Loss Aversion Down to Earth — a Comment on Gal & Rucker's

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Load more

Bringing (Contingent) Loss Aversion Down to Earth — A Comment on Gal & Rucker’s Rejection of “Losses Loom Larger Than Gains” Itamar Simonson Ran Kivetz Stanford University Columbia University Accepted by Sharon Shavitt, Associate Editor Although we disagree with some of Gal and Rucker’s (2018 – this issue) specific evidence and with their over- stated conclusion regarding loss aversion, their overarching message makes a worthwhile contribution. In par- ticular, loss aversion is less robust and universal than has been assumed while its most prominent empirical support — the endowment effect and the status quo bias — is susceptible to multiple alternative explanations. Instead of accepting loss aversion as true unless proven otherwise, we should treat it like other decision prop- erties and psychological accounts that are contingent on various moderators and call for an analysis of psy- chological mechanisms. In this commentary, we suggest that gatekeepers, such as reviewers, tend to favor loss aversion and other widely accepted tendencies, while demanding a much higher support-threshold for alternative or newer accounts. Although building on prior theories and concepts is of course important, the bias in favor of incumbent assumptions can impede scientific progress, bar new ideas from the literature, and reinforce well-established but contingent notions that may apply under some conditions but not others. Keywords Behavioral economics; Loss aversion; Judgment; Decision making; Behavioral decision theory; Contingent judgment properties Introduction: the Limitations of the Extant particular, as discussed further below, G&R’s Empirical Support for Loss Aversion claimed support for an endowment effect without loss aversion (using what is referred to as the “re- After reading David Gal and Derek Rucker’s target tention paradigm”) is itself open to rival accounts. article (2018 – this issue), we were skeptical, in More importantly, G&R unconvincingly and super- large part because like most scholars in our field ficially try to explain away the strongest illustration we have accepted loss aversion as unquestionably of loss aversion, namely, the typical extreme risk true and robust as any decision-making property aversion exhibited in choices between a certain gain can be. We still believe that the loss aversion ten- and a mixed, high expected-value gamble. dency plays an important role in many decisions, Further, some of the evidence proffered by G&R but we agree that loss aversion is not omnipresent appears to actually support loss aversion; for exam- or universal, and when relied upon, should be sub- ple, G&R cite their own finding that people enjoy ject to tests like other plausible accounts. Gal and gaining things that are lost (e.g., finding a lost Rucker (G&R) also correctly point out (see their flashlight) more than they enjoy gaining new things table 1) that loss aversion has received “credit” (Gal & Rucker, 2017), which suggests that losses do (although not from Kahneman and Tversky) for loom larger than gains. Still, consistent with G&R’s phenomena to which it does not apply; for exam- general message, treating loss aversion as another ple, framing effects, such as the well-known Asian mortal generalization that requires psychological Disease problem, represent a reflection effect rather analysis and, like other psychological generaliza- than loss aversion. Having said that, we do not find tions, is contingent and is sometimes violated offers persuasive some of the specific evidence that Gal progress and can bring down to earth what has and Rucker rely on to reach their conclusion that been treated as almost an axiomatic, unquestionable losses generally do not loom larger than gains. In (decision making) law of nature. As an aside, Gal and Rucker’s “strong version” of loss aversion is a Received 20 March 2018; accepted 20 March 2018 Available online 30 March 2018 Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to Itamar Simonson, Graduate School of Business, Stanford Univer- © 2018 Society for Consumer Psychology sity, 655 Knight Center, 94305 Stanford, CA, USA. Electronic All rights reserved. 1057-7408/2018/1532-7663 mail may be sent to [email protected] DOI: 10.1002/jcpy.1046 2 Simonson and Kivetz rhetorical strawman: we are unaware of any empir- not prove that some decision phenomenon is univer- ical phenomenon in the social sciences that always sal, and the observation of seemingly similar JDM holds, and presenting it as a viable option may cre- and choice phenomena among other species (Shafir, ate the wrong impression that the “weaker version” Waite, & Smith, 2002; Wong & Jennions, 2003) is they advocate represents a compromise view. open to various interpretations. Tversky and Kahneman (1991, p. 1047) described As G&R point out, we do not know much about the impact of loss aversion succinctly without elabo- the psychological mechanisms underlying loss aver- rating on the underlying psychology: “The basic sion, which may be due in part to the perceived intuition