Is There a Case for Copyright Levies? an Economic Impact Analysis

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Is There a Case for Copyright Levies? an Economic Impact Analysis Is there a case for copyright levies? An economic impact analysis April 2011 Oxera Consulting Ltd is registered in England No. 2589629 and in Belgium No. 0883.432.547. Registered offices at Park Central, 40/41 Park End Street, Oxford, OX1 1JD, UK, and Stephanie Square Centre, Avenue Louise 65, Box 11, 1050 Brussels, Belgium. Although every effort has been made to ensure the accuracy of the material and the integrity of the analysis presented herein, the Company accepts no liability for any actions taken on the basis of its contents. Oxera Consulting Ltd is not licensed in the conduct of investment business as defined in the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000. Anyone considering a specific investment should consult their own broker or other investment adviser. The Company accepts no liability for any specific investment decision, which must be at the investor’s own risk. © Oxera, 2011. All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purposes of criticism or review, no part may be used or reproduced without permission. Executive summary Summary of main findings The distribution of licensed digital music is evolving rapidly. New business models are emerging for downloading, streaming and other forms of accessing music. People have the ability to listen to and transfer their music collections using a variety of devices, ranging from PCs to portable MP3 players and mobile handsets. This increases flexibility and opens possibilities for new value propositions for music offerings. In this context, the existing system of copyright levies has come under particular scrutiny in recent years—it transfers payments to rights holders (via collecting societies) through levies charged on hardware and devices that can be used for copying. From an economic perspective, the copyright levy system is not well suited to the digital age, as it creates distortions and inefficiencies affecting consumers, device manufacturers and rights holders alike, hindering innovation, investment and the development of a European digital market. To contribute to the policy debate, Nokia commissioned Oxera to provide economic evidence on the impact of copyright levies. Oxera developed a model to assess the welfare effects of these levies on the EU economy as a whole, and on specific groups of market participants—in particular, consumers, device manufacturers, and rights holders. Taking into account current and future dynamics in the market, the main ‘base case’ scenarios modelled by Oxera are shown in the table below. The effect of removing copyright levies is positive in all scenarios. In the bottom row, this is shown as a welfare gain to the EU economy of between €975m and €1,880m per year. Consumers gain in each scenario. Without copyright levies, consumers would buy more devices at lower prices and consume more digital music. Manufacturers gain because they sell more devices and can take part in new business models for distributing music. Effect of removing Scenario 1: Scenario 2: Moderate Scenario 3: copyright levies Limited dynamic dynamic growth and High dynamic growth (€m per year): growth some new business and many new models business models on consumer surplus 601 809 1,088 on manufacturers’ surplus 166 166 166 on song writers’ revenues –16 7 30 on performers’ revenues 1 24 48 on producers’ (record labels’) 223 384 548 revenues Total EU-wide impact (€m) 975 1,389 1,880 Rights holders as a group can also make significant gains from the removal of copyright levies. The two biggest drivers are the growth in digital music sales and the effective compensation that rights holders can extract from selling music through the various new business models. The analysis indicates that, if there is further dynamic growth in the European digital market, song writers, performers, record labels and music publishers will all benefit directly from the removal of copyright levies (scenarios 2 and 3). The market dynamics and empirical evidence discussed in this report suggest that these scenarios are realistic. Removal of copyright levies would enhance the growth in licensed digital music, and enable and incentivise rights holders to engage in alternative business models. Finally, an increased offering of innovative digital services and the resulting boost to the sales of licensed digital content would be expected to contribute to the reduction of piracy. Even if this last effect were modest, it would significantly enhance rights holders’ revenues, and hence make scenarios 2 and 3 more likely. Policy-makers can promote dynamic growth in the European digital market by removing copyright levies and other impediments to innovative business models in the distribution of digital content. Oxera i Is there a case for copyright levies? Objective of the report The way people obtain and consume music has changed rapidly in recent years, and continues to evolve. One important development is