Uncorrected Proof

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Uncorrected Proof AUTHOR'S PROOF JrnlID 10816_ArtID 9236_Proof# 1 - 19/12/2014 J Archaeol Method Theory DOI 10.1007/s10816-014-9236-5 31 2 Are Social Networks Survival Networks? An Example 4 from the Late Pre-Hispanic US Southwest 5 Lewis Borck & Barbara J. Mills & 6 Matthew A. Peeples & Jeffery J. Clark 7 8 # Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014 9 10 Abstract Archaeologists have regarded social networks as both the links through 11 which people transmitted information and goods as well as a form of social storage 12 creating relationships that could be drawn upon in times of subsistence shortfalls or 13 other deleterious environmental conditions. In this article, formal social network 14 analytical (SNA) methods are applied to archaeological data from the late pre- 15 Hispanic North American Southwest to look at what kinds of social networks charac- 16 terized those regions that were the most enduring versus those that were depopulated 17 over a 250-year period (A.D. 1200–1450). In that time, large areas of the Southwest 18 were no longer used for residential purposes, some of which corresponds with well- 19 documented region-wide drought. Past research has demonstrated that some population 20 levels could have been maintained in these regions, yet regional scale depopulation 21 occurred. We look at the degree to which the network level property of embeddedness, 22 along with population size, can help to explain why some regions were depopulated 23 and others were not. SNA can help archaeologists examine why emigration occurred in 24 some areas following an environmental crisis while other areas continued to be 25 inhabited and even received migrants. Moreover, we modify SNA techniques to take 26 full advantage of the time depth and spatial and demographic variability of our 27 archaeological data set. The results of this study should be of interest to those who 28 seek to understand human responses to past, present, and future worldwide catastrophes 29 since it isUNCORRECTED now widely recognized that responses to major human PROOF disasters, such as 30 hurricanes, were “likely to be shaped by pre-existing or new social networks” (as 31 reported by Suter et al. (Research and Policy Review 28:1–10, 2009)). 32 Keywords Social network analysis . E–Iindex. Migration . Resilience . Salado . 33 Persistence 34 L. Borck (*) : B. J. Mills School of Anthropology, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ 85721, USA Q2 e-mail: [email protected] L. Borck : M. A. Peeples : J. J. Clark Archaeology Southwest, Tucson, AZ 85701, USA AUTHOR'SJrnlID 10816_ArtID 9236_Proof# PROOF 1 - 19/12/2014 Borck et al. Overview 35 Independence? That’s middle-class blasphemy. We are all dependent on one 3638 another, every soul of us on earth. (Shaw 1988, Act V, par. 244) 39 37 An enduring archaeological problem is why some regions were depopulated while 41 inhabitants remained in other areas for centuries and even millennia. When depopula- 4042 tion is sudden and arises at large spatial scales, it has often been called “collapse.” We 43 place this term in scare quotes because it has been interpreted to mean cultural 44 discontinuity—such as the Hohokam or Chaco “collapse” in the US Southwest or the 45 “collapse” of the Maya in Central America—without considering continuities in 46 indigenous populations through processes such as migration and decentralized social 47 reorganizations (see also the many critiques of the term, e.g.,Hegmonet al. 1998; 48 McAnany and Yoffee 2010;Middleton2012; Wilcox 2009). When an entireOF region is 49 depopulated, it frequently entails large-scale migrations. The underlying reasons for 50 these demographic shifts from one area to another have been central to understanding 51 human history across the globe (e.g.,Anthony1990;Cameron2013RO). 52 Another way to approach the problem is to look at why and how people are able to 53 persist in some regions over long periods. What makes settlementsP in these regions 54 more successful than others? Persistence may also be associated with the concept of 55 resilience (Holling and Gunderson 2002;Holling1973;Redman2005) because 56 communities that endure have withstood threats to their ongoing sustainability. 57 However, in some situations, persistence may be maladaptive rather than adap- 58 tive. For example, generational residential mobility can enhance the resilience 59 of particular individuals and groups (Varien 1999). Staying in one place may not be 60 the best decision because of negativeECTED changes in local, social, or environmental 61 contexts. Nonetheless, migrations are expensive and disruptive to the existing 62 social order and often result in migrants having lower status than the groups 63 they join (Mills 2007). 