Peter Rutland on Nationalism and the Economy: Explorations Into A

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Load more

Stefan Berger, Thomas Fetzer, ed.. Nationalism and the Economy: Explorations into a Neglected Relationship. Budapest: Central European University Press, 2019. 330 pp. $65.00, cloth, ISBN 978-963-386-198-1. Reviewed by Peter Rutland Published on H-Diplo (August, 2019) Commissioned by Seth Offenbach (Bronx Community College, The City University of New York) There is a dearth of literature on the intersec‐ an economic unit” (p. 90). Etges notes that one tion of economics and nationalism, a subject that reason people associate nationalism with protec‐ was frst broached in a pivotal 2005 collection tionism is that sectoral groups lobbying for tariff edited by Eric Helleiner and Andreas Pickel, Eco‐ protection have often succeeded in framing their nomic Nationalism in a Globalizing World. A own narrow interests as the national interest. Google ngram search records the frst use of the In his review of the political economy litera‐ term “economic nationalism” in 1898, with a ture, Fetzer notes that economic nationalism is sharp peak in usage in 1938, after which it fell off typically tied to questions of protecting national by two-thirds by the mid-1950s. Stefan Berger and security or the welfare state, seen as threatened Thomas Fetzer have assembled a team of a dozen by expanded foreign trade. In contrast, liberal na‐ authors to tackle the question, through a mixture tionalists (a term not used in the book) have long of literature reviews and case studies. They right‐ argued that participation in the liberal interna‐ ly argue that nationalism scholars tend to focus tional order can be key to a nation’s long-run eco‐ on state power and cultural representation at the nomic prosperity and hence power and prestige. expense of economics, while economists in turn This worked for Britain in the nineteenth century largely overlook the question of nationalism. One and the United States in the post-1945 world, and strength of the collection is its interdisciplinary since 1991 it has become integral to the neoliberal nature; one drawback is that most of the fourteen thinking that dominates policymaking in most chapters focus on Europe (there is one chapter on countries of the world. land policy in Israel and one on the Chinese dias‐ Oliver Kuhschelm provides a handy review of pora). the literature on consumption and national identi‐ One of the central arguments in the book is ty. Consumerism was traditionally treated as or‐ that economic nationalism should be understood thogonal to nationalism. The 1920s saw the rise of as a broader phenomenon than mere protection‐ “buy national campaigns,” but it is unclear how ism—the creation of tariff and other barriers to effective they were in actually shaping consumer deter foreign trade and investment. Berger and behavior or beliefs. Kuhschelm notes there is a Fetzer instead prefer Andreas Etges’s definition of tension between promoting “buy national” at “thinking and acting with regard to the nation as home and promoting national goods in export H-Net Reviews markets. He includes some references to Mexico Fund owned about half the Jewish land (about 10 and Japan but his main examples are Austria and percent of the total) and would not allow it to be Switzerland. Kuhschelm’s chapter includes the sold to Arabs (p. 105). Metzger briefly surveys the only image in the whole book: an ad for Austrian land ownership regime in other nation-building wafers. This reflects a broader deficiency in na‐ projects, such as the Baltic states in the 1990s. tionalism studies: a preference for text over im‐ Zarko Lazarevic notes that economic dispari‐ age, even though images have always been cen‐ ties between Yugoslavia’s regions marred the tral to nationalist narratives. country since its inception in 1918. Decentraliza‐ Similarly, Mads Mordhorst provides a useful tion to allow the diverse regions to pursue inde‐ review of the rise of nation branding, a concept pendent economic policies (as in the 1974 consti‐ launched by Simon Anholt in 1998. Globalization tutional reform, which included the creation of has not made nations irrelevant; rather, it has six republican central banks) paved the way for shifted their narrative focus from internal com‐ the “nationalization” of the regional Communist munity construction to external branding in the parties (p. 128). The poorer regions were hit by global marketplace. Originally, nation branding the economic stagnation of the socialist bloc in the referred to the value added when marketing a 1970s, and the author argues that the end of so‐ product as from country X, but later it came to cialism elsewhere in Europe meant that the col‐ mean trying to promote an image of the nation it‐ lapse of Yugoslavia was inevitable. The chapter self. Mordhorst sees nation branding as a grab would have benefited from the inclusion of some bag of marketing tools (also used to brand places basic data on the economic disparities between and corporations), with scant regard for the