that people have the ability to listen to and transfer their music collections onto a variety of devices, ranging from PCs to portable MP3 players and mobile handsets. In economic terms, the possibility of listening to music on various devices increases flexibility and opens new value propositions for music offerings to consumers. There have been long-standing policy and theoretical debates on how rights holders—in this context, song writers, performers, record producers and music publishers—can obtain commercial benefit when their music is acquired or consumed by others. One mechanism for transferring payments to rights holders (via collecting societies) has come under particular scrutiny in recent years: namely, copyright levies. Instead of being charged directly to end- consumers of the music, copyright levies are charged on the hardware that can be used for the private copying of music, including blank CDs, MP3 players, and, in some countries, mobile phones and PCs. The legal basis for copyright levies (as embedded in the EU Copyright Directive 2001/29/EC) is that rights holders may be ‘compensated’, for example, for the ‘harm’ suffered as a result of ‘private copying’—ie, copying unlicensed content, as permitted by national law. From an economic perspective, there is ‘harm’ to rights holders only if copying replaces a music purchase that would otherwise have been made. This may have occurred more frequently in the analogue age when copyright levies were first introduced (when music was copied onto media such as cassettes), but is perhaps less prevalent in this digital age when consumers can be licensed to transfer their collections onto multiple devices. Furthermore, copyright levies are a ‘crude’ way of addressing any ‘harm’ caused by private copying, since they target the devices, not private copying itself. This creates a number of inefficiencies and distortions, as set out in this report. The copyright levy system has a material financial impact. In some countries levies that represent as much as 5–10% of the retail price of an electronic device (or even more for certain products) are not unusual. Collecting societies in Europe collected around €0.5 billion in copyright levies in 2009. However, a much larger amount is claimed every year from device manufacturers (and is the subject of legal dispute). There is currently also pressure to apply copyright levies to newer devices with music-playing facilities, such as tablet computers. To contribute to the policy debate, Nokia commissioned Oxera to provide economic evidence on the impact of copyright levies. Oxera developed a model to assess the welfare effects of copyright levies on the EU economy as a whole, and on specific groups of market participants—in particular, consumers, device manufacturers, and rights holders. The analysis, undertaken in the period from September 2010 to March 2011, covers both static effects, in terms of how money currently flows among market participants, and dynamic effects, in terms of the impact of copyright levies on investment, innovation and creative output. While the analysis focuses on the music market and on hardware with music-playing facilities, the conceptual framework employed could be generalised to any products that are subject to copyright levies, including those used for audiovisual and printed content. The Oxera welfare model Oxera’s model captures the main market mechanisms in the hardware and music distribution markets, and the interactions between the market participants. The focus is on measuring the effects of copyright levies on consumers, hardware manufacturers, and rights holders (in this third group, the emphasis is on song writers—ie, creators). These effects are measured by analysing what would happen in the absence of copyright levies. The model is calibrated Oxera ii Is there a case for copyright levies? using current data on levy rates and sales of hardware and music. Several assumptions had to be made on some key parameters in the model, and the sensitivity of these assumptions has been tested. Three main scenarios are presented as base-case scenarios (see further below). Main market mechanisms captured in the model The following are some of the market mechanisms reflected in the model. – Consumers are affected by copyright levies insofar as hardware vendors pass the levies on in the form of higher retail prices. This in turn reduces the sale of electronic devices, and hence the demand for music downloads and other forms of music files. – Device manufacturers are affected because they absorb the levies as extra costs, or pass them on to retail prices, and hence make fewer sales. Either way, this diminishes their incentives to invest in, and introduce, new device models, and to launch new music distribution platforms. This in turn affects consumers as well. – Rights holders receive a direct financial benefit from copyright levies (to the extent that collecting societies do indeed distribute their revenues to principal rights holders—this varies by country and plays a role in the model, but is not the main focus of this report).
