TARGET2 Unlimited: Monetary Policy Implications of Asymmetric Liquidity Management within the Euro Area José M. Abad, Axel Löffler and Holger Zemanek No. 248, July 2011

Abstract This paper analyses the implications of a continued divergence of TARGET2 balances for monetary policy in the euro area. The accumulation of TARGET2 claims (liabilities) would make the ECB’s liquidity management asymmetric once the TARGET2 claims in core countries have crowded out credit in those regions. Then while providing scarce liquidity to banks in countries with TARGET2 liabilities, the ECB will need to absorb excess liquidity in countries with TARGET2 claims. We discuss three alternatives and their implications for absorbing excess liquidity in core regions: 1) using market-based measures might accelerate the capital flight from periphery to core countries and would add to the accumulation of risky assets by the ECB; 2) conducting non-market based measures, such as imposing differential (unremunerated) reserve requirements, would distort banking markets and would support the development of shadow banking; and 3) staying passive would lead to decreasing interest rates in core Europe entailing inflationary pressure and overinvestment in those regions and possibly future instability of the banking system. JEL: E42, E52, E58, F32, F36 Keywords: TARGET2 balances, monetary policy, euro area, , excess liquidity

Introduction A paper by Sinn (2011b) on the stealthily positions, which are recorded in the balance financed current account deficits in the euro area sheets of the Eurosystem’s national central by the (ECB) has sparked banks, began to diverge with the outbreak of the a controversial debate on the offspring, financial crisis back in 2007. Until now, the development and broader implications of (BB) has accumulated TARGET2 (im-)balances.1 Individual TARGET2 claims of more than €300 billion against the central banks of Greece, Ireland, Portugal and

Spain (hereafter ‘GIPS’). 1 TARGET2 is the Eurosystem’s real-time gross payment (and securities) settlement system. The ‘Eurosystem’ comprises the ECB and the ’s national central banks.

José M. Abad ([email protected]), Axel Löffler ([email protected]) and Holger Zemanek ([email protected]) are researchers at the Institute for Economic Policy, University of Leipzig. An earlier version of this paper is available on SSRN (http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/ papers.cfm?abstract_id=1875565). CEPS Policy Briefs present concise, policy-oriented analyses of topical issues in European affairs, with the aim of interjecting the views of CEPS researchers and associates into the policy-making process in a timely fashion. Unless otherwise indicated, the views expressed are attributable only to the authors in a personal capacity and not to any institution with which they are associated. Available for free downloading from the CEPS website (http://www.ceps.eu) y © CEPS 2011

Centre for European Policy Studies ▪ Place du Congrès 1 ▪ B-1000 Brussels ▪ Tel: (32.2) 229.39.11 ▪ www.ceps.eu 2 | ABAD, LÖFFLER & ZEMANEK

