Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Comparative Costs, Autarky General Equilibrium, Trade Patterns, Factor Endowments, Free Trade Balances, Terms of Trade Surfaces, International General Equilibrium Solutions and Factor Allocations. Bjarne S. Jensen and Jacopo Zotti University of Southern Denmark, Dept. of Environmental and Business Economics University of Trieste, Department of Political and Social Sciences Abstract This paper gives analytical parametric solutions for the basic, two-sector-two-factor-two- country, (2x2x2) model of international trade. Such analytical approach to the involved non-linear economic systems must start with the Cobb-Douglas specifications of sector technologies and consumer preferences. The closed-form expressions provide a unified framework for all traditional basic trade models. The solutions allow for international differences in country sizes, endowments, technology and preferences, encompassing the major "pure trade theories" within a systematic analytic and historical perspective. In this unified framework, we derive the general existence conditions for the solutions under diversification and incipient country specialization. Keywords: Trade models, general equilibrium, terms of trade JEL Classification: F11, F43, E21 1 1 Introduction The pure theory of international trade has always been involved with the fundamental questions of what decides : 1. The commodity pattern (composition) of international trade between countries, 2. The "international values", i.e., the prices of both the free traded commodities and their primary production factors, 3. The gains from foreign trade. Evidently the literature is overwhelming and hence many surveys have been made, Haberler (1936,1961), Mundell (1960), Bhagwati (1964), Chipman (1965-1966). The latter still surpasses all other historical accounts and expositions of theory evolution (to- gether with many references to contemporary authors/discussions). His theory chronology has three periods of main/early contributors : I. Classical theory of comparative advan- tage, gains from trade (Smith, Ricardo, Mill), II. Neo-Classical theory of international trade equilibrium and the equilibrium terms of trade (Marshall, Edgeworth, Haberler), III. Modern theory of factor endowments, factor price equalization, factor income distri- bution, two-sector growth models (Heckscher, Ohlin, Samuelson, Solow, Uzawa, Kemp). Economic laws (theory) governing trade between two countries dawned in Adam Smith - Chapter 11 of restraints upon the importation from foreign countries of goods that can be produced at home, Smith (1776, 1961, p.478): "What is prudence in the conduct of every private family, can scarcely be folly in that of a great kingdom. If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy [import] it from them with some part [export] of the produce of our own industry, employed [produced] in a way in which we have some advantage". By scrutinizing the principle of cheapness and advantage in more detail with some illustrations, Ricardo (1817, p.81, p.175), cf. Ruffin (2002, p.743), came up with the law of comparative advantage: "Under a system of perfectly free commerce, each country naturally devotes its capital and labour to such employments [industries, goods, sectors] as are most beneficial to each. This pursuit of individual advantages is admirably connected with the universal good of the whole." Precisely, the Ricardian term comparative advantage means the ability in autarky to produce a good at lower cost/price (relative to other goods), compared to another autarky country. Moreover, the law of comparative advantage (cost) says that a country exports 2 (imports) the good with the low (high) relative (p = P1=P2) autarky price, and it can be expressed an inequality in relative autarky prices : P1A=P2A = pA < P1B =P2B = pB : X1A > 0 (1) The prediction of trade patterns - X1A > 0 : export of good 1 by country A - in open economies by the autarky condition, (1), is (with precise assumptions) not violated in any trade model for : Two countries, two goods [commodities, sectors], two factors, (2x2x2). The world equilibrium terms of trade (p∗) are usually just taken (assumed, not proved) to fall strictly between the two countries relative prices (price ratios) under autarky, i.e., ∗ pA < p < pB (2) ∗ excluding the case of one country (say A) being 'small', hence p = pB . The bilateral rule of comparing relative prices under autarky to determine trade pat- terns, (1), is not valid for a multicommodity (multisector, i ≥ 3) world, as demonstrated by Drabicki and Takayama (1979, p.217). On these "higher dimensional" issues, see Deardorff (1980), Shimomura and Wong (1998). We focus on a full story of the (2x2x2) model, but in contrast to the available literature so far, our objective is to deduce and finally present explicit analytical solutions of the world trade model (2x2x2). While comparative advantage explains why and how trade takes place, it does not explain (give) the terms of trade : relative prices, p∗ in (2). Ricardo's numerical examples, cf. Chipman (1965, p.482), offer no clear size of (p∗) or hints to general answers. It was Stuart Mill, who first gave an analysis of the formation of "international values" [world market prices, determination of p∗ in (2)], that offered a rigorous answer - discussed in detail by Chipman (1965, p.485-86) - upon a pure trade theory example left by Ricardo. Stuart Mill (1875, p.352) stated: "When trade is established between two countries, the two commodities will exchange for each other at the same rate of interchange in both countries", i.e. the "law of one price" that will also be adhered to in our (2x2x2) model. Next