his‐ the north and the south of the country. The author torical context. There is little evidence that na‐ completely sidesteps the question of politics: there tion-branding campaigns have had any actual im‐ is no discussion about what happened in World pact on perceptions of the country in question War II, and Josip Tito’s name is never mentioned. among target audiences (tourists, investors, etc.). Sergiu Delcea examines welfare policy as a Harold James’s chapter, “Visions of Europe,” tool of nation-building, using the case of 1930s Ro‐ revisits the shift from culture to realpolitik in Ger‐ mania, where the state sought to promote the many after 1848 and the fusion of business and growth of an ethnically Romanian urban middle war in Krupp’s Age of Steel. Economic determin‐ class. The 1921 land reform especially targeted es‐ ism lived on in post-1945 Germany, now severed tates owned by the German and Hungarian mi‐ from its military role. The D-mark became central norities), and the new higher education system to German identity: as of 1988 only 20 percent mass-produced ethnic Romanian bureaucrats. wanted to give it up to join the euro (p. 74). James However, Delcea does not explain exactly how the does not mention the argument—supported by ethnic targeting of the insurance system worked subsequently released documents—that President in practice. François Mitterand forced Helmut Kohl to accept Vera Scepanovic argues that after 1989 in East the euro as the price for German unification Central Europe there was a convergence on ac‐ (which France had to approve as one of the four ceptance of free trade and foreign investment, Allied occupying powers).[1] though there was a broad variety in the specific Jacob Metzer’s study of land ownership in Is‐ policies adopted in each country. Hungary and Es‐ rael argues that the Zionist strategy was borrowed tonia sold most of their industry to foreign buy‐ from Prussian colonization of the Poznan region ers, while the Czechs, Poles, and Slovenes pre‐ in the 1890s. Prior to 1948, the Jewish National ferred vouchers and insider privatization. The 2 H-Net Reviews chapter focuses on the 1990s transition and only trajectory of the various nationalisms.[2] The ac‐ briefly touches on the 2008 crisis, which produced quisition of empire was of course key to the eco‐ a nationalist backlash in Hungary. nomics and ideology of nationalism in the nine‐ Pal Nyiri’s short but insightful chapter shows teenth century; and the loss of empire was central how Beijing has incorporated the Chinese diaspo‐ to nationalist agendas of the late twentieth centu‐ ra into its modernization strategy, fusing appeals ry, and remains so to this day. This myopia refects to patriotism with economic self-interest. Other the tendency of much of the classic nationalism nations, from Korea to India, have also “turned di‐ literature to focus on the building of the national asporas and migrants from suspect outsiders to community within the territory of a given (Euro‐ vital elements of nation-building” (p. 243). This il‐ pean) state.[3] lustrates how nationalism and transnationalism Another important phenomenon outside Eu‐ are intimately connected. rope is the rise of “resource nationalism” in oil Hagen Schulz-Forberg’s contribution discuss‐ and mineral producers from Indonesia to es efforts in the 1930s to develop a transnational Venezuela. A Google ngram search reveals the network around liberal thinkers, such as Walter first use of the term “resource nationalism” in Lippman and Friedrich Hayek. This essay does 1955, peaking in 1978-82 during the second oil cri‐ not address economic nationalism per se but a sis, and then falling by two-thirds since then. failed liberal cosmopolitanism, so it sits rather un‐ There is a body of scholarly research on the topic easily alongside the other contributions. of resource nationalism, none of it cited in the volume reviewed here.[4] In the concluding chapter, “Economic Euro‐ peanness,” Fetzer notes that earlier conceptions of There is a lively new political economy litera‐ a European social market model have receded as ture, mainly coming out of the US, in which au‐ countries moved in a more American neoliberal thors engage with important questions of the evo‐ direction since the creation of a single market in lution of the nation-state system in the context of 1993. Differences persist across the countries of globalization. It would have been interesting to Europe, both in institutional practices and elite see this work brought into the debate over nation‐ perceptions. As a result, the promise of a Euro‐ alism. In The Globalization Paradox (2012), Dani pean post-national model remains unfulfilled. Rodrik in particular has some important insights into the dilemmas facing democratic governments There is a reason for the paucity of works on trying to pursue national policies in an era of economic nationalism: it requires mastering very global flows of capital (and labor).[5] different disciplines and promoting dialogue be‐ tween them.
Recommended publications
  • The Grip of Nationalism on Corporate Law

