy 1. Should policy be active or passive? 2. Should policy be by rule or discretion? MACROECONOMICS SIXTH EDITION N. GREGORY MANKIW PowerPoint® Slides by Ron Cronovich © 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 1 Growth rate of real GDP, 1970-2006 Question 1: Percent 10 change from 4 8 quarters Should policy be active or earlier 6 passive? Average 4 growth rate 2 0 -2 -4 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 2 Increase in unemployment during Arguments for active policy recessions increase in no. of . Recessions cause economic hardship for millions peak trough unemployed persons (millions) of people. July 1953 May 1954 2.11 . The Employment Act of 1946: Aug 1957 April 1958 2.27 “It is the continuing policy and responsibility of the April 1960 February 1961 1.21 Federal Government to…promote full employment December 1969 November 1970 2.01 and production.” November 1973 March 1975 3.58 January 1980 July 1980 1.68 . The model of aggregate demand and supply July 1981 November 1982 4.08 (Chaps. 9-13) shows how fiscal and monetary July 1990 March 1991 1.67 policy can respond to shocks and stabilize the March 2001 November 2001 1.50 economy. CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 4 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 5 1 Arguments against active policy Automatic stabilizers Policies act with long & variable lags, including: . definition: inside lag: policies that stimulate or depress the economy the time between the shock and the policy response. when necessary without any deliberate policy . takes time to recognize shock change. takes time to implement policy, . Designed to reduce the lags associated with especially fiscal policy stabilization policy. outside lag: . Examples: the time it takes for policy to affect economy. income tax If conditions change before policy’s impact is felt, . unemployment insurance the policy may destabilize the economy. welfare CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 6 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 7 Forecasting the macroeconomy The LEI index and real GDP, 1960s 20 Because policies act with lags, policymakers must The Index of 15 predict future conditions. Leading Economic 10 Two ways economists generate forecasts: Indicators 5 . Leading economic indicators includes 10 data series that fluctuate in advance of the data series 0 -5 economy (see p.258 ). annual percentage change . Macroeconometric models -10 Large-scale models with estimated parameters 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 that can be used to forecast the response of source of LEI data: Leading Economic Indicators The Conference Board Real GDP endogenous variables to shocks and policies CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 8 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 9 The LEI index and real GDP, 1970s The LEI index and real GDP, 1980s 20 20 15 e 15 g n 10 a 10 h c 5 e 5 g a 0 t 0 n e -5 c r -5 e p -10 l -10 a u -15 n -15 annual percentage change n -20 a -20 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 source of LEI data: Leading Economic Indicators source of LEI data: Leading Economic Indicators The Conference Board Real GDP The Conference Board Real GDP CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 10 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 11 2 Mistakes forecasting the 1982 recession The LEI index and real GDP, 1990s 15 e e t g 10 a n r a t h n c 5 e e m g y a t 0 o n l e p c r m e -5 e p l n a U u -10 n n a -15 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 source of LEI data: Leading Economic Indicators The Conference Board Real GDP CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 12 Forecasting the macroeconomy The Lucas critique Because policies act with lags, policymakers must . Due to Robert Lucas predict future conditions. who won Nobel Prize in 1995 for rational expectations. The preceding slides show that the . Forecasting the effects of policy changes has forecasts are often wrong. often been done using models estimated with This is one reason why some historical data. economists oppose policy activism. Lucas pointed out that such predictions would not be valid if the policy change alters expectations in a way that changes the fundamental relationships between variables. CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 14 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 15 An example of the Lucas critique The Jury’s out… . Prediction (based on past experience): Looking at recent history does not clearly answer An increase in the money growth rate will reduce Question 1: unemployment. It’s hard to identify shocks in the data. The Lucas critique points out that increasing the . It’s hard to tell how things would have been money growth rate may raise expected inflation, different had actual policies not been used. in which case unemployment would not necessarily fall. Most economists agree, though, that the U.S. economy has become much more stable since the late 1980s… CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 16 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 17 3 The stability of the modern economy Question 2: n 4.0 o i t a i Volatility 3.5 Should policy be conducted by v e of GDP d 3.0 d rule or discretion? r rule or discretion? a d 2.5 n a t 2.0 S 1.5 1.0 Volatility of 0.5 Inflation 0.0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 18 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 19 Rules and discretion: Arguments for rules Basic concepts . Policy conducted by rule: 1. Distrust of policymakers and the political Policymakers announce in advance how process policy will respond in various situations, . misinformed politicians and commit themselves to following