concerning loss aversion is that losses (out- status of loss aversion as unquestionably true. As comes below the reference state) loom larger than detailed below, we agree with G&R that loss aver- corresponding gains (outcomes above the reference sion needs to be treated like other empirical gener- state).” The evidence presented in that 1991 article alizations and studied like other contingent revolves primarily around manifestations of the phenomena that are sometimes violated. endowment effect and the status quo bias, although Thus, consistent with a key implication of the other demonstrations of loss aversion are also pre- G&R discussion, the question relevant at the pre- sented. As G&R and other researchers have pointed sent time for our field is not whether loss aversion out, both the endowment effect and the status quo occurs on average (we think it does), but what fac- bias have additional viable explanations, which tors moderate its presence and magnitude, and make these phenomena less than ideal as the flagship relatedly, what are its boundaries? There are many sources of evidence for loss aversion. Furthermore, other tendencies, perhaps not as sweeping, that as they point out, the status quo bias and the endow- may apply more often than not but have been trea- ment effect are violated under certain conditions. ted all along as contingent and as calling for speci- Beyond the endowment effect and the status quo fic psychological explanations. Thus, conformity, bias, there is certainly additional evidence for loss the desire for fairness, preference for compromises aversion (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979); for example, and asymmetrically dominating options, variety the tendency of most people to reject a gamble seeking, and the desire for others’ approval are all involving a 50% chance to win $200 and a 50% observed in many cases, yet questions about their chance to lose $100 is less open to rival accounts. psychological mechanisms, applicability, modera- Unlike G&R, we do not find persuasive their inter- tors, and boundaries came to the fore as soon as pretation of such choices in terms of the status quo they were introduced. bias, which hinges on the presumption that not Conformity, for example, is not a surprising phe- accepting the bet is the status quo option; this nomenon, is perhaps overly intuitive, and it lacks assumption appears ad hoc and is unsupported. But the mystique of loss aversion. Indeed, Asch’s various loss aversion findings do appear contingent famous experiments (and other studies) notwith- and are sometimes violated, as discussed below, standing, known violations of conformity (e.g., which reinforce the need to treat loss aversion as a need for uniqueness) have probably stimulated normal tendency that is sometimes violated and call more research than supportive findings did. Loss for greater attention to moderators, boundary condi- aversion, on the other hand, was quickly accepted tions, and psychological mechanisms. as true and as a major contribution of prospect the- Loss aversion has had, and continues to have, a ory, and it has therefore become the default account special status among the insights offered by the judg- for phenomena that might also be explained by ment and decision making (JDM) field, better known other mechanisms. For example, we agree with today as behavioral economics. In fact, loss aversion G&R that the phenomena that are the primary has been elevated to something akin to a law of nat- sources of support for loss aversion — the endow- ure that might be hard-wired from birth and may ment effect and status quo bias — have additional hold also for some other species. It represents a fun- viable explanations (although loss aversion is prob- damental and all-encompassing driver of judgments ably one contributor). and decisions — the weight of losses compared to gains. Monkeys show loss aversion (Chen, Lakshmi- narayanan, & Santos, 2006), and fMRI studies can Rival Accounts for the Endowment Effect find evidence from brain activity that has been inter- preted as consistent with the presence of loss aver- As indicated, the endowment effect has arguably sion (Tom, Fox, Trepel, & Poldrack, 2007). It is been the most prominent illustration of the conse- noteworthy that “monkey-evidence” by itself does quences of loss aversion. For example, Kahneman, Bringing (Contingent) Loss Aversion Down to Earth 3 Knetsch, and Thaler (1991, p. 197) concluded: “This to isolate the impact of loss aversion. For example, suggests that the main effect of endowment is not is the pain associated with giving up something we to enhance the appeal of the good one owns, only thought we owned a reflection of loss aversion, of the pain of giving it up.” Kahneman et al. (1991) something else, or of some combination of factors? went on to attribute the status quo bias and other The challenge of isolating the impact of loss aver- phenomena to loss aversion: “These observations, sion is certainly a weakness of the loss aversion and many others, can be explained by a notion of explanation.
Recommended publications
  • Education and Behavioural Failures