64 In a recent review of archaeological approaches to “collapse” and resilience, Guy 65 Middleton (2012) suggestsORR that too much emphasis has been placed on environmental 66 factors at the expense of social factors (e.g.,Diamond2005). Archaeologists working in 67 the US Southwest—where a high-resolution paleoclimatic record indicates long-term 68 periods of droughtNC—have recognized that climatic downturns are not sufficient expla- 69 nations forU depopulation and migration (Kohler 2010;Minnis1985;VanWest1994; 70 Wright 2010). As Glowacki (2010, p. 200) pointed out “[c]omplete regional depopu- 71 lation is not a predestined outcome of drought and poor agricultural yield.” Van West 72 (1994; see also Ahlstrom et al. 1995 and Billman et al. 2000) demonstrated that, 73 Q3=Q4 despite the regional depopulation, yields could have sustained some of the population 74 in the Mesa Verde region during the drought of the last quarter of the thirteenth century, 75 albeit at lower levels. Other scholars have highlighted the increased incidence of 76 violence during periods of drought, especially during the early twelfth and late thir- 77 teenth centuries (e.g.,Kuckelmanet al. 2002; Kuckelman and Martin 2012). Kohler 78 (2010) suggested that the crosscutting social institutions that were created after the 79 eleventh century, which enabled the integration of segmentary groups with high 80 residential mobility, produced societies that could no longer easily fission when 81 mobility and social flexibility was required in later periods. These religious institutions 82 AUTHOR'S PROOF JrnlID 10816_ArtID 9236_Proof# 1 - 19/12/2014 Are Social Networks Survival Networks? Q1 would have facilitated intra-regional interaction while at the same time, they may have 83 laid the ground work for future inter-regional conflict and factionalism (Glowacki 84 2010;Kaldahlet al. 2004). 85 What the above Southwestern examples share is an emphasis on the formation, 86 transformation, and/or dissolution of different kinds of social networks. They also 87 largely focus on specific regions. Another way of incorporating social factors into 88 models of regional depopulation is to understand these areas in the context of inter- 89 regional networks (Mills et al. 2013a, b, c). As Hill and his colleagues (2010)pointed 90 out regarding the depopulation of the Mesa Verde area, this region can only be 91 understood by looking at population changes at much larger scales (see also Duff 92 1998). Several previous examples from the northern Southwest illustrate the value of 93 looking at migration across regional boundaries and tie these, either explicitly or 94 implicitly, to large-scale social networks. The intensity and extent of social networks 95 has been widely acknowledged in the anthropological literature as providingOF access to 96 information and resources to minimize risk and uncertainty (Colson 1979;Dyson- 97 Hudson and Smith 1978;HalsteadandO’Shea 1989; Wiessner 1977). This is partic- 98 ularly the case in the literature on foragers but it also pertains toRO agriculturalists in a 99 setting of high environmental variation, such as is found in many periods in the North 100 American Southwest. These authors argue that access to informationP and resources 101 from diverse environments can help populations deal with unpredictability. 102 Importantly, the work of Cordell and colleagues (2007) and Rautman (1993)suggest 103 that the distance and direction of such external connections are important in under- 104 standing how social networks were used to integrate diverse groups. This prior work 105 also shows the importance of inter-regional social networks in creating pathways for 106 future migration. 107 In this paper, we investigate severalECTED aspects of Southwest regions to better under- 108 stand the social factors that, during A.D. 1200–1450, led to regional depopulation on 109 the one hand and regional persistence on the other. We argue that the application of 110 social network analysis (SNA) to archaeological data provides insights into the ways in 111 which interaction at multiple scales (or lack thereof) can explain regional depopulation 112 or persistence. We use SNAORR to look at both internal and external ties to understand the 113 social component of regional depopulations as well as to examine how long-distance 114 ties created viable alternatives to staying in place. We argue that regions with relatively 115 low population sizesNC and relatively closed social networks were especially vulnerable to 116 depopulation.U Those regions with relatively open social networks, or closed networks 117 and large population sizes, were more successful through time. 118 Social Networks and Regional Depopulation 119 SNA refers to a broad range of methods and models, originally derived from the 120 mathematical field of graph theory, for formally exploring the structure of relations 121 among some set of social actors (Wasserman and Faust 1994). The most common 122 means for analyzing and visualizing social networks involves producing network 123 graphs where actors (which can be individuals or larger groups/organizations) are 124 depicted as nodes and the social relationships among these actors are depicted as lines 125 (also known as ties or edges). SNA is particularly useful for understanding the structure 126 AUTHOR'SJrnlID 10816_ArtID 9236_Proof# PROOF 1 - 19/12/2014 Borck et al.