through. politicians’ interests sometimes not the same . Policy conducted by discretion: as the interests of society As events occur and circumstances change, policymakers use their judgment and apply whatever policies seem appropriate at the time. CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 20 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 21 Arguments for rules Examples of time inconsistency 2. The time inconsistency of discretionary 1. To encourage investment, policy govt announces it will not tax income from capital. def: A scenario in which policymakers But once the factories are built, have an incentive to renege on a govt reneges in order to raise more tax revenue. previously announced policy once others have acted on that announcement. Destroys policymakers’ credibility, thereby reducing effectiveness of their policies. CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 22 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 23 4 Examples of time inconsistency Monetary policy rules a. Constant money supply growth rate 2. To reduce expected inflation, the central bank announces it will tighten . Advocated by monetarists. monetary policy. Stabilizes aggregate demand only if velocity is stable. But faced with high unemployment, the central bank may be tempted to cut interest rates. CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 24 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 26 Monetary policy rules Monetary policy rules a. Constant money supply growth rate a. Constant money supply growth rate b. Target growth rate of nominal GDP b. Target growth rate of nominal GDP . Automatically increase money growth c. Target the inflation rate whenever nominal GDP grows slower than . Automatically reduce money growth whenever targeted; decrease money growth when inflation rises above the target rate. nominal GDP growth exceeds target. Many countries’ central banks now practice inflation targeting, but allow themselves a little discretion. CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 27 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 28 Monetary policy rules The Taylor Rule a. Constant money supply growth rate iff = π + 2 + 0.5 (π – 2) – 0.5 (GDP gap) b. Target growth rate of nominal GDP where c. Target the inflation rate iff = nominal federal funds rate target d. The Taylor rule: Y !Y GDP gap = 100 x Target the federal funds rate based on Y . inflation rate = percent by which real GDP . gap between actual & full-employment GDP is below its natural rate CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 29 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 30 5 The federal funds rate: The Taylor Rule Actual and suggested iff = π + 2 + 0.5 (π – 2) – 0.5 (GDP gap) t 12 n e c If = 2 and output is at its natural rate, r 10 Actual . π e then fed funds rate targeted at 4 percent. P 8 . For each one-point increase in π, 6 mon. policy is automatically tightened to raise fed funds rate by 1.5. 4 . For each one percentage point that GDP falls 2 Taylor’s Rule below its natural rate, mon. policy automatically 0 eases to reduce the fed funds rate by 0.5. 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 31 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 32 Inflation and central bank Central bank independence independence n o i . A policy rule announced by central bank will t a l f work only if the announcement is credible. n i e g . Credibility depends in part on degree of a r e independence of central bank. v a index of central bank independence CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 33 CHAPTER 14 Stabilization Policy slide 34 Chapter Summary Chapter Summary 1. Advocates of active policy believe: 3. Advocates of discretionary policy believe: . frequent shocks lead to unnecessary fluctuations in . discretion gives more flexibility to policymakers in output and employment responding to the unexpected . fiscal and monetary policy can stabilize the economy 4.
Recommended publications
  • The Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy As Stabilization Policy
    The Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy as Stabilization Policy Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley July 2005 This paper was presented at the Bank of Korea International Conference, The Effectiveness of Stabilization Policies, Seoul, May 2005. I am grateful to my discussants, Takatoshi Ito and Chung Mo Koo, and other conference participants for comments on an earlier draft. I. Introduction Perspectives among economists on the usefulness of fiscal policy as a device for macroeconomic management have moved back and forth over the years. Belief in the active use of the tools of fiscal policy may have reached a relative peak sometime during the 1960s or early 1970s, and practice followed theory. In the United States, perhaps the best illustration of the evolution of theory and practice comes from the investment tax credit (ITC), which, when it was in effect, provided businesses with a strong incentive for equipment investment. The ITC, first introduced during the Kennedy administration in 1962, at a rate of 7 percent, was adjusted frequently in response to changes in economic conditions. It was strengthened in 1964, the same year in which major income tax reductions were introduced, suspended in 1966 during a boom associated with the Vietnam War, reinstated in 1967, “permanently” repealed in 1969 during a period of inflationary pressure, reinstated again in 1971, just after the trough of the first recession since early 1961, and increased to a rate of 10 percent in 1974, toward the end of the next recession. Although not necessarily conceived originally as a tool for stabilization policy, the ITC clearly became one during this period.
