The Future of Urban Research: Nonmarket Interactions [With Comments] Author(S): Edward L

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Future of Urban Research: Nonmarket Interactions [With Comments] Author(S): Edward L The Future of Urban Research: Nonmarket Interactions [with Comments] Author(s): Edward L. Glaeser, Vernon Henderson and Robert P. Inman Reviewed work(s): Source: Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs, (2000), pp. 101-149 Published by: Brookings Institution Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25067375 . Accessed: 02/10/2012 13:34 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Brookings Institution Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Brookings- Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs. http://www.jstor.org EDWARD L. GLAESER Harvard University The Future of Urban Research: Nonmarket Interactions modern growth theory argues that intellectual spillovers?ideaflows among individuals that are not mediated by themarket?are a linchpin of eco nomic progress. In Paul Romer's seminal work, endogenous economic growth requires increasing returns.1Without nonmarket intellectual spillovers or some form of externality, increasing returns and economic competition cannot coex ist. In Romer's now canonical model of growth, idea flows are seen as the basis for economic progress; the robust relationship between human capital and economic growth has been taken as support for the importance of these intellectual spillovers. Social capital theory argues that "social capital, connections, social net works are much more correlated with human happiness than is financial capital."2 In large surveys such as the General Social Survey (GSS), measures of social connection (such as churchgoing or membership in organizations) aremore strongly connected with self-reported happiness than income is. This body of research also claims that nonmarket social interactions (for example, membership in choral societies) are an important factor in determining the success of governments and societies at large. Social ties among individuals are thought to be critical in overcoming citizens' apathy and "making democ racy work."3 These two large, separate literatures have independently concluded that non market interactions are extremely important. Only an economist could be surprised by such a deduction. The tendency of economists to ignore these 1. Romer (1986). 2. Putnam (1999). 3. Putnam (1993). 101 102 Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs: 2000 interactions has led us to disregard critical segments of the economy. Over the next ten years, I believe that nonmarket interactions will be at the forefront of economic research. There are isolated examples of research on nonmarket interactions in urban economics, including Alfred Marshall's famous analysis of human-capital transfers in agglomerated areas and Jane Jacobs's discussion of idea flows among innovators in cities. Work on ghettos and discrimination has indeed often addressed the existence of nonmarket interactions.4 But traditional urban economics, such as research on real estate, has been primarily oriented toward themarket.5 Papers on local public finance often address externalities but treat them usually as mere assumptions and rarely in depth. Even the seminal work of Paul Krugman in part derives its strength from its ability to explain eco nomic agglomerations without resorting to ad hoc external effects.6 Nonmarket Interactions and Cities Nonmarket interactions occur when one individual influences another with out the exchange of money. The first kind of these interactions involves voluntary participation of both individuals. Neighbors' doing favors for one another is an example of this kind, and this fits our usual paradigm?there is a cost for one person and usually a benefit for another. In some circumstances, such interactions could be done through the market (that is, you could pay your neighbor every time he lent you his rake). These interactions do not involve cash, mainly because they are sufficiently small and sufficiently common that reciprocity saves transaction costs. Occasionally they are done out of altru ism (for example, caring for a sick friend). In some cases there may even be a social stigma attached to using or accepting money for a particular service (for example, donating organs). In dense urban areas, where the extent of the market is great, these inter actions may evolve from nonmarket interactions into market interactions. For example, in a small town a relative may serve as an amateur nurse for a sick 4. Researchers in this area have emphasized ghetto residents' lack of informational access tomainstream society. Taste-based discrimination (as opposed to statistical discrimination) also reflects a nonmarket interaction inwhich proximity to one group appears to cause psychic harm to others. 5. Urban sociologists such as Wirth (1938) have given these interactions more attention. 