Recommended publications
  • International Survey on Private Copying
    International Survey on Private Copying For more information contact WIPO at www.wipo.int Law & Practice 2 012 World Intellectual Property Organization 34, chemin des Colombettes 2012 International Survey on Private Copying – Law & Practice P.O. Box 18 CH-1211 Geneva 20 Switzerland Telephone: +4122 338 91 11 Fax: +4122 733 54 28 WIPO Publication No. 1037E ISBN 978-92-805-2271-6 International Survey on Private Copying Law & Practice 2012 Acknowledgement and thanks for front cover illustrations (Image of headphones courtesy of: www.publicdomainpictures.net/view-image.php?image=2133&picture=headphones by Anna Langova and all other images courtesy of www.copyright-free-images.com) Table of Contents EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 2 1. REVENUES PER CAPITA 12 2. TARIFFS ON BLANK CARRIERS 13 3. TARIFFS ON DEVICES (ALL THE AMOUNTS IN THIS REPORT ARE IN EUROS [€].) 14 4. AUSTRIA 15 5. BELGIUM 20 6. BULGARIA 25 7. BURKINA FASO 30 8. CANADA 33 9. CROATIA 37 10. CZECH REPUBLIC 41 11. CZECH REPUBLIC 45 12. DENMARK 48 13. FINLAND 51 14. FRANCE 56 15. GERMANY 61 16. GREECE 65 17. HUNGARY 69 18. ITALY 74 19. JAPAN 80 20. LATVIA 86 21. LITHUANIA 90 22. NETHERLANDS 97 23. NORWAY 102 24. PARAGUAY 104 25. POLAND 107 26. PORTUGAL 112 International Survey on Private Copying 27. ROMANIA 114 28. RUSSIA 118 29. SLOVAKIA 121 Law & Practice 2012 30. SLOVENIA 124 31. SPAIN 127 32. SWEDEN 132 33. SWITZERLAND 136 34. TURKEY 141 1 35. UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 144 Executive Summary 1. Introduction The present Survey represents a collection of key data on private copying compensation systems around the world.
    [Show full text]
  • Rethinking Private Copyinc in the Digital Age: an Analysis of the Canadian Approach to Music
    RETHINKING PRIVATE COPYINC IN THE DIGITAL AGE: AN ANALYSIS OF THE CANADIAN APPROACH TO MUSIC BY John Davidson A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Master of Laws Graduate Department of the Faculty of Law University of Toronto O By John Davidson 2001 National Library Bibliothèque nationale du Canada Acquisitions and Acquisitions et Bibliogmphic Services services bibliographiques 395 Wellington Street 395. rue Wellington mwa ON K1A ON4 OtlawaON K1AW canada Canada The author has granted a non- L'auteur a accordé une licence non exclusive licence allouwing the exclusive permettant à la National Library of Cana&. to Biblothèque nationale du Canada de reproduce, loan, distribute 9r seil reproduire, prêter, distribuer ou copies of diis thesis in microform, vendre des copies de cette îhèse sous paper or electronic formats. la forme de microfiche/fïlm, de reproduction sur papier ou sur format électronique. The author retains ownership of the L'auteur conserve la propriété du copyright in this thesis. Neither the droit d'auteur qui protège cette thèse. thesis nor substantial extracts fkom it Ni la thése ni des extraits substantiels may be printed or otherwise de celle-ci ne doivent être imprimés reproduced without the author's ou autrement reproduits sans son permission. autorisation. RETHINKING PRIVATE COPYING IN THE DIGITAL AGE: AN ANALYSIS OF THE CANADIAN APPROACH TO MUSIC John Davidson B.Comm. (U. Syd.), LL.B. (Hons.) (U. Syd.) Admitted to Practice Law in New South Wales, Australia Master of Laws Faculty of Law University of Toronto 200 1 ABSTRACT Digital technotogy and the Internet in particular have fundamentally altered the dynamics of private copying.