Sinn (2011a and 2011b) argues that such excess liquidity in Germany (as well as in other imbalances are the reflection of an interim and TARGET2-creditor countries), which – as we will secret bailout by the ECB of the countries see – would pose a threat to the ‘common’ nature grouped under the ‘GIPS’ acronym. By of monetary policy in the euro area. It should be increasing BB’s claims over time, the GIPS’ net noted that, in order to maintain a single interest imports (Greece’s in particular) net imports are rate for the whole union, the ECB needs to being supported and intra-euro current account provide liquidity to banks in the GIPS countries imbalances are being perpetuated (current (TARGET2 debtors) while simultaneously account view). However, as Buiter et al. (2011) and absorbing excess liquidity from the eurozone’s Bindseil & Koenig (2011) note, TARGET2 core countries (TARGET2 creditors). In this imbalances are just the result of capital paper, we look at the different alternatives for movements between each pair of countries liquidity management within the euro area and settled through the Eurosystem’s payment show that policy-making might become quite system (financial account view). The uncomfortable for European central bankers. policy relevance gained by the TARGET2 mechanism stems from the disruption and 1. The ECB as a market-maker of last prolonged malfunctioning of interbank funding resort ... or how target2 is financing markets in Europe. intra-euro area capital flights Since the financial crisis started, a number of In order to draw a stylized picture of how national banking systems (Irish, Greek and TARGET2 is supporting capital flights, we Portuguese banks in particular) have been assume the euro area as a currency union progressively excluded from the interbank consisting of two countries – Germany and lending markets over growing concerns about Ireland. Before the crisis, the German banking their solvency. The Eurosystem had to step in as system massively accumulated foreign claims – a market-maker, providing unlimited lending to in our two country world – against Irish banks, GIPS’ banks. TARGET2 (im-)balances began therefore playing an active role in the build-up of reflecting GIPS’ net capital outflows as the Irish boom. However, the financial crisis refinanced by the Eurosystem. Note that only the brought the boom to a sudden end. German Irish banking system has lost about €140 billion investors’ risk-aversion (against Irish assets) of foreign deposits since 2007, with German increased and German financial institutions banks becoming the main beneficiaries of capital- started to repatriate their investments. Funds repatriating flows currently underway. started to leave Ireland and flow back into Furthermore, TARGET2 balances will keep Germany. Figure 1 shows the balance sheets of diverging for as long as foreign (and even the Irish and the German banking systems. Until domestic) bank deposits in crisis countries are the crisis, the increase of the Irish banking transferred to other banking systems that are system’s balance sheet was mainly driven by perceived as safer by depositors. foreign deposits, which were used to finance In this context, Sinn & Wollmershäuser (2011) investments both inside and outside Ireland. argue that the total stock of central bank money With the outbreak of the 2007-08 financial crisis, poses a hard limit to TARGET2 (im)balances. this funding source started to decline, especially However, we show that – far from being any in the second half of 2010 (see upper panel of hard limit – TARGET2 balances might be Figure 1). In Germany this development was unlimited. That said, further extensions of mirrored (in absolute terms) by a rise in foreign TARGET2 claims (liabilities) in the euro area’s claims before the crisis and its reversal after the core (peripheral) economies might be at odds collapse of Lehman Brothers (see lower panel of with maintaining a common monetary policy Figure 1). within the currency union. Increasing BB’s TARGET2 claims above autonomous liquidity demand2 would lead to

liability side of the central banks balance sheet. This – 2 Autonomous liquidity demand is equivalent to the in case of the BB – is mainly explained by currency in sum of autonomous liquidity absorbing factors on the circulation, see ECB (2011, p. 115). TARGET2 UNLIMITED | 3

Figure 1. Banking system balance sheets Irish banking system

Foreign claims Domestic claims 1,500 Domestic deposits Foreign deposits - 1,500 1,300 Liabilities to BOI Debt securities - 1,300 1,100 Net other liabilities - 1,100 900 - 900 700 - 700 500 - 500 300 - 300 100 - 100 - 100 100

Billion EUR - 300 300 Billion EUR - 500 500 - 700 700 - 900 900 - 1,100 1,100 - 1,300 1,300 - 1,500 1,500 Jan-03 Mar-04 May-05 Jul-06 Sep-07 Nov-08 Jan-10 Mar-11

German banking system

Domestic claims (private sector) Foreign claims (private sector) Domestic deposits Foreign deposits 8000 Liabilities to BB Securities portfolios -8000

6000 -6000

4000 -4000

2000 -2000

0 0

Billion EUR Billion -2000 2000 EUR Billion

-4000 4000

-6000 6000

-8000 8000 Jan-03 Mar-04 May-05 Jul-06 Sep-07 Nov-08 Jan-10 Mar-11

Sources: National central banks, IMF and IFS.

4 | ABAD, LÖFFLER & ZEMANEK

Figure 2. Financing of intra-euro area capital flight via the TARGET2

ECB Eurosystem

Assets Liabilities

Target (CBI) ↑ Target (BB) ↑

(item 6) (item7)

Deutsche Bundesbank (BB) Central Bank of Ireland (CBI) Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities Target2 ↑ Liquidity ↑↓ Claims on Target2 ↑ (item 8) (item 9) Irish BS ↑ (item 5) (item 4) Claims on German BS ↓

(item 12)

German BS Irish BS Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities Claims on Deposits↓ BB ↑↓ (item 2) (item 10)

Claims on Liabilities to BB ↓ Liabilities to CBI ↑ Irish BS ↓ (item 11) (item 3) (item 1)