    [Show full text]
  • Argentina's Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies After the Convertibility
    CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH April Argentina’s Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies after the Convertibility Regime Collapse • ii Contents Introduction 1 1. The Convertibility Regime 2 2. The Post-Convertibility Macroeconomic Regime and Performance 9 2.1 The Main Characteristics of the Economic Recovery 10 2.2 The Evolution of Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies 16 3. A Macroeconomic Policy Regime with a SCRER as an Intermediate Target 25 3.1 The Orthodox Arguments Against RER Targeting 26 3.2 The Exchange Rate Policy 29 3.3 The Exchange Market and Capital Flows 30 3.4 Monetary Policy 31 Conclusion 35 References 36 Chronological Appendix 39 About the Authors Roberto Frenkel is a senior research associate at the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, D.C. and Principal Research Associate at the Centro de Estudios de Estado y Sociedad (CEDES) in Buenos Aires, Argentina. Martín Rapetti is a research assistant at CEDES and a Ph.D. candidate at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst. Acknowledgements This paper was written as part of an international research project on Alternatives to Inflation Targeting for Stable and Equitable Growth co-directed by Gerald Epstein, PERI and Erinc Yeldan, Bilkent University. The authors thank the Rockefeller Brothers Fund, Ford Foundation and UN-DESA for financial support. Additionally, Nelson Barbosa-Filho, Erinc Yeldan and the participants in the workshop on “Alternatives to Inflation Targeting Monetary Policy for Stable and Egalitarian Growth in Developing Countries” held at CEDES in May 13-14, 2005 contributed comments to a previous version of this paper. Finally, the authors thank Julia Frenkel for her collaboration and Erinc Yeldan and an anonymous referee from World Development for their comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Inflation Target Adjustment in Stabilization Policy
    The Role of Inflation Target Adjustment in Stabilization Policy∗ Yunjong Eoy Denny Liez This version: October 31, 2017 Abstract How and under what circumstances can adjusting the inflation target serve as a stabilization-policy tool and contribute to welfare improvement? We answer these questions quantitatively with a standard New Keynesian model that includes cost-push type shocks which create a trade-off between inflation and output gap stabilization. We show that this trade-off leads to a non-trivial welfare cost under a standard Taylor rule, even with optimized policy coefficients. We then propose an additional policy tool of an inflation target rule and find that the optimal target needs to be adjusted in a persistent manner and in the opposite direction to the realization of a cost-push shock. The inflation target rule, combined with a Taylor rule, significantly reduces fluctuations in inflation originating from the cost-push shocks and mitigates the policy trade-off, resulting in a similar level of welfare to that associated with the Ramsey optimal policy. The welfare implications of the inflation target rule are more pronounced under a flatter Phillips curve. JEL Classification: E12; E32; E58; E61; Keywords: Welfare analysis; Monetary policy; Cost-push shocks; Medium-run in- flation targeting; Flat Phillips curve; ∗We thank James Bullard, Efrem Castelnuovo, Chris Edmond, Nicolas Groshenny, Joonyoung Hur, Jinill Kim, Mariano Kulish, Jae Won Lee, James Morley, Ed Nelson, Adrian Pagan, Bruce Preston, Jae W. Sim, Inhwan So, Willem Van Zandweghe, Toshiaki
    [Show full text]
  • Intermediate Macroeconomics: New Keynesian Model
    Intermediate Macroeconomics: New Keynesian Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 1 Introduction Among mainstream academic economists and policymakers, the leading alternative to the real business cycle theory is the New Keynesian model. Whereas the real business cycle model features monetary neutrality and emphasizes that there should be no active stabilization policy by govern- ments, the New Keynesian model builds in a friction that generates monetary non-neutrality and gives rise to a welfare justification for activist economic policies. New Keynesian economics is sometimes caricatured as being radically different than real business cycle theory. This caricature is unfair. The New Keynesian model is built from exactly the same core that our benchmark model is { there are optimizing households and firms, who interact in markets and whose interactions give rise to equilibrium prices and allocations. There is really only one fundamental difference in the New Keynesian model relative to the real business cycle model { nominal prices are assumed to be \sticky." By \sticky" I simply mean that there exists some friction that prevents Pt, the money price of goods, from adjusting quickly to changing conditions. This friction gives rise to monetary non-neutrality and means that the competitive equilibrium outcome of the economy will, in general, be inefficient. New Keynesian economics is to be differentiated from \old" Keynesian economics. Old Keyne- sian economics arose out of the Great Depression, adopting its name from John Maynard Keynes. Old Keynesian models were typically much more ad hoc than the optimizing models with which we work and did not feature very serious dynamics.