    The Grip of Nationalism on Corporate Law

    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Indiana University Bloomington Maurer School of Law Indiana Law Journal Volume 95 Issue 2 Article 5 4-15-2020 The Grip of Nationalism on Corporate Law Mariana Pargendler [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/ilj Part of the Agency Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Law and Politics Commons, and the Law and Society Commons Recommended Citation Pargendler, Mariana (2020) "The Grip of Nationalism on Corporate Law," Indiana Law Journal: Vol. 95 : Iss. 2 , Article 5. Available at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/ilj/vol95/iss2/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School Journals at Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Indiana Law Journal by an authorized editor of Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Grip of Nationalism on Corporate Law MARIANA PARGENDLER* INTRODUCTION After decades of increased economic integration, nationalistic sentiment and protectionist policies are back in vogue, raising questions about the future of globalization. This tension is not new, but it matters. Countries have long adopted different and changing attitudes towards free trade or the protection of local industries, with significant economic and social repercussions. The current resurgence of nationalist impulses in the face of globalization may well be “the struggle of our time.”1
  • India's 2019 National Election and Implications for U.S. Interests

    India's 2019 National Election and Implications for U.S. Interests

    India’s 2019 National Election and Implications for U.S. Interests June 28, 2019 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R45807 SUMMARY R45807 India’s 2019 National Election and Implications June 28, 2019 for U.S. Interests K. Alan Kronstadt India, a federal republic and the world’s most populous democracy, held elections to seat a new Specialist in South Asian lower house of parliament in April and May of 2019. Estimates suggest that more than two-thirds Affairs of the country’s nearly 900 million eligible voters participated. The 545-seat Lok Sabha (People’s House) is seated every five years, and the results saw a return to power of the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) led by Prime Minister Narendra Modi, who was chief minister of the west Indian state of Gujarat from 2001 to 2014. Modi’s party won decisively—it now holds 56% of Lok Sabha seats and Modi became the first Indian leader to win consecutive majorities since Indira Gandhi in 1971. The United States and India have been pursuing an expansive strategic partnership since 2005. The Trump Administration and many in the U.S. Congress welcomed Modi’s return to power for another five-year term. Successive U.S. Presidents have deemed India’s growing power and influence a boon to U.S. interests in Asia and globally, not least in the context of balancing against China’s increasing assertiveness. India is often called a preeminent actor in the Trump Administration’s strategy for a “free and open Indo-Pacific.” Yet there are potential stumbling blocks to continued development of the partnership.
  • Economic Nationalism As a Driving Force of Populism in the US