In a world without a lender of last resort, the solvency. The ECB had to act as a ‘market-maker ‘bank run’ on Irish banks triggered by the flight of last resort’ in order to avoid a potential of foreign (German) deposits would have ended systemic event. The TARGET2 system up with the collapse of the Irish banking system guaranteed Irish banks unlimited4 credit lines while, in Germany, banks would have realised from other Eurosystem central banks at the massive losses as the capital flight would have ECB’s refinancing rate, eliminating the been limited by the sequential-service sequential-service constraint for German banks. constraint.3 Not so within the Eurosystem: since Figure 2 above shows the dynamics of the the start of the financial crisis, Irish banks have TARGET2 mechanism and the flight of German been progressively excluded from interbank capital out of Ireland (flowing back into lending as German banks reduced their exposure Germany).5 Firstly, German banks reduce their to them on the back of concerns over their exposure to Ireland. Foreign claims (item 1) of the German banking sector are declining,

3 Due to term transformation, only the first-movers would have saved their deposits. That was the case of 4 Conditional on Irish banks providing sufficient Iceland, where, as capital left the country, many collateral. ‘slow’ foreign investors based in the UK and the 5 A broadly similar approach is described in Buiter et Netherlands lost theirs. al. (2011) and Bindseil & Koenig (2011). TARGET2 UNLIMITED | 5 mirroring a reduction of foreign liabilities in the In order to minimise low-remunerated ‘excess’ Irish banking sector’s balance sheet (item 2). liquidity (item 10), German banks reduce their While also reducing their domestic and foreign reliance on refinancing operations at the BB (item claims, Irish banks fill the gap left by the 11), which is equivalent to declining claims of BB reduction in (foreign) financing sources by (over- on German banks (item 12) and a reduction of )relying on central bank credit (item 3). As a liquidity (item 9). result, open market operations increase (item 4) The stylized chart of liquidity flows diagrammed in the asset side of the Central Bank of Ireland‘s in Figure 2 shows up in the balance sheets of (CBI) balance sheet, and a similar increase in both the CBI and BB (Figure 3). Since the start of TARGET2 liabilities (item 5) follow. As the ECB the crisis, claims on Irish banks (as well as intermediates the transfer of bank deposits – via TARGET2 liabilities in the CBI balance sheet) TARGET2 – to the BB, the ECB’s TARGET2 have sharply increased. This increase has been liabilities to BB increase (item 7).6 In its turn, BB mirrored by an increase of TARGET2 claims books TARGET2 outflows among its assets (item (substituting previous claims on German banks) 8) and credits the proceeds on the account of the in the BB’s balance sheet. recipient German bank (item 9). The German banking system, whose claims on the central bank have increased (item 10) now holds liquidity in excess of their reserve requirements.

Figure 3. Central bank balance sheets

Central Bank of Ireland (CBI)

250 Other assets -250 200 Claims on Irish banks -200 Liabilities to other euro area residents 150 -150 Other Liabilities (Target) 100 -100 Liquidity 50 -50

0 0

Billion EUR -50 50 Billion EUR

-100 100

-150 150

-200 200

-250 250 Jan-03 Dec-03 Nov-04 Oct-05 Sep-06 Aug-07 Jul-08 Jun-09 May-10 Apr-11

6 There is no ‘world’ liquidity effect as TARGET2 claims and liabilities sum up to zero at the ECB level.

6 | ABAD, LÖFFLER & ZEMANEK

Deutsche Bundesbank

Net foreign assets Claims on German banks -750 700 Other assets (Target) Currency in circulation (corr.) Reserve requirements Deposit facility -550 500 Other liabilities

-350 300

-150 100

50

Billion EUR -100 Billion EUR

250 -300

450 -500

650 -700 Jan-03 Dec-03 Nov-04 Oct-05 Sep-06 Aug-07 Jul-08 Jun-09 May-10 Apr-11

Sources: National central banks, IMF and IFS.