Mill (1875, p.359) says: "All trade, either between nations or individuals, is an interchange of commodities, in which the things that they respectively have to sell, constitute also their means of purchase: the supply brought by the one constitutes his demand for what is brought by the other. So that supply and demand are but another 3 expression for reciprocal demand - or named the Equation of International Demand" - or today: the trade balance equation with a zero constraint - which is adopted here, too. To handle the special trade case of Ricardo, Mill assumed that consumers in both countries had identical commodity demand functions of simplest functional form, Mill (1875, p.361): "Let us therefore assume, that the influence of cheapness on demand conforms to some simple law, common to both countries and to both commodities. As the simplest possible and most convenient, let us suppose that in both countries any given increase of cheapness [fall in price] produces an proportional increase of consumption: or, in other words that value expended in the commodity, the cost incurred for the sake of obtaining it, is always the same, whether that cost [expenditure] affords a greater or smaller quantity of the commodity." In short, Mill used here consumer demand functions, generated today by Cobb-Douglas utility functions, as we will do for preferences below. Marshall (1879, 1974) continued the study of Mill's examples with an in-depth analysis of the trade balance equilibrium determination of "international values" (terms of trade) by "reciprocal demand" (offer, net-export) curves of two countries. Let us hear, Marshall (1879, 1974, p.1): "The function of pure theory and models is to deduce definite conclu- sions from definite hypothetical premises. The premises should approximate as closely as possible to the facts with which the corresponding applied theory has to deal. But the terms used in the pure theory must be cable of exact interpretation, and the hypotheses on which it is based must be simple and easily handled. The pure theory of foreign trade satisfies these conditions". Marshall supported his propositions/corollaries with 24 offer-curve diagrams; many now standard, cf. summary in Deardorff (2006, pp.322). While "classical" trade theory (Smith, Ricardo) may have assumed, cf. Chipman (1966, p.18), "constant factor prices and different technologies" among countries, Heckscher (1919, 1991, p.47) examined some : "fundamental assumptions concerning the reasons for differences in comparative costs among countries", i.e. why are in (1) the autarky relative costs (prices) pA and pB different ? As a keen economist, Heckscher correctly argued that countries with same - technologies and relative factor prices - do not trade; since then: "relative costs in one country cannot possibly differ from those in the other. Therefore trade between the countries will not arise", Heckscher (1991, p.47). 4 Hence behind the Ricardian inequality in (1), he saw (emphasized) as a prerequisite an inequality in autarky relative factor prices, !A and !B : ”different relative prices of the factors of production in the exchanging countries", Heckscher (1991, p.48). But next opening free trade would itself affect the relative factor prices and maybe, even under some conditions, bring about not just partial, but full factor price equalization (FPE). As to "modern factor endowment theory", Ohlin (1935, Appendix I) re-examined and extends the general equilibrium equation systems of Walras-Cassel for the mutual interde- pendence pricing of commodities and factors to trading regions (countries). He introduced and emphasized the role of different factor endowments ratios,(kA; kB ), among regions; but Ohlin (1933, p.561-62) opted in most situations for partial factor price equalization. Next Samuelson (1948, p.169) enters the discussion: `In attempting to
Recommended publications
  • The Generalized Theory of Distortions and Welfare
    LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/generalizedtheorOObhag 7 working paper department of economics THE GENERALIZED THEORY OF DISTORTIONS AND WELFARE Jagdish N. Bhagwatl Number 39 May 1969 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 THE GENERALIZED THEORY OF DISTORTIONS AND WELFARE by Jagdish N. Bhagwati Number 39 May 1969 The views expressed in this paper are the author's sole responsibility, and do not reflect those of the Department of Economics, nor of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. : The Generalized Theory of Distortions and Welfare The theory of trade and welfare has recently developed independently in seven areas which have apparently little analytical relationship among themselves (a) Sub-Optimality of Laissez-faire Under Market Imperfections : It has been shown that, when market imperfections exist, laissez-faire (other- wise described as "a policy of unified exchange rates" [5]) will not be the optimal policy. Among the market imperfections for which the sub-optimality of laissez-faire has been demonstrated are four key types: (i) factor mar- 2 ket imperfection: a wage differential between sectors; (ii) product mar- 3 ket imperfection: a production externality; (iii) consumption imperfection: This paper is the result of thinking and research over a period of many years, originating in my 1958 paper on immiserizing growth [1] and developing considerably since my joint paper with Ramaswami in 1963 [2] on domestic distortions. Since 1965, T. N. Srinivasan and I have col- laborated on research in related matters, pertaining to the theory of optimal policy intervention when non-economic objectives are present [7]: a sub- ject pioneered by Max Corden's brilliant work [12].