    Economic Nationalism As a Driving Force of Populism in the US

    Economic Nationalism as a Driving Force of Populism in the U.S. Pia Malaney Prepared for “Global Populisms: A Threat to Democracy?” 3-4 November, Stanford University The global surge towards populism presents us with something of a paradox. There seems little question that nothing of an obviously catastrophic nature has happened in the industrialized world, yet seemingly spontaneous outbreaks of populist resentment across Europe and the Americas are occurring at a level that suggests some kind of invisible cataclysm must be taking place. The symptoms of racism and xenophobia appear to be shared; the underlying etiology however is perhaps more complex. We focus here mainly on the US example, but touch on the waves of populism propagating throughout the world as links between it is hard to avoid parallels between some of the economic discontents believed to have been driving recent political shifts in Europe and the US. Populism and the Polarization of the US Electorate While the role of populism in the US 2016 election took many political observers by surprise political scientists in the US have, for a while, been pointing towards increasing polarization, often the precursor to and co-traveler with, political populism. The divide in the voting gap between congressional Republicans and Democrats, measured by NOMINATE scores, has been increasing since 1975 and is now at its widest ever.i The shape of this polarization has not been symmetric but rather right skewed. The shift left amongst congressional Democrats has been moderate, whilst the shift to the right amongst Republicans has been far more significant.
  • Economic Nationalism: Constrained and Fragmented, If Any? Yorgos Rizopoulos

    Economic Nationalism: Constrained and Fragmented, If Any? Yorgos Rizopoulos

    Economic nationalism: Constrained and fragmented, if any? Yorgos Rizopoulos To cite this version: Yorgos Rizopoulos. Economic nationalism: Constrained and fragmented, if any?. Ch. Nikas (ed), Economic Growth in the European Union, Springer, 2020. hal-03005871 HAL Id: hal-03005871 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-03005871 Submitted on 14 Nov 2020 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Economic nationalism: Constrained and fragmented, if any? Yorgos Rizopoulos Université Paris Diderot, Ladyss CNRS [email protected] (published, in Ch. Nikas (ed), Economic Growth in the European Union, Springer, 2020, pp. 9- 20). Abstract: In this contribution, the meaning of economic nationalism and the possibilities of pursuing nationalist policies in the context of increasingly interdependent economic processes are discussed. Economic nationalism need not solely be affiliated with statist protectionism, while very few states dispose the necessary economic, social, political and institutional conditions to influence economic policy given the long-term tendencies that undermine nationalist wills (empowerment of supranational bodies, internationalization of production, deindustrialization). Even these states are not monolithic and the pattern of business/government relations in different fields would have a critical influence.
  • The Economics of Nationalism∗

    The Economics of Nationalism∗

    The Economics of Nationalism∗ Xiaohuan Lan Ben Li Cheung Kong GSB Boston College May 4, 2014 Abstract This paper provides an economic framework for examining how economic openness affects nationalism. Within a country, a region’s level of nationalism varies according to its economic interests in its domestic market relative to its foreign market. A region’s nationalism is strongest if the optimal size of its domestic market equals the size of its country. All else being equal, increasing a region’s foreign trade reduces its economic interests in its domestic market and thus weakens its nationalism. This prediction holds both cross-sectionally and over time, as evidenced by our empirical study using the Chinese Political Compass data and the World Value Surveys. Our framework also applies to analysis of nationalism across countries and receives support from cross-country data. Keywords: Nationalism, Economic Openness, Country Size, Gains from Trade, China. JEL Codes: F52, P16. ∗Contact author: Ben Li, [email protected], 001-617-552-4517, Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467. We thank the editor, two anonymous referees, as well as James Anderson, Roger Gordon, Harry Harding, Ann Harrison, Ruixue Jia, Wolfgang Keller, Wei Li, Liugang Sheng, Kevin O’Rourke, Torsten Persson, and David Strömberg for their insightful suggestions. We thank Sandra Poncet for sharing the data on distances between Chinese provinces and foreign countries. We also thank seminar participants at Boston College, Cheung Kong GSB, and various other places for helpful comments, David Mao for access to the CPoC data, and Xiaofeng Wang for technical supports.
  • Working Paper 19-15 Measuring the Rise of Economic Nationalism