provides liquidity wherever it is scarce at the 2. Unlimited TARGET2 balances – policy rate (creditor central bank). In contrast, due The emergence of creditor and to the accumulation of large stocks of foreign debtor central banks reserves, most emerging market central banks According to Sinn & Wollmershäuser (2011), the are facing surplus liquidity in their domestic resulting increase in TARGET2 liabilities (claims) banking systems (debtor central bank). By at the CBI (BB) would crowd central bank credit expanding longer-term liabilities to the domestic out in Germany (see items 8 and 12 in Figure 2 banking system, debtor central banks and the horizontal dashed area substituting the structurally absorb liquidity (Loeffler et al., black area in the lower panel of Figure 3). While 2010). this situation might be possible, the implications The increase of TARGET2 claims above liquidity that Sinn & Wollmershäuser (2011) derive are demand at the BB would have a similar effect to not straightforward. They argue that the the accumulation of FX reserves in emerging- Eurosystem would need to sell its reserves (gold market central banks. In fact, the BB would and foreign exchange) when the supply of become a debtor central bank towards the liquidity due to the accumulation of TARGET2 German banking system! At the same time, claims exceeding autonomous liquidity national central banks building up TARGET2 demands. While theoretically possible, it is not liabilities – such as the CBI – would remain as very likely. Instead, the BB would (be inclined classical creditor central banks. That is, while the to) absorb liquidity by issuing debt instruments ECB would need to provide liquidity to one that would be recorded on its balance sheet’s region of the euro area, it would also have to liability side. reduce liquidity in countries with TARGET2 However, this – in our view – more realistic claims. As a result, liquidity management in the scenario would lead to a paradoxical situation. In euro area would become asymmetric. general, a textbook central bank holds a To get a sense of how the balance sheets of monopoly over the issuance of base money and creditor (CBI) and debtor central bank (BB) TARGET2 UNLIMITED | 7 would differ, Figure 4 zooms into Figure 2 for (item 13). In contrast, the CBI would have to that purpose. With constant liquidity demand in expand its open market operations on the asset Germany, the continued increase of TARGET2 side of its balance sheet in order to meet the claims would lead to an oversupply of liquidity. increasing liquidity needs of the Irish banking In order to absorb the excess liquidity, BB would system. have to offer debt instruments to German banks Figure 4. The emergence of creditor and debtor central banks

Deutsche Bundesbank (BB) Central Bank of Ireland (CBI) Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities Target2 ↑ Liquidity ↑↓ Claims on Target2 ↑ (item 8) (item 9) (item 5) Irish BS ↑

(item 4) Liabilities to German BS ↑ (item 13)

to the main refinancing rate. If excess liquidity is 3. Liquidity management in an completely absorbed, this option would ensure a asymmetric monetary union common monetary policy within the eurozone as In light of these developments, the ECB will face short-term rates would remain close to one three major alternatives for managing the excess another in all member countries. However, two liquidity we have already analysed in our main unintended consequences are likely to stylized 2-country monetary union. Firstly, the follow. Firstly, capital flight would likely Eurosystem take market-based measures such as accelerate as the TARGET2 mechanism would selling bonds to German banks or using reverse provide an incentive for German banks to repos to drain excess liquidity in the German withdraw their foreign deposits from Irish banking system. Secondly, it could absorb excess financial institutions and invest them into high- liquidity through non-market-based instruments yield central bank debt. The implications would such as an increase in (unremunerated) be that German banks would be encouraged to minimum reserve requirements. Thirdly, the even accelerate their disengagement in Ireland as Eurosystem could (do nothing and) just offer the Eurosystem – due to the TARGET2 German banks access to the ECB’s deposit mechanism – would de facto swap the risky facility, which is remunerated at 0.5%, that is, 75 exposure of German banks toward the Irish BS basis points below the marginal lending rate into riskless high-yielding claims against their (currently at 1.25%).7 central bank. Secondly, issuing debt certificates at the policy rate could complicate liquidity 3.1 Market-based liquidity drain management and discourage interbank lending as banks could overdemand liquidity knowing In order to encourage German banks to invest in that, at the end of the day, they could reinvest it longer-term central bank debt, the Eurosystem in market-based central bank debt at the policy could offer reverse repos at an interest rate close rate.8

Figure 5 describes this mechanism. ‘Private 7 There is a fourth alternative, which is ‘fiscal liquidity’ flows via the TARGET2 system back to coordination’. Fiscal authorities might move bank deposits to the central bank. In this case, government deposits would become quasi-monetary policy 8 Under ‘normal’ conditions, an over-demand for operations for as long as the central bank is able to liquidity is not ‘costless’ as lending the excess keep withdrawals under control. The mixture of fiscal liquidity in the interbank market would lead to a debt management and monetary policy would call downward pressure on interbank rates, while into question the ‘independence’ of the central bank at reinvesting it in central bank debt would be possible stake. only at the deposit interest rate.