    [Show full text]
  • Private Copying and Fair Compensation: an Empirical Study of Copyright Levies in Europe
    Private Copying and Fair Compensation: An empirical study of copyright levies in Europe Martin Kretschmer Centre for Intellectual Property Policy & Management www.cippm.org.uk Bournemouth University [email protected] WIPO, 15 February 2012 EC levy definition (2006) A private copying levy is a form of indirect remuneration for right holders, based on the premise that some acts of private copying cannot be licensed for practical purposes by the relevant right holders. A copyright levy is typically attached to certain products (equipment or blank media) that can serve to reproduce audio, audio-visual and textual material such as music, films or books. Policy context ESRC Fellowship at UK IPO (2010/11) – UK: What position on EU wide regulation? – UK: Can a private copying exception be introduced without providing compensation? Limitations and exceptions – Are exceptions just a response to market failure? – What activities should be possible without permission? – If without permission, requirement to pay? Empirical approach: If we don’t know how a “regulated” market works, we can’t intervene. Levy history in the EU – 1965: Germany UrhG §53 – 2001: Info Soc Directive (“fair compensation”) – 2006: EC recommendation (almost) – October 2010: ECJ Padawan (“uniform interpretation”, “calculation based on harm”) – May 2011: EC announces “comprehensive legislative action” regarding private copying levies (+ “mediator”) – August 2011: UK commitment to introduce private copying exception without compensation (“Hargreaves”) – [Norway], Finland,
    [Show full text]
  • The Future of Licensing Music Online: the Role of Collective Rights Organizations and the Effect of Territoriality, 25 J
    The John Marshall Journal of Information Technology & Privacy Law Volume 25 Issue 3 Journal of Computer & Information Law Article 1 - Summer 2008 Summer 2008 The Future of Licensing Music Online: The Role of Collective Rights Organizations and the Effect of Territoriality, 25 J. Marshall J. Computer & Info. L. 409 (2008) Neil Conley Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.uic.edu/jitpl Part of the Computer Law Commons, Entertainment, Arts, and Sports Law Commons, Internet Law Commons, and the Science and Technology Law Commons Recommended Citation Neil Conley, The Future of Licensing Music Online: The Role of Collective Rights Organizations and the Effect of Territoriality, 25 J. Marshall J. Computer & Info. L. 409 (2008) https://repository.law.uic.edu/jitpl/vol25/iss3/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by UIC Law Open Access Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in The John Marshall Journal of Information Technology & Privacy Law by an authorized administrator of UIC Law Open Access Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ARTICLES THE FUTURE OF LICENSING MUSIC ONLINE: THE ROLE OF COLLECTIVE RIGHTS ORGANIZATIONS AND THE EFFECT OF TERRITORIALITY NEIL CONLEYt I. INTRODUCTION The right to control the performance of a creative work' represents for most songwriters and music publishers ("rights holders")2 their great- est source of income.3 However, the current licensing regime practiced t The author will receive his LL.M. in intellectual property law at the George Wash- ington University Law School in August of 2008. I would like to thank Ralph Oman, my professor, for his guidance, suggestions, and edits.
    [Show full text]
  • FEP Report of Activities 2011 - 2012 3 4 FEP Report of Activities 2011 - 2012 Foreword by Fergal Tobin, FEP President
    Report of Activities May 2011 – May 2012 Table of Content Table of Content Foreword by Fergal Tobin, FEP President . 5 DG Internal Market & Services . 25 25. Review of the Enforcement Directive27 FEP . 7 26. Effective Enforcement of copyright 28 28. Directive on orphan Works 30 FEP Meets 29. out-of-commerce Dialogue 31 FEP in Brussels and in Europe 30. viP stakeholders Dialogue 32 FEP Networks 31. collective Management 33 FEP statistics 32. Levies 34 DG Culture & Education . 9 DG Justice . 33 9. Multilingualism 33. Data protection 35 10. European cultural platforms Green Paper on 35. Brussels i Regulation cultural industries 11. European Union Prize for Literature 12. High level expert group on literacy DG Home Affairs . 36 36. Data retention DG Entreprise . 13 13. Toy Safety DG Research & Innovation . 38 DG Environment . 15 DG Taxation . 39 15. Eco-label 16. Obligations of operators who place timber and 39. Reduced rates of vAt timber products on the market 41. vAt on books in the member countries DG Health & Consumers . 17 DG Trade . 42 17. Review of the consumer Acquis 42. Anti-counterfeiting trade Agreement (ACTA) 43. External EU actions against piracy and counterfeiting DG Information Society & Media. 19 19. task force for the coordination of the Media The Publications Office of the European Union 20. European Digital Library - Europeana (publications office) . 45 21. ARROW – ARROW + 22. Revision of the directive 2003/98/Ec on the re- use of public sector information 24 23. Net Neutrality 25 FEP REPoRt oF ActivitiEs 2011 - 2012 3 4 FEP REPoRt oF ActivitiEs 2011 - 2012 Foreword by Fergal Tobin, FEP President Ebook, epublishing, elibraries, ebookshops… if the word of them are developing digital works, innovative tools to that defines you does not start with an e, you are pretty access them, tailor-made licences for all types of users.