    Working Paper 19-15 Measuring the Rise of Economic Nationalism

    WORKING PAPER 19-15 Measuring the Rise of Economic Nationalism Monica de Bolle and Jeromin Zettelmeyer August 2019 Abstract Since the mid-2000s, the platforms of major political parties in both advanced and emerging-market economies have increasingly emphasized policies that stress national sovereignty, reject multilateralism, and seek to advance national interests through measures that come at the expense of foreign interests. This paper documents this shift by evalu- ating the policy platforms of the largest political parties (about 55 in total) in the Group of Twenty (G-20) countries with regard to trade policy, foreign direct investment (FDI), immigration, and multilateral organizations. Preference shifts with respect to industrial policy, competition policy, and macroeconomic populism are also examined. In advanced economies, the biggest shifts were toward restrictions on immigration and trade and toward macroeco- nomic populism. In emerging-market economies, the largest preference shifts were toward industrial policies favoring specific sectors, macroeconomic populism, and industrial concentration. Trade protectionism and skepticism toward multilateral organizations and agreements have increased in both advanced and emerging-market economies. As of 2018, economic policy preferences in emerging-market economies were more nationalist and less liberal than in advanced countries, but the gap has narrowed. Right-wing parties tend to be more nationalist than left-wing parties in the areas of immigration restrictions, FDI restrictions, and antimultilateralism, but there is no significant differ- ence with respect to trade protectionism. JEL Codes: F5, F1, F2 Keywords: nationalism, populism, capitalism, trade policy, industrial policy, protectionism Monica de Bolle is a senior fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics and the Riordan Roett Chair in Latin American Studies at the Johns Hopkins School for Advanced International Studies.
  • A Critical Analysis of Economic Nationalism Written by Frederico Rafael Silva

    A Critical Analysis of Economic Nationalism Written by Frederico Rafael Silva

    Are You a Realist in Disguise? A Critical Analysis of Economic Nationalism Written by Frederico Rafael Silva This PDF is auto-generated for reference only. As such, it may contain some conversion errors and/or missing information. For all formal use please refer to the official version on the website, as linked below. Are You a Realist in Disguise? A Critical Analysis of Economic Nationalism https://www.e-ir.info/2018/09/21/are-you-a-realist-in-disguise-a-critical-analysis-of-economic-nationalism/ FREDERICO RAFAEL SILVA, SEP 21 2018 The concept of nationalism was deeply defamed and vilified during the previous century, mostly on the count of fascist movements prior to Second World War. While during the interwar period, Economic Nationalism’s (EN) literature received fair attention, after the war the scholarly debate was confined between Liberalism and Marxism (Helleiner, 2002; Levi-Faur, 1997). This led to poor theoretical and analytical sophistication of this perspective when compared to the developments in the liberal and Marxist literature (Levi-Faur, 1997) and the use by the former as to describe policies that don’t conform to liberal prescriptions (Helleiner, 2002). With time, EN became attached to the realist tradition characterized by a state-centred approach, where the state is charged with manipulating the economy in order to pursue national interests (Crane, 1998). Scholars from all fields came to associate Friedrich List, one of EN’s predominant and pioneer scholars (Levi-Faur, 1997), and his work, with protectionism and in particular infant-industry protection (Helleiner, 2002). However, an analysis of List’s The National System of Political Economy and a proper understanding of the concept of nationalism, reveals a side of EN less entangled with the material persecution of state interests and more concerned about the national dimension that stands between “each individual and entire humanity” (List, 2000, p.
  • Liberalism As a Form of Economic Nationalism Introduction Whereas