6. Krugman (1991). Edward L. Glaeser 103 outpatient because professional nurses are rare. In a large city, this service might more commonly be performed in the context of a market. The second kind of nonmarket interactions are classic externalities?for example, the positive effects of role models, or acquiring human capital through the observation of a neighbor's successes and failures.7 In these cases, it takes effort to stop the interactions?that is, unless the influencing party specifi cally works to stop the other party from observing, the interaction will take place (at no cost to the influencing party)?so it ismuch less natural to imag ine such interactions' being regulated by the market. Often physically proximate individuals create both kinds of nonmarket interactions with one another. For example, my research is improved by the work of my colleagues both because of the actions they take to help my work (reading my papers, talking tome), which impose costs on them, and because I learn by watching them do research. Spatial proximity (and hence urban density) facilitates the first kind of non market interaction, as proximity makes reciprocal relationships easier to start and maintain. The second kind of interaction even more strongly depends on spatial proximity. In many cases, these effortless transmissions of ideas and values depend on sight or hearing. Even if the affected person has not seen or heard the influential person himself, it is often true that he knows someone who has had this personal contact. Obviously, the ability to see or hear depre ciates sharply with space. Indeed, empirical evidence supports the idea that the effect of this prox imity on nonmarket transactions is large. The work of Adam B. Jaffe, Manuel Trajtenberg, and Rebecca Henderson shows the extent to which patent cita tions decline with physical distance. Survey data show that the correlation between distance (measured in time to arrive) between friends and frequency of contacts is 64 percent.8 In nonmarket transactions (particularly of the second kind), individuals rarely receive the full social returns for their actions: these transactions are rife with externalities. When spatial distance deters standard trade, the increase in transport costs will only reduce market transactions that have social bene fit equal to or less than those costs. Because of the externalities associated with nonmarket interactions, however, an equal increase in transport costs will reduce social interactions with social returns thatmay be much larger than the 7. SeeWilson (1987). 8. Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson (1993); and author's calculations from the General Social Survey. 104 Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs: 2000 change in costs. This might explain why small differences in the architecture of work environments (the presence of an office lounge, the arrangement of offices in close proximity) might make a large difference to the overall qual ity of social connection in the organization. Urban economics needs to increase its focus on nonmarket interactions because they are central to an understanding of causes and effects in cities. The example of Paul Krugman illustrates that a brilliant theorist can explain cities without addressing nonmarket interactions.9 But it is less obvious tome why one would want to do so. The flow of ideas and values that occurs through face-to-face interaction may be the most interesting feature of cities. Further more, the market for space?that is, the real-estate market?also appears to be driven to a large extent by the relative presence or absence of particular forms of nonmarket interactions in different areas. Urban economics cannot continue tomake progress toward understanding its basic issues, namely, the causes and consequences of human density, without learning much more about nonmarket interactions. Since nonmarket interactions are so determined by space, and the spatial organization of economic activities is so determined by nonmarket interac tions, the expansion of study into nonmarket interactions is naturally the province of urban economists. This paper first argues that space is crucial in understanding nonmarket interactions. I then identify areas that urban eco nomics must explore in the future. I begin with idea flows and human-capital spillovers in cities. I then discuss peer effects and
Recommended publications
  • The Location Market
    2012] 637 THE LOCATION MARKET Daniel B. Rodriguez*and David Schleicher- INTRODUCTION Individual location decisions are not given much respect by local gov- ernments. Governments frequently use zoning and other regulatory rules to spread development across a city, claiming that the whole city, and not just one favored or disfavored part, should get the benefits and bear the costs of new development.' Local governments also create incentives to encourage certain types of development to locate in certain areas-using policy tools that range from non-cumulative zoning to outright subsidies-in order to create particular mixes of industrial, commercial, and residential develop- ment.2 However, the arguments in favor of these policies frequently rely upon a specious depiction of the incentives of governmental decisionmakers on the one hand and private citizens on the other.' That is, they fail to see the wisdom behind the old saying that the three most im- portant factors in real estate are "location, location, location." When justifying such policies, officials and interest groups rely on an assumption, frequently unstated, that property developers, businesses, and individuals just do not care very much (or do not have the right incentives to care) about where they locate inside a given city.4 And this assumption is surely wrong. Instead, locational decisions are motivated by specific bene- fits citizens and firms receive when they choose to reside in one specific area rather than in another.' Moreover, locational decisions are frequently "sticky"-that is, they are resistant to governmental management and are resistant for good reasons. 6 The fact that residents do in fact care about the identity and number of their neighbors for reasons other than their potential for creating nuisances * Dean and Harold Washington Professor, Northwestern University School of Law.