    Education and Behavioural Failures

    Proceedings of ADVED 2017- 3rd International Conference on Advances in Education and Social Sciences 9-11 October 2017- Istanbul, Turkey EDUCATION AND BEHAVIOURAL FAILURES Venelin Terziev1*, Dimitar Kanev2 1Corresponding Member of the Russian Academy of Natural History, Moscow, Professor, Ph.D., D.Sc. (National Security), D.Sc. (Ec.), University of Rousse, Rousse, Bulgaria; National Military University, Veliko Tarnovo, Bulgaria; University of Telecommunications and Post, Sofia, Bulgaria, [email protected] 2Professor, Ph.D., D.Sc. (Ec.), Naval Academy, Varna, Bulgaria, [email protected] *Corresponding author Abstract The work defences the thesis that even ensured equal opportunities to invest in education and to get better life, even if this is the best life alternative for them, young people and their families would hardly take complete advantage of these opportunities. This particularly regards the ones in an unequal position. The reasons are looked for in behavioural failures connected to hyperbolic discounting and to focusing on the present, momentum, stereotypes, herd-instinct behaviour, the paralysis at the availability of numerous options and defects of will. The work also suggests solutions, which to help young people and their families to take adequate advantage of educational opportunities and to develop their potential, getting over or softening behavioural deformations and deviations from reality. Keywords: education, limited rationality, lack of foresight, momentum, herd-instinct behaviour 1. INTRODUCTION Target of the present work is education, and subject – behavioural failures in education decisions. What we make our aim is to study the behavioural deformations impact upon the effectiveness of individual decisions for education. We use the behavioural economy’s theoretical approach and verify the thesis that together with ensuring access to quality education, young people and their families are to be helped to take adequate advantage of that access, particularly those occupying low social-economic status.
  • Testing the Endowment Effect in Law

    Testing the Endowment Effect in Law

    DePaul Law Review Volume 68 Issue 1 Fall 2018 Article 3 Bridging the Property-Contract Divide: Testing the Endowment Effect in Law Marco Jimenez Follow this and additional works at: https://via.library.depaul.edu/law-review Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Marco Jimenez, Bridging the Property-Contract Divide: Testing the Endowment Effect in Law, 68 DePaul L. Rev. (2019) Available at: https://via.library.depaul.edu/law-review/vol68/iss1/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Law at Via Sapientiae. It has been accepted for inclusion in DePaul Law Review by an authorized editor of Via Sapientiae. For more information, please contact [email protected]. \\jciprod01\productn\D\DPL\68-1\DPL103.txt unknown Seq: 1 7-JAN-19 10:03 BRIDGING THE PROPERTY-CONTRACT DIVIDE: TESTING THE ENDOWMENT EFFECT IN CONTRACT LAW Marco Jimenez* CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................................. 31 R I. THE ENDOWMENT EFFECT .............................. 35 R A. General Overview of the Endowment Effect......... 35 R B. Previous Experiments Testing the Endowment Effect ............................................... 38 R C. Contract Law and the Endowment Effect ........... 40 R II. TESTING THE ENDOWMENT EFFECT IN CONTRACT LAW ..................................................... 40 R A. Establishing Initial Preferences ...................... 40 R B. Registering the Strength of Initial Preferences ....... 42 R C. Distributing and Tracking Contracts ................ 44 R D. Trading Exercise .................................... 46 R E. Predicting the Number of Trades Absent an Endowment Effect .................................. 47 R III. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION .............................. 49 R A. Quantitative Evidence for the Presence of the Endowment Effect .................................. 49 R B. Quantitative Evidence for the Strength of the Endowment Effect .................................
  • Todd Zywicki1 George Mason University Foundation Professor of Law Antonin Scalia School of Law at George Mason University Senior Scholar, Cato Institute