    [Show full text]
  • The Fallacies of Distributism
    NOVEMBER 2003 The Fallacies of Distributism by Thomas E. Woods, Jr. n certain disaffected pockets of the politi- A family possessed of the means of pro- cal left and right, more and more voices duction—the simplest form of which is can be heard on behalf of an economic and the possession of land and of the imple- Isocial system known as distributism. ments and capital for working the land— According to the celebrated Catholic writers cannot be controlled by others. Of course, G. K. Chesterton and Hilaire Belloc, who various producers specialize, and through popularized the idea in the early twentieth exchange one with the other they become century, that social system is best in which more or less interdependent, but still, “productive property” is widely dispersed each one can live “on his own”: each one rather than concentrated. They contend that can stand out, if necessary, from pressure the market order undermines community life exercised against him by another. He can and introduces an intolerable level of insecu- say: “If you will not take my surplus as rity and anxiety into the economic life of the against your surplus I shall be the poorer; ordinary person. They would, therefore, but at least I can live.”1 limit business competition and implement a system of punitive taxation against firms For Belloc, then, the great advantage of dis- that had attained what these writers consid- tributism is that it gives the household a sig- ered excessive economic concentration. nificant measure of independence. A new I do not for a moment doubt the good will introduction to his Essay on the Restoration and pure intentions of those who support of Property describes his view of “economic distributism, and indeed I count some of freedom” as something that “comes from the them among my friends.
    [Show full text]
  • Market, Transition and Developing Economies 1
    When Does Trade Hurt? Market, Transition and Developing Economies 1 Kala Krishna Pennsylvania State University and NBER Cemile Yavas Pennsylvania State University September, 2002 1 We are grateful to Don Davis, Elhanan Helpman, Abhijit Banerjee, Jim Anderson, and participants at the 2001 ITI Summer Institute at the NBER, the Fall 2001 Midwest Trade Conference, the IEFS session at the ASSA in 2002, and the ETSG meetings in 2002 for comments. Abstract This paper argues that labor market distortions present in transition and devel- oping economies coupled with indivisibilities in consumption may help explain the resistance to globalization prevalent in many of these economies. We assume that workers differ in ability. In a market economy their earnings depend on their ability. However, earnings are independent of ability due to a common wage set in manufacturing in a transition economy and because of family farms in a developing economy. Trade can have significant adverse effects in this setting. When the economy is productive enough, a high income autarky equilibrium can be sustained in a distorted economy through a high income, high demand, high income virtuous circle. However, the distortion tends to make trade operate in a way that destroys this. Our work suggests that trade liberalization without structural reform can have serious adverse effects in transition and developing economies: there can even be mutual losses from trade. 1Introduction This paper argues that labor market distortions (LMDs) present in transition and developing economies may help explain the resistance to globalization that is prevalent in many of these economies. For example, it is often argued that trade had significant adverse effects in transition economies, in particular, on the ability of workers to afford highly valued but inherently lumpy consumer durables.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tragedy of the Locals
    Research Paper 41 | 2016 ENERGY, TRADE, AND INNOVATION: THE TRAGEDY OF THE LOCALS Chiara RAVETTI, Tania THEODULOZ, Giulia VALACCHI ENERGY,TRADE AND INNOVATION: THE TRAGEDY OF THE LOCALS∗ Chiara Ravettiy Tania Theoduloz z Giulia Valacchix January 20, 2016 Abstract This paper analyses the use of different energy sources in a dynamic trade model with endoge- nous innovation. We consider two countries, North and South, the first with high environmental concerns and the second endowed with abundant fossil fuel resources. In this asymmetric setting, the South specializes in energy production using fossil fuels, causing local and global environmental damages. The North, instead, specializes in other manufacturing and imports energy inputs from the South. Endogenous innovation reinforces this pattern of specialization over time. We show that the North can unilaterally stop the use of fossil fuels and avoid a global climate disaster with two dif- ferent strategies: either redirecting the comparative advantage of the South towards manufacturing, relocating the production of energy to the North, or buying fossil fuel deposits in the South. These two policies have different implications in terms of monetary costs and environmental outcomes for the North. The choice between the two depends on the valuation of the environment, the energy requirements of final goods’ production, the starting time of the policy and the time preferences of the North. Overall, however, there is no costless way for the North to stop unilaterally the use of fossil fuels. Keywords: Energy, technical change, international trade, comparative advantage, fossil fuels JEL Classification: F18, O32, O38 ∗The research leading to these results was funded by the Swiss National Science Foundation under the Swiss South African Joint Research Programme (SSAJRP).