    [Show full text]
  • Reinventing Boston: the Changing American City
    REINVENTING BOSTON: THE CHANGING AMERICAN CITY United States in the World 24, Fall 2010 Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:15 pm-2:30 pm, Harvard Hall 104 Weekly Sections: To Be Arranged Christopher Winship David Luberoff Diker-Tishman Professor of Sociology Executive Director [email protected] Rappaport Institute for Greater Boston 620 William James Hall [email protected] 617-495-9821 Taubman 352, KSG, 617-495-1346 Office hours: By Appointment Office hours: By Appointment Josh Wakeham Head Teaching Fellow [email protected] 618 William James Hall In the 1970’s, Boston was marred by racial violence and its economy was rapidly collapsing. Boston, as was claimed at the time about many other American cities, was dying. Given this situation, how is it that Boston has come to reinvent itself and become one of America’s most successful and vibrant cities in the 21st century? Today, Boston, like many other cities, faces a variety of challenges brought on by the worldwide economic downturn. Can Boston maintain its success in coming years? And what, if anything, can Boston’s reinvention teach us about cities in general? This course seeks to answer these interrelated questions via a unique combination of lectures by both scholars and civic leaders, a wide array of readings, student observations of Boston neighborhoods, and student research on the city’s neighborhoods, leaders, and institutions. Taken together, the lectures, readings, neighborhood visits, and research should give students not only a better understanding and “feel” for Boston but also a better understanding and appreciation for cities in general. COURSE OVERVIEW This course seeks to help students understand how economic, social, and political factors have combined to produce what has become known as Boston’s Renaissance.
    [Show full text]
  • Regulation and the Rise of Housing Prices in Greater Boston a Study Based on New Data from 187 Communities in Eastern Massachusetts
    LAND USE REGULATION AND HOUSING Regulation and the Rise of Housing Prices in Greater Boston A study based on new data from 187 communities in eastern Massachusetts By Edward L. Glaeser, Jenny Schuetz and Bryce Ward, Harvard University January 5, 2006 RAPPAPORT Institute for Greater Boston Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University Regulation and the Rise of Housing Prices in Greater Boston This paper is part of the Initiative on Local Housing Regulation, a joint effort of the Pioneer Institute for Public Policy Research and Harvard Universityʼs Rappaport Institute for Greater Boston. As part of this initiative, researchers at the Pioneer Institute and the Rappaport Institute have assembled and coded a database on zoning codes, subdivision requirements, and environmental regulations that as of 2004 governed land use in 187 communities in eastern and central Massachusetts. The searchable database is available at www.pioneerinstitute.org/municipalregs/. The site also houses summary reports, analyses of the data, and a downloadable version of the database in formats that can be used for econometric analyses. In coming months, the Pioneer Institute and the Rappaport Institute will also be issuing papers and policy briefs, some jointly and some individually, on land-use regulation in greater Boston. Authors Edward L. Glaeser is the Fred and Eleanor Glimp Professor of Economics in Harvardʼs Faculty of Arts and Sciences and is director of Harvardʼs Rappaport Institute for Greater Boston. He teaches urban and social economics and micro- economic theory and has published dozens of papers on cities, economic growth, housing prices, and law and economics. Jenny Schuetz is a doctoral student in public policy at Harvardʼs Kennedy School of Government.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Did the West Extend the Franchise?: Democracy, Inequality and Growth in Historical Perspective
    WHYDID THEWEST EXTEND THEFRANCHISE? DEMOCRACY,INEQUALITY,AND GROWTHIN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE* DARON ACEMOGLU AND JAMES A. ROBINSON During thenineteenth century mostWestern societies extended voting rights, adecisionthat led tounprecedented redistributive programs. We argue that these politicalreforms can be viewed as strategic decisions by the political elite to preventwidespread social unrest and revolution. Political transition, rather than redistributionunder existing political institutions, occurs becausecurrent trans- fersdo not ensure future transfers, while the extension of the franchise changes futurepolitical equilibria and acts as a commitmentto redistribution. Our theory alsooffers a novelexplanation for the Kuznets curve inmany Western economies duringthis period, with the fall in inequality following redistribution due to democratization. I. INTRODUCTION Thenineteenth century was aperiodof fundamental political reformand unprecedentedchanges in taxation and redistribu- tion.Britain, forexample, was transformedfrom an ‘‘oligarchy’’ runby an eliteto a democracy.Thefranchise was extendedin 1832 and thenagain in 1867 and 1884, transferringvoting rights toportionsof the society with noprevious political representation. Thedecades afterthe political reformswitnessed radical social reforms,increased taxation, and theextension of educationto the masses.Moreover, as notedby Kuznets,inequality ,whichwas previouslyincreasing, started todecline during this period:the Gini coefficientfor income inequality in England and Waleshad risenfrom