    Todd Zywicki1 George Mason University Foundation Professor of Law Antonin Scalia School of Law at George Mason University Senior Scholar, Cato Institute

    STATEMENT PREPARED FOR CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU ABUSIVE ACTS OR PRACTICES SYMPOSIUM June 25, 2019 Todd Zywicki1 George Mason University Foundation Professor of Law Antonin Scalia School of Law at George Mason University Senior Scholar, Cato Institute 1 I would like to thank Karin Thrasher for her research assistance in preparation of this statement. 1 Enacted in response to the 2008 financial crisis, the Dodd-Frank regulatory reform law was one of the most consequential pieces of financial regulatory reform legislation since the Great Depression. Among its myriad provisions was the creation of the Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (“CFPB”). Among the CFPB’s substantive powers is to ensure that “consumers are protected from unfair, deceptive, or abusive acts and practices.” The terms “unfair” and “deceptive” are well-established terms that despite their apparent vagueness have come to take on relatively predictable and determinate meaning over time. “Abusiveness,” however, is a novel term with limited predecessors. The CFPB, scholars, and commenters have struggled to define the term “abusive” in a manner that effectuates Congress’s language and intent in a predictable and consumer welfare-enhancing manner. During the tenure of Director Richard Cordray, the CFPB eschewed any settled or precise definition of the term but instead adopted a policy of defining the term on a case-by-case enforcement process. Still, the CFPB has struggled to define the term “abusive” so as to distinguish it from “unfair” and “deceptive” acts and practices. In light of the substantial penalties that the CFPB is entitled to mete out, the lack of a predictable definition of the term “abusive” has given rise to great consternation by regulated entities about basic due process rights and their ability to engage in useful transactions with their customers.
  • The Endowment Effect: Unique Predictions from a Cognitive

    The Endowment Effect: Unique Predictions from a Cognitive

    ASSOCIATION FOR CONSUMER RESEARCH Labovitz School of Business & Economics, University of Minnesota Duluth, 11 E. Superior Street, Suite 210, Duluth, MN 55802 The Endowment Effect: Unique Predictions From a Cognitive Elaboration Account Christopher Cannon, University of Hawaii, USA Derek Rucker, Northwestern University, USA David Gal, University of Illinois at Chicago, USA The endowment effect is a widely documented phenomenon whereby sellers demand a higher price for the same good relative to buyers. This work proposes a novel account for the endowment effect based on cognitive elaboration. This cognitive elaboration account provides new predictions about when endowment increases versus decreases consumers’ evaluations. [to cite]: Christopher Cannon, Derek Rucker, and David Gal (2020) ,"The Endowment Effect: Unique Predictions From a Cognitive Elaboration Account", in NA - Advances in Consumer Research Volume 48, eds. Jennifer Argo, Tina M. Lowrey, and Hope Jensen Schau, Duluth, MN : Association for Consumer Research, Pages: 254-255. [url]: http://www.acrwebsite.org/volumes/2656006/volumes/v48/NA-48 [copyright notice]: This work is copyrighted by The Association for Consumer Research. For permission to copy or use this work in whole or in part, please contact the Copyright Clearance Center at http://www.copyright.com/. The Endowment Effect: Unique Predictions from a Cognitive Elaboration Account Christopher Cannon, University of Hawaii, USA Derek D. Rucker, Northwestern University, USA David Gal, University of Illinois at Chicago, USA EXTENDED ABSTRACT each experiment, we aimed to collect 300 participants to ensure a The endowment effect is a phenomenon in which sellers have sufficiently large cell sizes. For the endowment conditions, buyers a higher valuation of their goods than buyers (Kahneman, Knetsch, were asked to imagine that they are thinking about purchasing the and Thaler 1990, 1991).
  • Zicklin School of Business Baruch College, CUNY MKT 88800