    [Show full text]
  • OPPORTUNITIES of EU-LEVEL ADMINISTRATION of PRIVATE COPYING LEVIES Natasha Mangal*
    Conference Draft – Do Not Distribute OPPORTUNITIES OF EU-LEVEL ADMINISTRATION OF PRIVATE COPYING LEVIES Natasha Mangal* ABSTRACT The foundation of the private copying levy is eroding. What was once a remuneration-based “reward” has transitioned into a compensation-based payment linked to the notion of rightholder “harm,” resulting in a wide range of levy applications, calculations and distribution schemes among EU Member States. This administrative fragmentation is further compounded by new online business models, as streaming and cloud storage services forego the need to create private copies altogether. Yet in spite of this, the levy remains as relevant as ever: as an unwaivable contractual mechanism, it serves as a stable source of income for EU rightholders with limited bargaining power, and accounts for millions of Euros reinvested back into the creative economy. In the continued absence of an adequate technological means to track the private copying practices of users, it seems that the levy may provide an even longer-term solution than anticipated – what is still needed, then, is a means by which levy administration can be optimized for the digital era. This paper will examine and critique one approach to improving the function of the private copying levy in EU Member States: administrative intervention at the EU- level. Part I will first identify theoretical and technological shifts that challenge the current existence of the levy. After these issues are addressed, Part II will assess the feasibility of an EU-level institutional approach by addressing regulatory gaps in three distinct areas: tariff setting, collection and distribution and technological monitoring. This paper will ultimately propose recommendations for improving the administration of the levy among EU Member States.
    [Show full text]
  • English and Collections Stream
    ANNUAL REPORT 2018 Content President’s foreword by Jean-Michel Jarre CISAC is a unique “united nations” of creators 02 Foreword by Eric Baptiste Pushing for a creators-centric agenda 03 Introduction by Gadi Oron Building a better future for creators of all repertoires 04 CISAC Vice Presidents Champions for creators’ rights internationally 06 Key data The world of CISAC in numbers 08 Key figures 09 CISAC work programme in review 10 Special features Pingyao International Film Festival 29 UNESCO & CISAC team up on transfer of value 30 Algiers Creators Conference 31 CISAC structure and committees CISAC key services CISAC’s structure and committees Transfer of value campaign 32 at a glance 46 Bringing fairness to authors Education in the digital world Public education and raising awareness 48 Audiovisual campaign 34 Creators Councils Fair remuneration for film directors and screenwriter CIAM: Extending international influence 49 Resale right campaign 36 W&DW: New leadership, new frontiers 50 Fair royalties for visual artists CIAGP: Action and transition at the top 51 Private copying campaign 38 Regional Reports A key collections source for creators Asia Pacific 52 Technology and innovation 40 Africa 54 Developing effective data Latin America & the Caribbean 56 management tools Canada/USA 58 Governance 42 Europe 60 Strengthening collective management worldwide CISAC Members 62 Management team and Board 64 Publications 44 Authority, information, awareness Credits 65 CISAC ANNUAL REPORT # 2018 / 1 President’s foreword by Jean-Michel Jarre CISAC is a unique “united nations” of creators As the “United Nations” of creators, CISAC has a unique voice – one which speaks for the whole world, for five repertoires and for four million creators.