    [Show full text]
  • The Seminal Work of Becker (1967) Launched the Formal Study of Labor
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PREJUDICE AND THE ECONOMICS OF DISCRIMINATION Kerwin Kofi Charles Jonathan Guryan Working Paper 13661 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13661 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2007 The authors thank Gary Becker, John Bound, Charlie Brown, Henry Farber, Larry Katz, Kevin Lang, Kevin Murphy and Paul Oyer for helpful discussions regarding this work, seminar participants at the University of Chicago, Harvard, Wharton, CUNY, Yale, Brown, the Institute for Research on Poverty, Princeton and the University of Georgia for their suggestions and Phil Wengerd for research assistance. Guryan thanks the University of Chicago GSB and the Industrial Relations and Education Research Sections at Princeton University for research support. This research was also funded in part by the George J. Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State at the University of Chicago Graduate School of Business. All errors are our own. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2007 by Kerwin Kofi Charles and Jonathan Guryan. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Prejudice and The Economics of Discrimination Kerwin Kofi Charles and Jonathan Guryan NBER Working Paper No. 13661 December 2007 JEL No. J01,J7 ABSTRACT This paper tests the predictions about the relationship between racial prejudice and racial wage gaps from Becker's (1957) seminal work on employer discrimination - something which has not previously been done in the large economics discrimination literature.
    [Show full text]
  • The Growth of Small, Cold Cities
    The Growth of Small, Cold Cities Edward Glaeser Director, Rappaport Institute for Greater Boston and Professor of Economics, Harvard University Forum on “Collaboration and Leadership in Smaller, Industrial Cities” July 13, 2011 www.hks.harvard.edu/centers/rappaport Outline • Patterns in the 2010 Census – Density, Income, Temperature and Skills • Cities are not Counties and Small Cities are Not Big Cities • What Matters for Medium-Size City Growth within the U.S.? • How Does Massachusetts Differ? • Policy Questions Growth and Income in MA Growth and Income in CT Growth and Income in RI Growth and Income in NH Innovation in the Industrial Age Francis Cabot Lowell goes to Manchester and memorizes the structure of power looms– Boston associates establish Lowell and Lawrence. The “father of American watch-making,” “went to Boston to perfect himself as a journeyman watchmaker ... so that he could get the instruction of Tubal Hone, then the best watch- maker in America.” Lawrence establishes the Lawrence Scientific School at Harvard; Rogers comes to Boston for the scientific atmosphere and gets the legislature to found M.I.T. The Decline of the Costs of Moving Goods Temperature and Growth: Large Cities Temperature and Growth: Small Cities College Education and Growth in Larger (over 200k), Colder Cities College Education and Growth: Colder, Smaller Cities Chinitz: Contrasts in Agglomeration: New York and Pittsburgh What Does the Model Teach Us? Five variables explain about 40 percent of the growth rates in colder (under 40 degrees), smaller (under 200k) cities. • January Temperature still matters– 10 degrees, 5 percentage points more growth. • Share with HS degrees– 10 percentage points is 6.1 percentage points more growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Housing Markets Economy
    531-38784_ch00_1P.qxp 1/14/09 1:00 AM Page i HOUSING MARKETS AND THE ECONOMY ___–1 ___ 0 ___+1 531-38784_ch00_1P.qxp 1/14/09 1:00 AM Page ii –1___ 0___ +1___ 531-38784_ch00_1P.qxp 1/14/09 1:00 AM Page iii HOUSING MARKETS AND THE ECONOMY Risk, Regulation, and Policy o ESSAYS IN HONOR OF KARL E. CASE Edited by EDWARD L. GLAESER AND JOHN M. QUIGLEY ___–1 ___ 0 ___+1 531-38784_ch00_1P.qxp 1/14/09 1:00 AM Page iv © 2009 by the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy All rights reserved. Library of Congress Cataloging- in- Publication Data Housing markets and the economy: risk, regulation, and policy: essays in honor of Karl E. Case / edited by Edward L. Glaeser and John M. Quigley. p. cm. Papers from a conference sponsored by the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, held in Dec. 2007. Includes index. ISBN 978- 1- 55844- 184- 2 1. Housing—United States— Congresses. 2. Housing policy— United States— Congresses. 3. Housing—Prices—United States— Congresses. 4. Housing—Law and legislation— United States— Congresses. I. Case, Karl E. II. Glaeser, Edward L. (Edward Ludwig), 1967– III. Quigley, John M., 1942–HD7293.H678 2009 333.33'80973—dc22 2008043990 Designed by Westchester Book Composition Composed in Electra LH Regular by Westchester Book Composition in Danbury, Connecticut. Printed and bound by (printer) in (city, state). The paper is (paper name), an acid- free, recycled(?)sheet. –1___ 0___ MANUFACTURED IN THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA +1___ 531-38784_ch00_1P.qxp 1/14/09 1:00 AM Page v Contents List of Figures vii List of Tables ix Foreword xiii GREGORY K.