    Liberalism As a Form of Economic Nationalism Introduction Whereas

    Liberalism as a Form of Economic Nationalism Introduction Whereas the literature on political nationalism is vast, relatively little has been written on economic nationalism. Much of the literature that does exist, views economic nationalism as an “outdated phenomenon in this age of globalisation” (Helleiner and Pickel, 2005: p. vii). Economic nationalism has traditionally been associated with protectionist policies, which are perceived to contradict liberal policies with their emphasis on free trade and an economically passive, non-interventionist state (Baughn and Yaprak, 1996; Nakano, 2004). However, as Pickel (2003), Shulman (2000) and Nakano (2004) argue, economic nationalism is still relevant and does not contradict liberal policies. The purpose of this paper is firstly to demonstrate the relevance of economic nationalism. Secondly, by investigating the origins of neoliberal economic policies and the motives behind them, using policy formulation in Estonia as a case, I show how Estonian national identity shaped economic policy in post-socialist Estonia. I claim that economic nationalism and economic liberalism are not a dichotomy. I argue that Estonian policy formulators decided to pursue neoliberal policies because they perceived them to best serve their objectives of regaining and maintaining their sovereignty, breaking away from the geopolitical, economic and cultural influence of Russia, and reorienting their economy towards Western Europe. I draw a parallel between Estonian economic nationalism and neoliberal values. 1 Estonia’s post-socialist administration is among the “very few, that explicitly identify themselves as neoliberal” (Larner, 2000: 8). As a leading Estonian economist declared: “I am a supporter of neoliberal fields in economy” (interview). Estonian policy makers consider the neoliberal trajectory as the only viable path to closing the gap between Estonian and western standards of living, and maintaining the economic, political and cultural sovereignty of their nation.
  • ECONOMIC NATIONALISM OR PROGRESSIVE GLOBALISATION? the Choice for Modern Government

    ECONOMIC NATIONALISM OR PROGRESSIVE GLOBALISATION? the Choice for Modern Government

    ECONOMIC NATIONALISM OR PROGRESSIVE GLOBALISATION? The choice for modern government Alex Karalis Isaac TRAY - Criticism of globalisation – once confined to academia and the margins of politics – is becoming increasingly mainstream. Understanding the N costs of globalisation, and reducing them, will be crucial to improving I our standard of living over the next decade. However, the emergence of economic nationalism as a popular alternative to open markets works against such a future. Economic nationalism supposes that we can only prosper at the expense of others, and that we can S exclude others from our markets while still enjoying access to theirs. ’ Economic nationalism is becoming popular on both the left and the right, following its growth in Europe and the USA. Britain’s next prime minister will be under pressure to depart from our traditional open stance towards global markets. This would be an economic and social disaster. Liberals and PM progressives should be united in resisting ‘protectionism-lite’, a policy that creates poverty and international tension. But progressives must >>> 2 ECONOMIC NATIONALISM OR PROGRESSIVE GLOBALISATION? First published by The Social Market Foundation The Social Market Foundation, The Foundation’s main activity is to March 2007 commission and publish original papers by independent academic and other experts IN-TRAY The Social Market Foundation on key topics in the economic and social 11 Tufton Street fields, with a view to stimulating public London SW1P 3QB discussion on the performance of markets PM’S and the social framework within which Copyright © The Social Market they operate. Foundation, 2007 The Foundation is a registered charity The moral right of the authors has been and a company limited by guarantee.
  • Nationalism and the Economy: Explorations Into a Neglected Relationship'

    Nationalism and the Economy: Explorations Into a Neglected Relationship'