Recommended publications
  • Gifts and Commodities (Second Edition)
    GIFTS AND COMMODITIES Hau BOOKS Executive Editor Giovanni da Col Managing Editor Sean M. Dowdy Editorial Board Anne-Christine Taylor Carlos Fausto Danilyn Rutherford Ilana Gershon Jason Throop Joel Robbins Jonathan Parry Michael Lempert Stephan Palmié www.haubooks.com GIFTS AND COMMODITIES (SECOND EditIon) C. A. Gregory Foreword by Marilyn Strathern New Preface by the Author Hau Books Chicago © 2015 by C. A. Gregory and Hau Books. First Edition © 1982 Academic Press, London. All rights reserved. Cover and layout design: Sheehan Moore Typesetting: Prepress Plus (www.prepressplus.in) ISBN: 978-0-9905050-1-3 LCCN: 2014953483 Hau Books Chicago Distribution Center 11030 S. Langley Chicago, IL 60628 www.haubooks.com Hau Books is marketed and distributed by The University of Chicago Press. www.press.uchicago.edu Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper. For Judy, Polly, and Melanie. Contents Foreword by Marilyn Strathern xi Preface to the first edition xv Preface to the second edition xix Acknowledgments liii Introduction lv PART ONE: CONCEPTS I. THE COmpETING THEOriES 3 Political economy 3 The theory of commodities 3 The theory of gifts 9 Economics 19 The theory of modern goods 19 The theory of traditional goods 22 II. A framEWORK OF ANALYSIS 25 The general relation of production to consumption, distribution, and exchange 26 Marx and Lévi-Strauss on reproduction 26 A simple illustrative example 30 The definition of particular economies 32 viii GIFTS AND COMMODITIES III.FTS GI AND COMMODITIES: CIRCULATION 39 The direct exchange of things 40 The social status of transactors 40 The social status of objects 41 The spatial aspect of exchange 44 The temporal dimension of exchange 46 Value and rank 46 The motivation of transactors 50 The circulation of things 55 Velocity of circulation 55 Roads of gift-debt 57 Production and destruction 59 The circulation of people 62 Work-commodities 62 Work-gifts 62 Women-gifts 63 Classificatory kinship terms and prices 68 Circulation and distribution 69 IV.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes on the Ontology of Design
    Notes on the Ontology of Design Arturo Escobar University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill Contents 1. Introduction ………………………………………………………. ……….. 2 2. Part I. Design for the Real World: But which world? what design? what real? ………………………….. …. 4 3. Part II. In the background of our culture: The rationalistic tradition and the problem of ontological dualism……… 16 4. Part III. Outline of ontological and autonomous design ……………….. 34 5. Part IV. The politics of relationality. Designs for the pluriverse ………. 57 6. Some provisional concluding remarks ………………………………….. 74 7. References ………………………………………………………………….. 78 Note to readers: This ‘paper’ ended up being actually the draft of a short book; the book is likely to have one more chapter, dealing with globalization, development, and environment issues; it is also likely to have examples, and to be written in a less academic manner, or so I hope. I’ve had several tentative titles over the past few years, the most recent one being The Ecological Crisis and the Question of Civilizational Transitions: Designs for the Pluriverse. I’ve been reading, and working with, most of this material for a long time, but some of it is new (to me); this is particularly true for Part I on design. I suspect the text is quite uneven as a result. Part IV is largely cut-and-paste from several texts in English and Spanish, particularly the long preface to the 2nd ed. of Encountering Development. This part will need additional re/writing besides editing and reorganizing. The references are somewhat incomplete; there are a few key design references of which I have been made aware very recently that are not, or not significantly, included (e.g., on participatory design, postcolonial computing, and human-computer interaction).