    [Show full text]
  • Mclane Teammates Reading Program Spring 2017 Texas Tech University
    McLane Teammates Reading Program Spring 2017 Texas Tech University Reading Schedule Introduction – January 25, 2017 . Den Uyl, Douglas J. (2000). “Education as Civil Society.” In Pierre F. Goodrich, Ed., Why Liberty? A Collection of Liberty Fund Essays. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc. 67-72. Session 1 – February 1, 2017 – The Importance of Cities . Glaeser, Edward. (2011) “Our Urban Species.” In Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier. New York, NY: Penguin Press. 1-15. Florida, Richard. (2005) “Cities and the Creative Class.” In Cities and the Creative Class. New York, NY: Routledge. 27-45. Jacobs, Jane. (1961) “Introduction.” In The Death and Life of Great American Cities. New York, NY: Vintage Books. 3-25. Session 2 – February 15, 2017 – Urban Decline . Glaeser, Edward. (2011) “Why Do Cities Decline?” In Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier. New York, NY: Penguin Press. 41-67. Downs, Anthony. (1994) “Why We Need a New Vision.” In New Visions for Metropolitan America. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. 3-16. –––––––– (1994) “Factors Affecting Growth.” 17-30. Summit at Southern Methodist University – February 17-18, 2017 – Edward Glaeser . Glaeser, Edward. (2011) “Why Do They Make in Bangalore?” In Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier. New York, NY: Penguin Press. 17-40. –––––––– (2011) “How Do Cities Succeed?” 223-246. 1 Session 3 – February 22, 2017 – Sprawl and Local Economic Development . Glaeser, Edward. (2011) “Why Has Sprawl Spread?” In Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier.
    [Show full text]
  • Nber Working Paper Series Infrastructure and Urban
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INFRASTRUCTURE AND URBAN FORM Edward L. Glaeser Working Paper 28287 http://www.nber.org/papers/w28287 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2020 I am grateful to Margaret Brissenden and Eliza Glaeser for editorial assistance. Greg Ingram provided excellent comments. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2020 by Edward L. Glaeser. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Infrastructure and Urban Form Edward L. Glaeser NBER Working Paper No. 28287 December 2020 JEL No. F61,N70,R14,R41 ABSTRACT Cities are shaped by transportation infrastructure. Older cities were anchored by waterways. Nineteenth century cities followed the path of streetcars and subways. The 20th century city rebuilt itself around the car. The close connection between transportation and urban form is natural, since cities are defined by their density. Physical proximity and transportation investments serve the common cause of reducing the transportation costs for goods, people and ideas. The close connection between transportation and urban form suggests the need for spatial equilibrium models that embed a full set of equilibrium effects into any evaluation of transportation spending. Their connection implies that restrictions on land use will change, and often reduce, the value of investing in transportation infrastructure.