    H-Diplo Rutland on Berger and Fetzer, 'Nationalism and the Economy: Explorations into a Neglected Relationship' Review published on Saturday, August 3, 2019 Stefan Berger, Thomas Fetzer, ed. Nationalism and the Economy: Explorations into a Neglected Relationship. Budapest: Central European University Press, 2019. 330 pp. $65.00 (cloth), ISBN 978-963-386-198-1. Reviewed by Peter Rutland (Wesleyan University)Published on H-Diplo (August, 2019) Commissioned by Seth Offenbach (Bronx Community College, The City University of New York) Printable Version: http://www.h-net.org/reviews/showpdf.php?id=54174 There is a dearth of literature on the intersection of economics and nationalism, a subject that was first broached in a pivotal 2005 collection edited by Eric Helleiner and Andreas Pickel,Economic Nationalism in a Globalizing World. A Google ngram search records the first use of the term “economic nationalism” in 1898, with a sharp peak in usage in 1938, after which it fell off by two- thirds by the mid-1950s. Stefan Berger and Thomas Fetzer have assembled a team of a dozen authors to tackle the question, through a mixture of literature reviews and case studies. They rightly argue that nationalism scholars tend to focus on state power and cultural representation at the expense of economics, while economists in turn largely overlook the question of nationalism. One strength of the collection is its interdisciplinary nature; one drawback is that most of the fourteen chapters focus on Europe (there is one chapter on land policy in Israel and one on the Chinese diaspora). One of the central arguments in the book is that economic nationalism should be understood as a broader phenomenon than mere protectionism—the creation of tariff and other barriers to deter foreign trade and investment.
  • Economic Patriotism: Reinventing Control Over Open Markets Ben Clift & Cornelia Woll Published Online: 08 Feb 2012

    Economic Patriotism: Reinventing Control Over Open Markets Ben Clift & Cornelia Woll Published Online: 08 Feb 2012

    This article was downloaded by: [MPI Max-Planck-institute Fur Gesellschaftsforschung] On: 01 August 2013, At: 04:47 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Journal of European Public Policy Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rjpp20 Economic patriotism: reinventing control over open markets Ben Clift & Cornelia Woll Published online: 08 Feb 2012. To cite this article: Ben Clift & Cornelia Woll (2012) Economic patriotism: reinventing control over open markets, Journal of European Public Policy, 19:3, 307-323, DOI: 10.1080/13501763.2011.638117 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2011.638117 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Versions of published Taylor & Francis and Routledge Open articles and Taylor & Francis and Routledge Open Select articles posted to institutional or subject repositories or any other third-party website are without warranty from Taylor & Francis of any kind, either expressed or implied, including, but not limited to, warranties of merchantability, fitness for a particular purpose, or non- infringement. Any opinions and views expressed in this article are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis.
  • Economic Nationalism A

    Economic Nationalism A

    Today’s Menu I Civic Nationalism (cont.) A. Mazzini: unity of liberalism and Nationalism B. Hamilton and Jefferson: Tensions between Liberalism and Nationalism II. Ethnic Nationalism: Germany A. How did it arise? B. Herder C. Father Jahn and Fichte III. Nationalism and Imperialism IV. Economic Nationalism A. List B. The key principles of Economic Nationalism C. Economic Nationalism American Style 1. How to structure Political Economy: Liberal or Nationalist? a. How to use labor b. How to use capital c. How to deal with foreign economic policy d. How to deal with debt 1) Hamilton vs. Jefferson 2) Hamilton’s proposal: A National Bank 3) Jefferson’s objections 4) Hamilton wins: A National Bank is Created Guiseppe Mazzini You are free, and therefore responsible. From this moral liberty is derived your right to political liberty, your duty to conquer it for yourselves and to keep it inviolate, and the duty of others not to limit it. Do not be led astray by hopes of material progress which in your present conditions can only be illusions. Your Country alone can fulfill these hopes. You cannot obtain your rights except by obeying the commands of Duty. O my Brothers ! love your Country. Our Country is our home, the home which God has given us, with which we have a more intimate and quicker communion of feeling and thought than with others; a family which by its concentration upon a given spot, and by the homogeneous nature of its elements, is destined for a special kind of activity. Our Country is our field of labour; the products of our activity must go forth from it for the benefit of the whole earth; In labouring according to true principles for our Country we are labouring for Humanity; Clash between classic Liberalism and Nationalism: Hamilton and Jefferson Jefferson: Purpose of Govt.