    [Show full text]
  • Redalyc.Political Ecology of Globality and Diference
    Gestión y Ambiente ISSN: 0124-177X [email protected] Universidad Nacional de Colombia Colombia Escobar, Arturo Political Ecology of Globality and Diference Gestión y Ambiente, vol. 9, núm. 3, diciembre, 2006, pp. 29-44 Universidad Nacional de Colombia Medellín, Colombia Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=169421027009 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative Reflexión Political Ecology of Globality and Diference Recibido para evaluación: 27 de Octubre de 2006 Arturo Escobar 1 Aceptación: 13 de Diciembre de 2006 Recibido versión final: 20 de Diciembre de 2006 Artículo de reflexión, introducción al libro “Regions and Places in the Age of Globality: Social Movements and Biodiversity Conservation in the Colombian Pacific”, próximo a ser publicado, y resultado de un proceso de investigación sobre geopolítica del conocimiento. RESUMEN Este artículo es la introducción a un libro que está en imprenta. El versa sobre la dinámica de la globalidad imperial y su régimen global de colonialidad como una de las carracterísticas más sobresalientes del sistema mundo colonial moderno a comienzos del siglo XXI. También es, en un sentido literal, geopolítica del conocimiento. Presta de Joan Martínez Allier su definición de “ecología política” como el estudio de los conflictos ecológico­distributivos. Argumenta que una globalidad eurocéntrica tiene una contraparte obligatoria en el acto sistemático de “encubrimiento del otro”. Un tipo de “colonialidad global”.Usa seis conceptos clave para comprender el argumento: lugar, capital, naturaleza, desarrollo, e identidad.
    [Show full text]
  • Play As a Foundation for Hunter-Gatherer Social Existence
    Play as a Foundation for Hunter- Gatherer Social Existence • Peter Gray The author offers the thesis that hunter-gatherers promoted, through cultural means, the playful side of their human nature and this made possible their egalitar- ian, nonautocratic, intensely cooperative ways of living. Hunter-gatherer bands, with their fluid membership, are likened to social-play groups, which people could freely join or leave. Freedom to leave the band sets the stage for the individual autonomy, sharing, and consensual decision making within the band. Hunter- gatherers used humor, deliberately, to maintain equality and stop quarrels. Their means of sharing had gamelike qualities. Their religious beliefs and ceremonies were playful, founded on assumptions of equality, humor, and capriciousness among the deities. They maintained playful attitudes in their hunting, gathering, and other sustenance activities, partly by allowing each person to choose when, how, and how much they would engage in such activities. Children were free to play and explore, and through these activities, they acquired the skills, knowl- edge, and values of their culture. Play, in other mammals as well as in humans, counteracts tendencies toward dominance, and hunter-gatherers appear to have promoted play quite deliberately for that purpose. I am a developmental/evolutionary psychologist with a special inter- est in play. Some time ago, I began reading the anthropological literature on hunter-gatherer societies in order to understand how children’s play might contribute to children’s education in those societies. As I read, I became in- creasingly fascinated with hunter-gatherer social life per se. The descriptions I read, by many different researchers who had observed many different hunter- gatherer groups, seemed to be replete with examples of humor and playfulness in adults, not just in children, in all realms of hunter-gatherers’ social existence.