    [Show full text]
  • Exploring Edward Glaeser's City JAMIE PECK
    Economic rationality meets celebrity urbanology: exploring Edward Glaeser’s city JAMIE PECK Forthcoming in International Journal of Urban & Regional Research (2015) Abstract The paper presents a critique of the popular and public-policy work of Harvard economist Edward Glaeser, which has been constructed at the nexus of neoclassical economic rationality and celebrity urbanology. Widely recognized as one of the world’s leading urbanists, Glaeser has combined a high-flying academic career with public-policy engagement and extensive work as a newspaper columnist and media commentator— enabled by a long-standing affiliation with the Manhattan Institute, a leading conservative think tank. The critique is pointed, but seeks to exceed argumentum ad hominem by calling attention to sociopolitical and institutional factors that have facilitated the accelerated diffusion and enlarged dominion of this model (and mode) of microeconomically rationalized urbanism, including the production of new forms of intellectual marketing, the construction of colonizing variants of urban-economic expertise, and the ongoing rearticulation and creeping consolidation of market-centric policy norms. The paper argues that a distinctive form of urban-economic orthodoxy is under construction, based on potent fusion of scientific reasoning and pop presentation, combining ideologically disciplined applications of neoclassical economics with dissemination in the register of the ‘freakonomics’ franchise. Edward Glaeser’s intellectual accomplishments have been significant, but the ‘Glaeser effect’ is more than a story of individual scholarly endeavor, calling for more than a merely ‘internal’ critique. Its conformity to Manhattan Institute principles testifies to a telling consistency of ideological purpose, contributing as it does to a sustained effort rationalize and normalize lean and limited modes of neoliberal urban governance, fortified by microeconomic reason.
    [Show full text]
  • What Would a Graduate Seminar on Geography Look Like
    Political Science 344 Politics and Geography Mondays, 1:15-4:05 PM 400 Encina Hall West Instructors: Karen Long Jusko and Jonathan Rodden This course introduces students to basics techniques for the exploration of political and economic geography while covering a range of substantive themes. Students will learn to produce and analyze maps and learn the basics of spatial data analysis, and apply these skills to a range of exciting questions at the intersection of political and economic geography. This course begins with a brisk overview of attempts to answer some of the basic questions of economic geography and urban economics. What explains the spatial location of workers, firms, and economic activity? What explains the rise (and fall) of cities, suburbs, and residential segregation around the world? Can we draw any general conclusions about the spatial location of income groups? We start with these questions in part because they have a variety of potential political consequences that have largely been ignored by political scientists, and the goal of the course is to explore them. First, we ask whether lessons from urban economics and economic geography have any implications for the geography of political preferences and voting behavior, and explore the ways in which the geographic distribution of preferences might interact with electoral institutions. Next, we explore geographic underpinnings of sectionalism, regionalism, and political polarization, revisiting and hopefully moving beyond debates about “red states and blue states.” We then examine the implications of geography for theories and empirical analyses of inter-personal redistribution and the welfare state. Next we address “contextual” and “neighborhood” effects, and examine the potential for GIS data to help explain ethnic conflict.
    [Show full text]
  • Housing Affordability Is Attainable Through Regulatory Reform
    PUBLIC INTEREST COMMENT HOUSING AFFORDABILITY IS ATTAINABLE THROUGH REGULATORY REFORM SALIM FURTH Senior Research Fellow, Mercatus Center at George Mason University EMILY HAMILTON Research Fellow, Mercatus Center at George Mason University White House Council on Eliminating Regulatory Barriers to Affordable Housing; Request for Information Agency: US Department of Housing and Urban Development Comment Period Opens: November 22, 2019 Comment Period Closes: January 21, 2020 Submitted: January 9, 2020 Docket No. FR-6187-N-01 Thank you for the opportunity to provide information to the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) pertaining to the White House Council on Eliminating Regulatory Barriers to Affordable Housing.1 The Mercatus Center at George Mason University is dedicated to bridging the gap between academic ideas and real-world problems and to advancing knowledge about the likely consequences of proposed regulation for private markets. Accordingly, this comment represents the views of no particular party or interest group. The president and Secretary Carson have directed attention to the problem of expensive housing in cities across the United States and correctly tied it to artificial scarcities induced by overregulation. Since land use regulation is under the authority of state governments and is largely administered by local governments, federal authorities have relatively little scope for corrective action. In this comment, we first note two avenues for immediate federal action to alleviate artificial unaffordability. Then, in response to query IV(6)(a), we provide an annotated list of research resources on regulation, emphasizing those published by the Mercatus Center. Finally, we address query IV(6)(b) directly. 1. The authors thank Isaac LaGrand for his research assistance on this comment.
    [Show full text]