    [Show full text]
  • Political Mobilization and the Institutional Origins of National Developmentalist States: the Cases of Turkey, Mexico, Argentina, and Egypt
    Political Mobilization and the Institutional Origins of National Developmentalist States: the Cases of Turkey, Mexico, Argentina, and Egypt A Dissertation Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Cornell University In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy by Berk Esen January 2015 © 2015 Berk Esen Political Mobilization and the Institutional Origins of National Developmentalist States: the Cases of Turkey, Mexico, Argentina, and Egypt Berk Esen, Ph.D. Cornell University 2015 My dissertation examines why the common challenge of late development has generated starkly different responses in the Global South. I focus in particular on a cluster of cases that reacted to trade imbalances and political turmoil at the international stage with a combined agenda of economic nationalism, social progress and state-led industrialization, establishing what I term national developmentalist states. Why then, despite facing similar adaptive pressures, did these regimes markedly differ in terms of their durability and socio-economic policies? Through a careful study of such regimes in Turkey, Mexico, Argentina and Egypt during the middle third of the twentieth century, the dissertation specifies four variants of the national-developmentalist state and articulates how each type produced a distinct policy set with varying redistributive implications and political outcomes. I argue that where leaders invested heavily in building cohesive ruling-party and/or state organizations, regimes proved durable even with only moderate levels of economic redistribution. Where such institutions were weak, leaders could expand their popularity through excessive redistribution and risk elite polarization or establish a limited base but remain vulnerable to elite defections and popular opposition.
    [Show full text]
  • American Capitalism
    AC/No.7/June 2017 American Capitalism PURSUING PROSPERITY, 1953-1961 Louis Galambos Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and Study of Business Enterprise Pursuing Prosperity, 1953-1961 By Louis Galambos Co-Director, Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise, The Johns Hopkins University About the Series The American Capitalism series is under the general direction of Prof. Steve H. Hanke, Co-Director of The Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise ([email protected]). About the Author Louis Galambos is a Research Professor of History; Editor of The Papers of Dwight David Eisenhower; and a Co-Director of the Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise at The Johns Hopkins University. His major interest in recent years has been innovation and, in particular, the interactions between individuals and organizations in the private, public, and nonprofit sectors that foster entrepreneurship in America. 237 This chapter is from Louis Galambos’ Eisenhower: Leadership, Identity, and the Middle Way, forthcoming at the Johns Hopkins University Press. CHAPTER TEN PURSUING PROSPERITY, 1953-1961 In January 1953, Dwight Eisenhower became the leader of an American economy that faced three major challenges. One stemmed from a postwar settlement that had laid the foundation for a second globalization of the world economy. The first, British-led globalization of the late nineteenth century had been destroyed long ago by the First World War and the retreat in the 1920s and 1930s to nationalism, then to autarky, and finally to war again.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Crisis of Autarky in Spain, 1939-1959
    05-barciela_173_200_05-barciela_173_200 30/06/16 11:25 Pagina 175 The Disasters of Leviathan: The Economic Crisis of Autarky in Spain, 1939-1959 Carlos Barciela University of Alicante ABSTRACT This article reflects on the causes of the acute crisis suffered by Spain during the decades following the victory of General Franco in the Civil War. It emphasises the incoherence of the totalitarian eco- nomic model that was imposed, particularly with respect to the ob- jective of autarky. It also highlights the insufficient economic training of the bureaucrats and the active role of military commanders in the design of economic policy, including General Franco, who lacked any sort of economic or historical knowledge. Je sais qu’il importe que les hommes élevés en pouvoir soient plus éclairés que les autres; je sais que les fautes des particuliers ne peuvent jamais ruiner qu’un petit nombre de familles, tandis que celles des princes et des ministres répandent la désolation sur tout un pays. Jean-Baptiste Say1 1. Introduction It is common knowledge that Leviathan is a monster that ap- pears in different passages of the Bible. Leviathan was also used by the English political philosopher, Thomas Hobbes, as the title of the book in which he describes what he conceived to be the pro- per structure of the State, which although not absolutist, should 1 Say, Traité d’économie politique, p. 35. 