    [Show full text]
  • An Economic Sociological Look at Economic Anthropology
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Aspers, Patrik; Darr, Asaf; Kohl, Sebastian Article An economic sociological look at economic anthropology economic sociology_the european electronic newsletter Provided in Cooperation with: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies (MPIfG), Cologne Suggested Citation: Aspers, Patrik; Darr, Asaf; Kohl, Sebastian (2007) : An economic sociological look at economic anthropology, economic sociology_the european electronic newsletter, ISSN 1871-3351, Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies (MPIfG), Cologne, Vol. 9, Iss. 1, pp. 3-10 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/155897 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available
    [Show full text]
  • The Failure of Substahtivist Social Theory I 3^ a Critical
    3^ I THE FAILURE OF SUBSTAHTIVIST SOCIAL THEORY A CRITICAL REASSESSMENT OF KARL POLANYI Ellen Antler, B.A. University of Chicago, 196? A Thesis Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of K&ster of Arts at The University of Connecticut 1971 APPROVAL PAGE Master of Arts Thesis THE FAILURE OF SUBSTAIJTIVIST SOCIAL THEORY: A CRITICAL REASSESSMENT OF KARL POLANYI Presented by Ellen Antler, B.A. Major Adviser /'i—- Associate Adviser Associate Adviser a c,£-,,v< The University of Connecticut 1971 ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I wish to thanlc Dr* Janes Chester Faris, Daryl Clark White and the Wilbur Cross Library. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ..................................................... 1 PART I. Chapter I. THE RATIONALE FOR POLANYI*S MORALIST, HUMANITARIAN UNDERTAKING: BERATING THE SCOURGE OF INDUSTRIALIZATION .... 8 II. THE CONTENT OF THE NSW ECONOMICS: BOTH HISTORY MID THEORY REVEAL THE MARKET TO BE UNIQUE AND PERNICIOUS ..... 11 III. THE STRATEGY OF THE NEW ECONOMICS I ........................ 16 IV. THE STRATEGY OF THE NEW ECONOMICS II ...................... 21 V. THE STRATEGY OF THE NEW ECONOMICS III ..................... 25 VI. THE NEW ECONOMICS BECOMES A NEW SOCIAL THEORY ............. 30 VII. EVALUATION OF POLANYITS SOCIAL THEORY .................... 1,0 PART II. I. THE SEARCH FOR THE NON-MARKET STATE OF NATURE WITH POLANYI »S OWN TOOLS OF ANALYSIS ................... .......46 II. THE NON-MARKET STATE OF NATURE ...................... 50 III. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS .....................................77
    [Show full text]
  • Research Articles
    research articles Issue Networks, Information, and Interest Group Alliances: The Case of Wisconsin Welfare Politics, 1993–99 Michael T. Heaney, University of Chicago abstract Interest group scholars have long emphasized the importance of group alliances in the policymaking process. But little is known about how groups choose specific alli- ance partners; that is, who works with whom? Social embeddedness theory suggests that the social location of groups in issue networks affects the information available to them about potential partners and the desirability of particular alliances. To test this hypothesis, I use data from interviews with representatives of 57 interest groups and 46 other significant political actors involved in Wisconsin’s 1993–99 welfare policy debate to model alliance formation with two-stage conditional maximum like- lihood regression (2SCML). I find substantial support for my social embeddedness hypotheses that alliance formation is encouraged by previous network interaction, contact with mutual third parties, and having a central position in a network. In short, the placement of groups in networks serves to facilitate alliances among some pairs of groups and to cut off potential connections among others. The last quarter century has witnessed an explosion of interest group formation and participation in policymaking at the state and national levels in the United States (Baumgartner and Jones 1993; Berry 1999; Gray and Lowery 1996). As interest group communities have become larger and more complex, individual groups may find themselves to be less influential than in the past (Salisbury 1990). This crowding of interest communities has led groups to devise new strategies to gain policymaking influence.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Settling Good for Pastoralists?