8 | ABAD, LÖFFLER & ZEMANEK

Germany leading to an increased demand on are encouraged to remove their deposits as they ‘central bank liquidity’ by Irish banks, which can invest their repatriated deposits with the have to pay the policy rate for their increased Eurosystem yielding at least the policy rate. reliance over Eurosystem lending. German banks

Figure 5. Free lunch for German banks

Flow of ‘private liquidity’ (TARGET2)

capital flight Flow of ‘central bank liquidity’ (TARGET2)

Irish BS Expansionary Restrictive risk monetary policy Eurosystem monetary policy German BS tribution operations against operations against filter risky collateral riskless collateral

While claims against the Eurosystem (reverse to invest on their own initiative, minimum repos) are riskless,9 funds deposited at Irish reserve requirements are imposed by legal force. banks are (perceived as) much riskier.10 The An increase of unremunerated11 required Eurosystem as a whole would be accumulating reserves on German banks would force them to riskier assets as a by-product of its monetary increase their deposits at the Eurosystem.12 BB’s policy operations with the Irish banks (lower longer-term liabilities to the German BS (item 13 part of Figure 5). The default risk of holding such in Figure 4) would increase and – therefore – the riskier assets posted as collateral by Irish banks (over)supply of liquidity would fall. would be borne by the ECB and, ultimately, by The very serious drawbacks of absorbing the individual national central banks in liquidity by legal force are at least two-fold: accordance to their capital key. Overall, this first option would represent a ‘free lunch’ for the 1. Mixing up interest rate policies with German banking sector. quantity restrictions would probably induce higher interest rate volatility as 3.2 Non-market based liquidity drain monetary policy can only choose between two instruments: either targeting prices In order to absorb excess liquidity in the German (interest rates) and leaving quantities to banking system, the Eurosystem could also impose differential unremunerated required reserves (DeGrauwe, 2010). In contrast to 11 market-based measures in which banks are free Currently, minimum reserves in the Eurosystem are remunerated by the average interest rate of the ECB’s main refinancing operations during a month.

Therefore, although banks are not free to invest in 9 In order to ensure the attractiveness of those required reserves, an increase in remunerated reserve investments, the default risk would have to remain at requirements would have a similar impact as that of the ECB. using market-based measures to absorb surplus 10 Note that, while it could be argued that ‘deposit liquidity. insurance’ makes deposits risk-free, this depends – in 12 In practice, minimum reserve requirements would its turn-on the government’s creditworthiness. Once need to be increased in all euro area countries that are this is lost, concerns over the higher risk of funds interconnected with the German banking system deposited at domestic institutions would be justified. through the interbank market. TARGET2 UNLIMITED | 9

react endogenously or targeting quantities Interbank interest rates would fall to the and accepting an endogenous Eurosystem’s overnight deposit rate,14 currently determination of prices. Therefore, 75 basis points below the main financing rate minimum reserve requirements would not (Figure 6). At this rate, banks would be be able to absorb peaks of excess liquidity indifferent between investing their excess of without causing extreme interest rate liquidity with other commercial banks and swings in the interbank market.13 investing it in the Eurosystem’s riskless deposit facility. Thus, building on the deposit facility, the 2. As reserve requirements are not effective money market rate would be higher in mandatory for all financial institutions, but crisis countries – like Ireland – than in the boom just for depository banks, the quasi-tax ones – like Germany. nature would hinder fair competition. In this case, monetary policy would support Apart from not being in line with a common the emergence of unregulated financial monetary policy, the ‘do-nothing’ option would products and institutions. foster overinvestment in Germany. In order to avoid investing the ‘free’ liquidity into the low- 3.3 Deposit facility – No active yielding deposit facility, German banks would liquidity drain have the incentives to search for higher-yielding investment projects. Inflationary pressures, This option – in our view, the most likely one – together with the usual hazards associated with would be equivalent to a decrease of the money excessive and/or riskier lending in Germany, market interest rate in Germany. Since Irish would be two likely outcomes. However, there is banks are virtually excluded from the euro also a point in favour of the deposit facility interbank lending market, excess liquidity in the solution. The lack of investment opportunities German banking system would lead – due to the could also discourage German banks from lack of alternative investment opportunities with removing their foreign deposits.15 That would a better risk-return profile – to additional lower the pressure on the TARGET2 mechanism pressure on short-term interest rates. as well as on monetary policy.