    Zicklin School of Business Baruch College, CUNY MKT 88800

    Zicklin School of Business Baruch College, CUNY MKT 88800: Consumer Behavior and Behavioral Decision Theory Professor Stephen Gould: Fall 2019 This course aims to develop your knowledge and research skills by considering a number of different perspectives and focusing them on consumer behavior and decision making. We start with readings on selected topics each week and enrich our understanding through experiential exercises, thought experiments and research proposals. This comprehensive approach reflects a mapping of research which might best be considered as locating points in researcher consciousness, whether or not you follow up in any particular domain mentioned here. It thus is designed to help you think out of the box, whether you want to take a huge leap of the imagination or more generally extend the work of some relevant topic you are interested in. It is impossible to read or even consider all important papers or topics. I have made a subjective selection based on what I see at the moment. There is some flexibility and if any of you have any thoughts about some topic to consider let me know. Learning Objectives 1. Students should be able as a result of this course to theorize about, design and run studies applying BDT. 2. All students whether they directly focus on BDT in their own research programs or not should be able to apply the theoretical and experimental design insights from this field to their own investigations of consumer behavior and other related disciplines. In that respect, they will come away with a deeper appreciation of decision making in terms of such central aspects as (1) conscious versus non-conscious effects, (2) intuitive versus counterintuitive findings and (3) how various BDT theories such as Prospect Theory and others are continually evolving, contesting and challenging more conventional economic and consumer research perspectives.
  • The Loss of Loss Aversion: Will It Loom Larger Than Its Gain?

    The Loss of Loss Aversion: Will It Loom Larger Than Its Gain?

    The Loss of Loss Aversion: Will It Loom Larger Than Its Gain? David Gal Derek D. Rucker University of Illinois at Chicago Northwestern University Accepted by Sharon Shavitt, Associate Editor Loss aversion, the principle that losses loom larger than gains, is among the most widely accepted ideas in the social sciences. The first part of this article introduces and discusses the construct of loss aversion. The sec- ond part of this article reviews evidence in support of loss aversion. The upshot of this review is that current evidence does not support that losses, on balance, tend to be any more impactful than gains. The third part of this article aims to address the question of why acceptance of loss aversion as a general principle remains per- vasive and persistent among social scientists, including consumer psychologists, despite evidence to the con- trary. This analysis aims to connect the persistence of a belief in loss aversion to more general ideas about belief acceptance and persistence in science. The final part of the article discusses how a more contextualized perspective of the relative impact of losses versus gains can open new areas of inquiry that are squarely in the domain of consumer psychology. Keywords Loss aversion; Sociology of science One of us polled approximately 80 people present we have encountered near unanimous support for for a conference session on consumer decision mak- the premise that losses loom larger than gains. ing at the 2016 Society for Judgment and Decision Although anecdotal, we view these examples as Making Conference in Boston. The question posed illustrations of the near universal acceptance among was simple: Which of the following do you believe? social scientists of loss aversion—the idea that losses loom larger than equivalent magnitude gains.
  • Gains, Losses, and Judges: Framing and the Judiciary Jeffrey J

    Gains, Losses, and Judges: Framing and the Judiciary Jeffrey J

    Notre Dame Law Review Volume 94 | Issue 2 Article 2 1-2019 Gains, Losses, and Judges: Framing and the Judiciary Jeffrey J. Rachlinski Cornell Law School Andrew J. Wistrich United States District Court for the Central District of California Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.nd.edu/ndlr Part of the Courts Commons, and the Judges Commons Recommended Citation 94 Notre Dame L. Rev. 521 (2019). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Notre Dame Law Review at NDLScholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Notre Dame Law Review by an authorized editor of NDLScholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. \\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\94-2\NDL202.txt unknown Seq: 1 27-DEC-18 9:19 GAINS, LOSSES, AND JUDGES: FRAMING AND THE JUDICIARY Jeffrey J. Rachlinski* & Andrew J. Wistrich** Losses hurt more than foregone gains—an asymmetry that psychologists call “loss aver- sion.” Losses cause more regret than foregone gains, and people struggle harder to avoid losses than to obtain equivalent gains. Loss aversion produces a variety of anomalous behaviors: people’s preferences depend upon the initial reference point (reference-dependent choice); people are overly focused on maintaining the status quo (status quo bias); people attach more value to goods they own than to identical goods that they do not (endowment effect); and people take excessive risks to avoid sure losses (risk seeking in the face of losses). These phenomena are so pervasive that legal scholars have assumed that they influence the development of law. Although numerous studies reveal that framing influences how ordinary people think about their rights, a clear demonstration that judges decide cases differently when the underlying facts present gains as opposed to losses does not exist.
  • How Buyer Usage Intent Affects the Pricing of Used Goods