    Is Settling Good for Pastoralists? The Effects of Pastoral Sedentarization on Children’s Nutrition, Growth, and Health Among Rendille and Ariaal of Marsabit District, Northern Kenya Elliot Fratkin, Martha A Nathan, and Eric A. Roth Elliot Fratkin PhD, Department of Anthropology, Smith College, Northampton, Massachusetts 01063 USA and Graduate Faculty, Department of Anthropology, University of Massachusetts-Amherst, Amherst MA 01002 USA ([email protected] for correspondence) Martha A Nathan MD, Brightwood Health Center, Baystate Medical Center, 380 Plainfield Street, Springfield MA 01107 and Tufts University School of Medicine, Boston MA Massachusetts 02111 ([email protected]) Eric A. Roth PhD, Department of Anthropology, University of Victoria, P.O. Box 3050, Victoria, British Columbia Presentation for “Pastoralism and Poverty Reduction in East Africa: A Policy Research Conference” International Livestock Research Institute, 27-28 June 2006, Nairobi Abstract The settling of formerly mobile pastoral populations is occurring rapidly throughout East Africa. Pastoral sedentarization has been encouraged by international development agencies and national governments to alleviate problems of food insecurity, health care delivery, and national integration. However, it has not been demonstrated that abandoning the pastoral way of life, and particularly access to livestock products, has been beneficial to the health and well-being of pastoral populations. This paper reports the results of a three-year study of pastoral and settled Rendille and Ariaal (mixed Samburu/Rendille) communities in Marsabit District northern Kenya, which compares levels of child malnutrition and illness between five different Rendille communities, ranging from purely pastoral to agricultural and urban communities. Analysis of bimonthly dietary recalls, anthropometric measurements, morbidity data, and economic differentiation and specialization among 202 mothers and their 488 children under age 9 reveals large differences in the growth patterns and morbidity of nomadic vs.
    [Show full text]
  • Exploring Exchange and Direct Procurement Strategies for Natufian
    www.nature.com/scientificreports OPEN Exploring exchange and direct procurement strategies for Natufan food processing tools of el‑Wad Terrace, Israel Danny Rosenberg1*, Tatjana M. Gluhak2, Daniel Kaufman3, Reuven Yeshurun3 & Mina Weinstein‑Evron3 We present the results of a detailed geochemical provenance study of 54 Natufan (ca. 15,000– 11,700 cal. BP) basalt pestles from the site of el‑Wad Terrace (EWT), Israel. It is the frst time precise locations from where basalt raw materials were derived are provided. The results indicate that the Natufan hunter‑gatherers used multiple sources of basaltic rocks, distributed over a large area surrounding the Sea of Galilee. This area is located at a considerable distance from EWT, ca. 60–120 km away, in a region where contemporaneous Natufan basecamps are few. We consider two possible models that suggest vehicles for the transportation of these artifacts to EWT, namely the exchange obtaining model (EOM) and the direct procurement model (DPM). We argue that these mechanisms are not mutually exclusive and may have operated together. We also suggest that at a time of increasing Natufan territoriality, a large area around the Sea of Galilee remained unclaimed. The paper concludes with a brief discussion of the implications for the two models. In particular, we note that the DPM implies that technological know‑how for pestle production was maintained within the EWT community. Te nascence of sedentism profoundly impacted human societies’ mobility patterns, requiring a host of adjust- ments. Among its immediate implications are economic intensifcation and preoccupation with production and territoriality, both within and across communities.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Polanyi and the New Economic Sociology: Notes on the Concept of (Dis)Embeddedness
    RCCS Annual Review A selection from the Portuguese journal Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais 3 | 2011 Issue no. 3 Karl Polanyi and the New Economic Sociology: Notes on the Concept of (Dis)embeddedness Nuno Miguel Cardoso Machado Translator: João Paulo Moreira Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/rccsar/309 DOI: 10.4000/rccsar.309 ISSN: 1647-3175 Publisher Centro de Estudos Sociais da Universidade de Coimbra Electronic reference Nuno Miguel Cardoso Machado, « Karl Polanyi and the New Economic Sociology: Notes on the Concept of (Dis)embeddedness », RCCS Annual Review [Online], 3 | 2011, Online since 01 October 2011, connection on 21 December 2020. URL : http://journals.openedition.org/rccsar/309 ; DOI : https:// doi.org/10.4000/rccsar.309 © CES RCCS Annual Review, 3, October 2011: 119-140 Nuno Miguel Cardoso Machado Research Centre in Economic and Organizational Sociology, School of Economics and Management (SOCIUs- ISEG), Technical University of Lisbon Karl Polanyi and the New Economic Sociology: Notes on the Concept of (Dis)embeddedness* Within the context of the New Economic Sociology, Karl Polanyi is almost universally osideed the fathe of the oept of eeddedess. However, this concept has been subject to selective appropriation by this discipline and its relationship to the remaining theoretical edifice constructed by Polanyi has been neglected. It is, in fact, possible to refer to the geat tasfoatio to hich the concept of embeddedness has been subjected: heeas i Polais ok it is assoiated ith the aoeooi leel ad is used as evidence of the exceptional nature of the capitalist market economy – disembedded from society – in NES, it is normally associated with the meso (and even micro) level, on the assumption that all economies – including capitalist economies – are embedded.