    [Show full text]
  • Executive Summary Italy's Economy, the Ninth-Largest in the World, Is Fully
    Executive Summary Italy’s economy, the ninth-largest in the world, is fully diversified, but dominated by small and medium-sized firms (SMEs), which comprise 99.9 percent of Italian businesses. Italy is an original member of the 18-nation Eurozone. Germany, France, the United States, Spain, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom are Italy's most important trading partners, with China continuing to gain ground. Tourism is an important source of external revenue, as are exports of engineering products, mechanical machinery, and textiles/fashion. Italy continues to lag behind many industrialized nations as a recipient of direct foreign investment, and Italy does not have a bilateral investment treaty with the United States (see section on Bilateral Investment Agreements for the full list of countries that have such treaties with Italy). Italy’s relatively affluent domestic market, proximity to emerging economies in North Africa and the Middle East, and assorted centers of excellence in scientific and information technology research remain attractive to many investors. The government in 2013 remained open to specific foreign sovereign wealth funds to invest in shares of Italian companies and banks and continued to make information available online to prospective investors. The Italian government’s efforts to implement new investment promotion policy that would paint Italy as a desirable direct investment destination were overshadowed in large part by Italy’s ongoing economic weakness, setbacks to reform initiatives, and lack of concrete action on structural reforms that could repair the lengthy and often inconsistent legal and regulatory systems, unpredictable tax structure and layered bureaucracy. However, Italy’s economy is moving into fragile recovery after its longest recession in recent memory and this could provide political momentum for improvements to Italy’s investment climate.
    [Show full text]
  • FAQ – Extending the Private Copying Levy to MP3 Players
    FAQ – Extending the Private Copying Levy to MP3 Players Why should the private copying levy be extended to MP3 players like the iPod? The private copying levy exists to provide fair compensation to songwriters, composers, music publishers, recording artists, musicians and recording companies for private copies made of their music. Currently, the levy only applies to CD-Rs. The time has come to extend the levy to reflect how private copies of music are actually made today – not how they were made a decade ago. Of the 1.9 billion songs copied annually in Canada, 62% are copied onto MP3 players like the iPod. Modernizing the levy by extending it to MP3 players will bring the current copyright legislation in line with the way people use and copy music today. Why is this so “urgent”? MP3 players have become the method of choice for copying music. The percentage of private copies being made on to CD-Rs is decreasing significantly. Revenue from the current levy has dropped 68% since 2008 and is drying up quickly. Rights holders are no longer being compensated for the majority of private copies being made of their music. Canadians have changed the technology used to copy music – our copyright law needs to change also, so that artists, songwriters and other rights holders can continue to receive the compensation to which they are entitled. Isn’t this just another tax? No. The private copying levy is not a tax. It is a royalty paid to music rights holders. Unlike a tax, which is collected by the government, the private copying levy is collected by the Canadian Private Copying Collective (CPCC) to provide remuneration to rights holders for private copying.
    [Show full text]
  • I Diritti SIAE I Diritti SCF La Licenza Ombrello Il Canone RAI Speciale
    I diritti SIAE i diritti SCF la licenza ombrello il canone RAI speciale a cura di Patrizia Clementi n. 68 I diritti SIAE i diritti SCF la licenza ombrello il canone RAI speciale a cura di Patrizia Clementi SUPPLEMENTO AL N° 68 DI EX LEGE - POSTE ITALIANE SPA SPED. IN ABB.TO PO- STALE DL 353/2003 (conv. in legge 27/02/2004 n. 46) art. 1 comma 1 LO/MI Fonti normative – D.P.R. 633/1941 – R.D.L. 21/02/1938, n. 246 – D.L.Lt. 21/12/1944, n. 458 – Accordo CEI-SIAE – Convenzione CEI-SCF – Licenza Ombrello Di seguito si riassumono gli adempimenti cui la par- rocchia è tenuta relativamente al possesso di appa- recchi radiotelevisivi (esclusi quelli presenti nelle a- bitazioni dei sacerdoti), alla diffusione di musica “dal vivo” o registrata e all'utilizzo di opere cinema- tografiche. Questa Guida non è esaustiva; intende offrire solo un primo quadro di riferimento per comprendere come operare correttamente in riferimento alle si- tuazioni più diffuse nelle parrocchie ambrosiane. Diritto d’autore Per poter eseguire dal vivo o mediante strumenti le per le opere opere musicali tutelate dal diritto d’autore, ai sensi della legge n. 633 del 1941 occorre essere autoriz- musicali, zati (acquisire la “licenza”) e pagare i relativi diritti la cui tutela d’autore: «Sono protette ai sensi di questa legge le opere dell’ingegno di carattere creativo che appar- compete alla SIAE tengono alla letteratura, alla musica, alle arti figura- tive, all’architettura, al teatro ed alla cinematografia, qualunque ne sia il modo o la forma di espressione» (art.