    [Show full text]
  • Stabilizing Expectations Under Monetary and Fiscal Policy Coordination
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Stabilizing Expectations under Monetary and Fiscal Policy Coordination Stefano Eusepi Bruce Preston Staff Report no. 343 September 2008 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Stabilizing Expectations under Monetary and Fiscal Policy Coordination Stefano Eusepi and Bruce Preston Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 343 September 2008 JEL classification: E52, D83, D84 Abstract This paper analyzes how the formation of expectations constrains monetary and fiscal policy design. Economic agents have imperfect knowledge about the economic environment and the policy regime in place. Households and firms learn about the policy regime using historical data. Regime uncertainty substantially narrows, relative to a rational expectations analysis of the model, the menu of policies consistent with expectations stabilization. When agents are learning about the policy regime, there is greater need for policy coordination: the specific choice of monetary policy limits the set of fiscal policies consistent with macroeconomic stability—and simple Taylor-type rules frequently lead to expectations-driven instability. In contrast, non-Ricardian fiscal policies combined with an interest rate peg promote stability. Resolving uncertainty about the prevailing monetary policy regime improves stabilization policy, enlarging the menu of policy options consistent with stability. However, there are limits to the benefits of communicating the monetary policy regime: the more heavily indebted the economy, the greater is the likelihood of expectations-driven instability.
    [Show full text]
  • Activist Stabilization Policy and Inflation: the Taylor Rule in the 1970S
    Activist Stabilization Policy and Inflation: The Taylor Rule in the 1970s Athanasios Orphanides∗ Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System February 2000 Abstract A number of recent studies have suggested that activist stabilization policy rules responding to inflation and the output gap can attain simultaneously a low and stable rate of inflation as well as a high degree of economic stability. The foremost example of such a strategy is the policy rule proposed by Taylor (1993). In this paper, I demonstrate that the policy settings that would have been suggested by this rule during the 1970s, based on real- time data published by the U.S. Commerce Department, do not greatly differ from actual policy during this period. To the extent macroeconomic outcomes during this period are considered unfavorable, this raises questions regarding the usefulness of this strategy for monetary policy. To the extent the Taylor rule is believed to provide a reasonable guide to monetary policy, this finding raises questions regarding earlier critiques of monetary policy during the 1970s. Keywords: Great Inflation, Taylor rule, output gap, real-time data. JEL Classification System: E3, E52, E58. Correspondence: Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, D.C. 20551, USA. Tel.: (202) 452-2654, e-mail: [email protected]. ∗ I would like to thank David Lindsey and Richard Porter for helpful discussions and comments. The opinions expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1 Introduction There is widespread agreement that the objective of monetary policy in the United States over the past several decades has been the pursuit of price stability and maximum sustain- able growth over time.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Policy, Growth, and Design of Stabilization Programs
    Fiscal Policy, Growth, and Design of Stabilization Programs Vito Tanzi The objectives of Fund-supported stabilization programs include a balance of payments viable over the medium run, the promotion of growth under a stable economic environment, price stability, and the prevention of excessive growth in external debt. These objectives do not have the same weight, but each is important in stabilization pro- grams. A narrow interpretation of the Fund's role would emphasize the balance of payments objective and de-emphasize the others. This paper deals with the role of fiscal policy in stabilization pro- grams, emphasizing the structural aspects of fiscal policies since, over the years, these aspects have attracted less attention than has demand management. The Baker initiative of October 1985 called attention to the importance of these structural aspects. The paper does not discuss other elements of program design, such as incentive measures imple- mented through the exchange rate, through import liberalization, through financial deregulation, or through pricing policy, even though these structural elements are obviously important. In coun- tries where institutions necessary for the effective use of other policies are not adequately developed, fiscal policy may be the main avenue to economic development and stability, although, unfortunately, politi- cal pressures, external shocks, and administrative shortcomings have frequently weakened government control over this instrument. Tax evasion, inflation, and the proliferation of exonerations have reduced the government's ability to control tax revenues, while political pres- sures, fragmentation of the public sector, and inadequate monitoring 121 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 122 VITO TANZI systems have undermined its ability to keep public expenditure in check.