175 05-barciela_173_200_05-barciela_173_200 30/06/16 11:25 Pagina 176 CARLOS BARCIELA have a very great deal of authority. Almost in the same period in which John Locke was advocating the need for a limited, democratic state with division of powers, Hobbes defended the existence of a strong state as a way to overcome the fratricidal tendencies of human beings, summed up in the famous phrase: “man is a wolf to man”.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case of International Trade Roger Guesnerie
    WORKING PAPER N° Mots clés : Codes JEL : Second Best redistributive policies: the case of international trade Roger Guesnerie December 2000 Abstract The paper presents a brief review of recent work that focuses on the normative economics of international trade. In an Heckscher Ohlin - like economy, with skilled and unskilled workers, the available redistributive tools, (that include income taxation) are not powerful enough to allow the separation of efficiency and equity issues and ”production efficiency” is no longer desirable. At a social optimum that calls for redistribution towards the unskilled workers, the social value of the unskilled intensive good is necessarily smaller than its production price. This finding allows to unify existing results and suggests conjectures. Résumé : Ce document présente une revue de travaux récents qui portent sur l’économie normative du commerce international. Dans une économie à la Heckscher-Ohlin, avec du travail qualifiéetdutravailnonqualifié, les outils disponibles pour la redistribution, (qui incluent un impôt non linéaire sur le revenu) ne sont pas assez puissants pour permettre une certaine sèparation des considérations d’équité et d’efficacité et ”l’efficacité de la production” n’est plus souhaitable. A un optimum social, qui appelle de la redistribution vers les travailleurs non qualifiés, la valeur sociale du bien intensif en travail non qualifié est nécessairement plus petite que son prix de production. Cette propriété de l’optimum permet d’unifier des résultats existants et suggère des conjectures. 1. Introduction. This paper provides a brief presentation of recent research Naito (1996), (1998), Gabaix (1997a) (1997b), Guesnerie (1998) (see also Spector(1999),...,) that focuses on the normative economics of international trade, and in particular, on how both the efficiency and redistributional dimensions should properly be taken into account.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Nationalist' Economic Policy John E. Richardson
    The National Front, and the search for a ‘nationalist’ economic policy John E. Richardson (forthcoming 2017) To be included in Copsey, N. & Worley, M. (eds) 'Tomorrow Belongs to Us': The British Far- Right Since 1967 Summarizing the economic policies of the National Front (NF) is a little problematic. Compared to their copious discussion of race and nation, of immigration, culture, history and even the environment, British fascists since WWII have had little to say, in detail, on their political-economic ideology. In one of the first content analytic studies of the NF’s mouthpiece Spearhead, for example, Harris (1973) identified five themes which dominated the magazine’s all pervasive conspiracy thinking: authoritarianism, ethnocentrism, racism, biological naturalism and anti-intellectualism. The economy was barely discussed, other than in the context of imagined generosity of the welfare state. The topic is so under-developed that even Rees’ (1979) encyclopaedic bibliography on British fascism, covering over 800 publications on and by fascists (between 1923-1977) doesn’t include a section on political economy. Frequently, the closest fascists get to outlining their political-economic ideology is to identify ‘the problem’: the forces of ‘cosmopolitan internationalism’ (that is: the Jews) importing migrants, whose cheap labour threatens white livelihoods, and whose physical presence threatens the racial purity of the nation. ‘The solution’, on the other hand, is far less frequently spelled out. In essence, fascist parties, like the NF, are comparatively clear about what political economies they oppose – international capitalism and international communism – but are far less clear or consistent about the political economy they support.