    [Show full text]
  • Copyrighted Material Not for Distribution
    Contents MATERIAL List of Figures vii List of Tables xi 1. Surplus: The Politics of ProductionDISTRIBUTION and the Strategies of Everyday and Life—An Introduction Christopher T. Morehart and Kristin De Lucia 3 FOR 2. The Cost ofCOPYRIGHTED Conquest: Assessing the Impact of Inka Tribute Demands on the Wanka of Highland Peru Cathy Lynne CostinNOT 45 3. Surplus and Social Change: The Production of Household and Field in Pre-Aztec Central Mexico Kristin De Lucia and Christopher T. Morehart 73 4. Surplus in the Indus Civilization: Agricultural Choices, Social Relations, Political Effects Heather M.-L. Miller 97 v vi Contents 5. Surplus from Below: Self-Organization of Production in Early Sweden T. L. Thurston 121 6. From Surplus Land to Surplus Production in the Viking Age Settlement of Iceland Douglas J. Bolender 153 7. Surplus Capture in Contrasting Modes of Religiosity: Perspectives from Sixteenth-Century Mesoamerica E. Christian Wells 175 8. Surplus Houses: Palace Politics in the Bight of Benin West Africa, AD 1650–1727 Neil L. Norman 203 9. Surplus Labor, Ceremonial Feasting, and Social Inequality at Cahokia: A Study MATERIALin Social Process James A. Brown and John E. Kelly 221 10. The Sociality of Surplus among Late Archaic Hunter-Gatherers of CoastalDISTRIBUTION Georgia Victor D. Thompson and Christopher R. Moore 245 11. The Transactional DynamicsFOR of Surplus in LandscapesCOPYRIGHTED of Enslavement: Scalar Perspectives from Interstitial West Africa Ann B. StahlNOT 267 12. Conclusions: Surplus and the Political Economy in Prehistory Timothy Earle 307 List of Contributors 327 Index 329 Figures 2.1. Inka empire MATERIAL 47 2.2.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Anthropology History, Ethnography, Critique
    Economic Anthropology History, Ethnography, Critique Chris Hann and Keith Hart polity Economic Anthropology also historians and sociologists (and many varieties under each of those labels) - must join forces. Some economists 1 claim a special status for their discipline and locate it closer to the 'hard' sciences than to 'soft' disciplines in the humanities. We take a critical and historical view of such claims, but it is Introduction: Economic not our intention to offer a romantic, utopian alternative to Anthropology economics. We are aware that economics is in some ways as diverse as anthropology. Our aim is to bring the two closer together and this makes us critical of mainstream positions on both sides. Previous accounts of economic anthropology linked it to the founding fathers of modern social theory - notably Marx, Weber and Durkheim. Occasionally the history was Anthropologists aim to discover the principles of · social traced back to the political economists of the Enlightenment. organization at every level from the most particular to the We argue that the core questions are much older than this. universal. The purpose of economic anthropology in the nine­ Ultimately, economic anthropology addresses questions of teenth century, even before it took shape as 'the economics of human nature and well-being, questions that have preoc­ primitive man', was to test the claim that a world economic cupied every society's philosophers from the beginning. We order must be founded on the principles that underpinned make a case for an economic anthropology that is able to a Western industrial society striving for universality. The investigate this 'human economy' anywhere in time and search was on for alternatives that might support a more just space, as a creation of all humanity.
    [Show full text]