Figure 6. Euro area policy rates

7 Marginal lending 6 Main refinancing operations Overnight deposits 5

4 Percent

3

2

1

0 Jan-99 May-00 Sep-01 Jan-03 May-04 Sep-05 Jan-07 May-08 Sep-09 Jan-11

Source: ECB. 13 Managing liquidity through reserve requirement adjustments has sometimes been compared to cutting a diamond with a sledgehammer. The ECB’s required reserve ratio is 2% of overnight deposits as well as 14 The overnight deposit rate is the relevant policy rate deposits and debt securities with a maturity up to 2 in an environment of excess liquidity. years and has not changed since the beginning of 15 That would also be the case when excess liquidity is EMU. absorbed using the non-market based option.

10 | ABAD, LÖFFLER & ZEMANEK

fully restored so as to improve the liquidity 4. Conclusion allocation process. Since this cannot be safely This paper has looked at the implications of an achieved by the usual stabilisation policies at ongoing divergence of TARGET2 balances for hand, we urge policy-makers to speed up the monetary policy in the euro area in the case of a restructuring process currently underway in prolonged capital flight from the periphery to many European banking sectors and to meet the core countries. We show that the ‘common’ fiscal consolidation targets in place to regain the nature of monetary policy within the eurozone trust of financial markets. could be called into question if TARGET2 claims lead to rising liquidity in the core regions. References Should that be the case, the Eurosystem would Bindseil, Ulrich and Philipp Johann Koenig need to provide liquidity to banks in countries (2011), “The Economics of TARGET2 with TARGET2 liabilities while absorbing excess Balances”, SFB 649 Discussion Paper 35, liquidity in countries with TARGET2 claims to Humbolt Universität, Berlin. maintain a common interest rate for the euro area. Buiter, Willem, Ebrahim Rahbari and Jürgen Michels (2011), “TARGETing the Wrong The strategies available at hand for absorbing Villain: Target2 and Intra-Eurosystem excess liquidity are limited and neither of their Imbalances in Credit Flows”, Citi Global outcomes will be optimal from the Eurosystem’s Economics Views, 9 June. perspective. Using liquidity-absorbing market- based measures might even accelerate the capital De Grauwe, Paul (2010), “What kind of repatriation process and would provide core governance for the eurozone?”, CEPS banks with a ‘free lunch’. Imposing Policy Brief No. 214, Centre for European unremunerated reserve requirements on core Policy Studies, Brussels. banks might hamper (or even break) the interest- ECB (2011), The Monetary Policy of the ECB, rate transmission channel and encourage the Frankfurt/Main. emergence of shadow banking. Finally, even a ‘do-nothing’ scenario would likely cause Loeffler, Axel, Gunther Schnabl and Franziska inflationary pressures, together with the hazards Schobert (2010), “Inflation Targeting by associated with excessive and/or riskier lending Debtor Central Banks in Emerging in core countries. Market Economies”, CESifo Working Paper 3138, CESifo, Munich. Whether a credit-driven boom in core Europe’s domestic economies would provide a way out of Sinn, Hans-Werner (2011a), “The ECB’s Secret the current crisis remains uncertain. By driving Bailout Strategy, Project Syndicate”, 29 an overinvestment cycle in core Europe (in April (http://www.project-syndicate.org particular in Germany), GDP growth and asset /commentary/sinn37/English). prices would pick up. Domestic demand would Sinn, Hans-Werner (2011b), “The ECB’s Stealth start rising possibly with positive spillover Bailout”, VoxEU, 1 June, effects to periphery countries. The boom would (http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=n improve the asset side of German banks’ balance ode/6599). sheets so their restructuring would also be quicker. A likely increase of liquidity demand by Sinn, Hans-Werner and Timo Wollmershäuser German banks could lead to a reduction of (2011), “Target Loans, Current Account excess liquidity, although it could also accelerate Balances and Capital Flows: The ECB’s the deposit drain to fund investments in Rescue”, CESifo Working Paper 3500, Germany. Overall, relying on a bubble for CESifo, Munich. boosting short-term growth would be sowing the seeds of the next crisis. The best scenario we can conceive of is one in which TARGET2 balances do not infinitely diverge. However, to reach that goal, the euro area interbank money market would need to be