    How Buyer Usage Intent Affects the Pricing of Used Goods

    Aaron R. Brough & Mathew S. Isaac Finding a Home for Products We Love: How Buyer Usage Intent ConsumersAffects often dispose of theused products Pricing by selling them in a ofsecondary Used market (e.g., classifiedGoods advertisements, Craigslist, eBay). When consumers must dispose of products to which they feel emotionally attached, they often expect to sell the product at a price in excess of its market value. However, the authors identify a condition in which product attachment can decrease rather than increase the minimum price sellers are willing to accept. Specifically, they propose that due to concern for how products are used following a transaction, strongly attached sellers may be more willing than weakly attached sellers to provide discounts to potential buyers whose usage intentions are deemed appropriate. Whereas prior research has focused primarily on one particular consequence of attachment, namely, the intensified reluctance of consumers to part with their possessions, this research identifies a novel consequence of attachment: a heightened sensitivity to the manner in which the product will be used following a transaction. Four empirical studies provide converging evidence that sellers’ product attachment determines the extent to which their minimum acceptable sales price is influenced by buyer usage intent. Keywords: product attachment, secondary markets, pricing, product disposition onsumers often dispose of used products by selling from the transaction. According to this logic, as the strength them in a secondary market (e.g., classified adver- of a seller’s attachment to an item increases, the item’s min- tisements, Craigslist, eBay). An important decision imum acceptable selling price should increase as well.
  • Nishad Singhi Btech Thesis

    Nishad Singhi Btech Thesis

    Computational Modeling of Decisions in Mixed Gambles Thesis submitted by Nishad Singhi 2016EE10107 under the guidance of Prof. Sumeet Agarwal Prof. Sumitava Mukherjee in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the award of the degree of Bachelor of Technology Department Of Electrical Engineering INDIAN INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY DELHI July 2020 Contents ABSTRACT 2 1 INTRODUCTION 3 2 Computational models of decision making 5 2.1 Neurophysiology of Choice [BUZM07] . 5 2.2 Drift Diffusion Model . 5 2.3 The Leaky Competing Accumulator [UM01] . 6 3 Modeling mixed gambles using Drift Diffusion Model 8 3.1 Why do people reject mixed gambles? [ZWB18] . 8 3.1.1 Experimental Data . 8 3.1.2 Modeling . 8 3.1.3 Reported and replicated results . 9 3.2 Additional dataset . 11 3.2.1 Description of dataset . 11 3.2.2 DDM fitting results . 13 3.3 Discussion . 14 4 Modeling mixed gambles using LCA 15 4.1 LCA for value based decisions [UM04] . 15 4.1.1 Fitting Methods . 16 4.1.2 Experiments . 17 4.1.3 Discussion . 21 5 General Discussion 23 A Economics models of decision making 26 A.1 Expected Utility Hypothesis [MCWG+95] . 26 A.2 Prospect Theory [KT79] . 26 A.2.1 Value Function . 26 A.2.2 Weighting Function . 26 A.2.3 Evaluation of outcomes . 27 B Modeling of Loss Aversion for time 28 B.1 Introduction . 28 B.2 Experimental Design . 28 B.3 Stimuli . 28 B.4 Information given to participants . 29 ABSTRACT An important finding in behavioural economics is that people tend to reject mixed gambles.