    [Show full text]
  • Effective Demand Failures and the Limits of Monetary Stabilization Policy
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EFFECTIVE DEMAND FAILURES AND THE LIMITS OF MONETARY STABILIZATION POLICY Michael Woodford Working Paper 27768 http://www.nber.org/papers/w27768 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 2020, Revised September 2021 An earlier version was presented at the 2020 NBER Summer Institute under the title “Pandemic Shocks, Effective Demand, and Stabilization Policy.” I would like to thank Aloísio Araújo, Gauti Eggertsson, Guido Lorenzoni, Argia Sbordone, Ludwig Straub, Harald Uhlig, and Iván Werning for helpful comments, and Yeji Sung for research assistance. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2020 by Michael Woodford. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Effective Demand Failures and the Limits of Monetary Stabilization Policy Michael Woodford NBER Working Paper No. 27768 September 2020, Revised September 2021 JEL No. E12,E52,E63 ABSTRACT The challenge for stabilization policy presented by the COVID-19 pandemic stems above all from disruption of the circular flow of payments, resulting in a failure of what Keynes (1936) calls “effective demand.” As a consequence, economic activity in many sectors can be inefficiently low, and interest-rate policy cannot eliminate the distortions — not because of a limit on the extent to which interest rates can be reduced, but because interest-rate reductions fail to stimulate demand of the right sorts.
    [Show full text]
  • Explain the Strategy Behind Government Policies to Stabilize the Economy and the Specific Role of the Federal Reserve.”
    Macroeconomics Topic 9: “Explain the strategy behind government policies to stabilize the economy and the specific role of the Federal Reserve.” Reference: Gregory Mankiw’s Principles of Microeconomics, 2nd edition, Chapter 20. Smoothing out the fluctuations: stabilization policy Real GDP in the United States has grown at about 3.3% per year since about 1875. Overtime this has led to the US becoming one of the richest countries in the world. Unfortunately, this growth in real GDP has not been smooth. In some years (expansions) GDP grows much faster than the long term trend, and inflation often increases. while in others (called recessions) real GDP falls. The pattern of recessions and expansion is called the business cycle by economists. Since the burden of poor economic performance during recessions falls principally on the unemployed, policy aimed at eliminating the fluctuations associated with the business cycle seems desirable to most people. Government policy designed to smooth out the business cycle are called stabilization policies. The two primary types of stabilization policy used in the United States are monetary and fiscal policy. Monetary policy Monetary policy attempts to reduce the fluctuations in nominal GDP and unemployment by manipulating the rate of growth in the money supply. Monetary policy is carried out by Federal Reserve Bank’s open market committee. The general strategy is to increase money growth during periods of higher unemployment (recession) and reduce money growth during periods of inflation (excess expansion) Why does increasing the money supply raise aggregate demand? Economists following the writings of John Maynard Keynes believe that recessions stem mostly from unusually low aggregate demand for final goods and services.