    [Show full text]
  • International Survey on Private Copying
    International Survey on Private Copying For more information contact WIPO at www.wipo.int World Intellectual Property Organization Law & Practice 2015 34, chemin des Colombettes P.O. Box 18 CH-1211 Geneva 20 Switzerland Telephone: +4122 338 91 11 Fax: +4122 733 54 28 WIPO Publication No. 1037E/16 ISBN 978-92-805-2707-0 Acknowledgement and thanks for front cover illustrations Acknowledgement and thanks for front right image courtesy of Carlos Porto at FreeDigitalPhotos.net Top image courtesy of Stuart Miles at FreeDigitalPhotos.net centre Top right image courtesy of tungphoto at FreeDigitalPhotos.net Top Lower left Image courtesy of stockimages at FreeDigitalPhotos.net image courtesy of xedos4 at FreeDigitalPhotos.net Lowewr centre Lower right image courtesy of watcharakun at FreeDigitalPhotos.net International Survey on Private Copying Law & Practice 2015 International Survey on Private Copying Law & Practice 2015 International Survey on Private Copying Law & Practice 2015 Table of Contents PREFACE 2 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 3 1. Introduction 3 2. Methodology and Scope 3 3. Legal background for private copying remuneration 4 4. Practical implementation of compensation systems 7 5. Liability 10 6. Collection and distribution 11 7. Revenue trends 13 8. Conclusion 22 9. Annex 24 1. AUSTRIA 30 2. BELGIUM 37 3. BURKINA FASO 44 4. CANADA 46 5. CROATIA 51 6. CZECH REPUBLIC 56 7. DENMARK 60 8. ESTONIA 64 9. FINLAND 68 10. FRANCE 74 11. GERMANY 81 12. GREECE 85 13. HUNGARY 90 14. ITALY 97 15. JAPAN 103 International Survey on Private Copying 16. LATVIA 109 17. LITHUANIA 112 18. NETHERLANDS 118 19. NORWAY 123 Law & Practice 2015 20.
    [Show full text]
  • P2P and the Future of Private Copying Peter K
    Texas A&M University School of Law Texas A&M Law Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 2005 P2P and the Future of Private Copying Peter K. Yu [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar Part of the Intellectual Property Law Commons, and the Internet Law Commons Recommended Citation Peter K. Yu, P2P and the Future of Private Copying, 76 U. Colo. L. Rev. 653 (2005). Available at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar/383 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Texas A&M Law Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Texas A&M Law Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. P2P AND THE FUTURE OF PRIVATE COPYING PETER K. Yu* TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ..................................................................................... 654 I. THE 2003 COPYRIGHT WARS ......................................................... 658 I. THE FUTURE P2P FILE-SHARING WARS ......................................... 676 A . Dom estic Challenges ............................................................... 676 1. Proliferation of New P2P Technologies ............................ 676 2. Transnational Nature of the Future Copyright Wars ......... 677 3. Increased Political Alienation of the Recording Industry. 679 4. Counterattacks and Setbacks ............................................. 685 B. InternationalChallenges ......................................................... 686 1. Heightened
    [Show full text]