    [Show full text]
  • Soviet Economic Impact on Czechoslovakia and Romania in the Early Postwar Period: 1944 - 1956
    SOVIET ECONOMIC IMPACT ON CZECHOSLOVAKIA AND ROMANIA IN THE EARLY POSTWAR PERIOD: 1944 - 1956 Tamas R~ti This paper examines the conditions under which the so­ called Soviet model of industrialization was introduced into East Central Europe. While it is difficult to define direct Soviet economic policy, one can discern the Soviet interest and its direct economic impact by analyzing Czechoslovakia and Romania in terms of both their internal development and their relations with .the Soviet Union. No doubt, the primacy of politics is the main component of the Soviet relationship to East Central Europe; this paper, however, will focus on the economic side of that relationship. Although these countries fOlJowed the Sovi~t development -,strategy of the 1930s -- rapid extensive growth of heavy industry through central planning -- it is important to recognize the distinctive features of each country's pattern. Though it is widely accePted that significant national differences exist in the 1980s, their emergence from the 1940s and 1950s is much less well-known, let alone the fact that these differences were strengthened by various Soviet policies. Let us turn to the cases of Czechoslovakia and Romania. In the interwar period there were already important social and economic dissimiliarities between the two countries. The question then is: Could the Stalinist "melting pot" actually eliminate these distinctive features? To begin with, Romania's population was overwhelmingly rural and its level of development was closer to the USSR's than was Czechoslovakia's.' Almost two thirds of Romania's agriculttrral properties remained smaller than the viable size of three hectares, despite an extensive land reform completed after World War I.
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 3: the Ricardian (Classical) Trade Model
    Topic 3: the Ricardian (Classical) trade model Ricardian model: introduction This will be our first theoretical model that explains our basic questions: What do countries trade? (comparative advantage) What are the gains from trade (GFT)? Do both (all) countries GFT? Before starting the model, let’s consider three (false) common propositions you may hear about international trade. The first two: (1) “Wealthy, high-wage countries cannot afford to trade with low-wage developing countries because their low wage costs would allow them to produce most goods more cheaply and drive firms in richer countries out of business.” We need protection from low-wage imports to avoid seeing our wages brought down to their level. (2) “Low-wage developing countries cannot afford to trade with high-wage countries because labor in those countries is so much more productive because of skills, capital, and technological superiority that they would produce most goods more cheaply and drive LDC firms out of business.” Ricardian model: introduction Which is it? They can’t both be true, even though both are commonly heard in the media and policy circles. The fallacy with both is that they look at only one component of production costs: wages on the one hand and productivity on the other. But productivity and wages (also exchange rates, capital costs, and many other factors) combine to determine unit costs. The US can trade with Mexico or Vietnam to our mutual advantage, because we’re much better at producing some goods (better enough to pay for the high wages) and only a little better at others, so low wages matter there.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainable Energy Autarky and the Evolution of German Bioenergy Villages
    sustainability Article Sustainable Energy Autarky and the Evolution of German Bioenergy Villages Dariusz Pie ´nkowski 1,* and Wojciech Zbaraszewski 2 1 Faculty of Economics and Social Sciences, Department of Social Sciences and Pedagogy, Pozna´nUniversity of Life Sciences, ul. Wojska Polskiego 28, 60-637 Pozna´n,Poland 2 Faculty of Economics, Department of System Analysis and Marketing, West Pomeranian University of Technology in Szczecin, ul. Janickiego 31, 71-270 Szczecin, Poland; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Received: 30 July 2019; Accepted: 6 September 2019; Published: 12 September 2019 Abstract: The concept of an autarky has a long history and meaning related to its negation and unpopularity. In liberal schools of economics, autarky is usually considered from the perspectives of economic trade protectionism, closed economies, and threats to welfare. Nevertheless, the concept of autarky has gained a new meaning, understood as the local utilization of renewable energy resources from the perspective of their inter- and intragenerational distribution. Local action is shaped by the global perspective. This research consists of three steps. First, a model of energy autarky has been offered based on the system theory. The model shows the variety of the structures and features of energy systems offered in today’s debates on energy autarky. Second, the key postulates of sustainable development have been presented to define an autarkical sustainable energy system. Finally, the concept of bioenergy villages in Germany has been presented to illustrate the approach to energy autarky. The research shows that the concept of autarky and single solutions, such as the use of renewable resources, are not themselves a success from the perspective of sustainable development; this misunderstanding is well illustrated by the evolution of the German concept of bioenergy villages into smart villages.
    [Show full text]