    [Show full text]
  • Evolution of Economic Understanding and Postwar Stabilization Policy
    The Evolution of Economic Understanding and Postwar Stabilization Policy Christina D. Romer David H. Romer Introduction I Over the past fifty years, there have been large changes in aggregate demand policy in the United States, and, as a consequence, substantial changes in economic performance. In the 1950s, monetary and fiscal policy were somewhat erratic, but moderate and aimed at low infla- tion. As a result, inflation was indeed low, and recessions were fre- quent but mild. In the 1960s and 1970s, both monetary policy and fis- cal policy were used aggressively to stimulate and support rapid eco- nomic growth, and for much of the period unemployment was remark- ably low. But inflation became a persistent problem, and periodic severe recessions were necessary to keep inflation in check. In the 1980s and 1990s, aggregate demand policy became more temperate and once again committed to low inflation. Not surprisingly, inflation has been firmly under control for almost twenty years now, and the American economy experienced two decade-long expansions at the end of the twentieth century, interrupted only by one of the mildest postwar recessions. Given the consequences of these changes in policy, it is important to understand what has caused them. Our contention is that the funda- mental source of changes in policy has been changes in policymakers’ beliefs about how the economy functions. We find that while the basic 11 12 Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer objectives of policymakers have remained the same, the model or framework they have used to understand the economy has changed dramatically. There has been, as our title suggests, an evolution of eco- nomic understanding.
    [Show full text]
  • The Austral Plan
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance, Volume 2: The Country Studies -- Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey D. Sachs, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press, 1990 Volume ISBN: 0-226-73333-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/sach90-1 Conference Date: September 21-23, 1987 Publication Date: January 1990 Chapter Title: The Austral Plan Chapter Author: Rudiger Dornbusch, Juan Carlos de Pablo Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c8927 Chapter pages in book: (p. 91 - 114) 91 ArgentindChapter 5 inevitable because the inflation tax, with sufficient financial adaptation, can be almost entirely evaded and hence the budget deficit cannot be financed. The Olivera-Tanzi effect, the shortening of contracts, and financial adaptation all react in a perverse way (from the point of view of stabilization) in that they widen the deficit and accelerate explosively the inflation process. 4.4 Concluding Remarks: Why Stabilization Is Difficult The preceding discussion has an immediate bearing on the fact that stabiliza- tion is difficult and, more often than not, takes more than one attempt to succeed. In the process of high inflation all institutions melt. When stabilization is undertaken, there is neither immediate, spontaneous resumption of longer adjustment periods for wages and prices, nor an instant increase of real money demand to noninflationary levels. As a result, more sizable adjustments in the budget are required and more dramatic measures are necessary to create the confidence that stabilization will last.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Monetary Stabilization Policy∗
    Optimal Monetary Stabilization Policy∗ Michael Woodford Columbia University Revised October 2010 Contents 1 Optimal Policy in a Canonical New Keynesian Model . 3 1.1 The Problem Posed . 4 1.2 Optimal Equilibrium Dynamics . 7 1.3 The Value of Commitment . 13 1.4 Implementing Optimal Policy through Forecast Targeting . 17 1.5 Optimality from a \Timeless Perspective" . 24 1.6 Consequences of the Interest-Rate Lower Bound . 31 1.7 Optimal Policy Under Imperfect Information . 40 2 Stabilization and Welfare . 44 2.1 Microfoundations of the Basic New Keynesian Model . 44 2.2 Welfare and the Optimal Policy Problem . 50 2.3 Local Characterization of Optimal Dynamics . 54 2.4 A Welfare-Based Quadratic Objective . 63 2.4.1 The Case of an Efficient Steady State . 64 2.4.2 The Case of Small Steady-State Distortions . 69 2.4.3 The Case of Large Steady-State Distortions . 71 2.5 Second-Order Conditions for Optimality . 74 2.6 When is Price Stability Optimal? . 76 3 Generalizations of the Basic Model . 79 3.1 Alternative Models of Price Adjustment . 79 3.1.1 Structural Inflation Inertia . 81 3.1.2 Sticky Information . 88 3.2 Which Price Index to Stabilize? . 92 ∗Prepared for the new (2010) volumes of the Handbook of Monetary Economics, edited by Ben- jamin M. Friedman and Michael Woodford. I would like to thank Ozge Akinci, Ryan Chahrour, V.V. Chari, Marc Giannoni and Ivan Werning for comments, Luminita Stevens for research assistance, and the National Science Foundation for research support under grant SES-0820438. 3.2.1 Sectoral Heterogeneity and Asymmetric Disturbances .
    [Show full text]