Human Conservation Programs at Catoctin Mountain Park: a Special Resource Study

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Human Conservation Programs at Catoctin Mountain Park: a Special Resource Study Human Conservation Programs at Catoctin Mountain Park: A Special Resource Study Final April 23, 2015 By Angela R. Sirna Ph.D. Candidate in Public History Middle Tennessee State University EXECUTIVE SUMMARY In 2011, the Organization of American Historians (OAH), at the behest of the National Park Service (NPS), published Imperiled Promise: The State of History in the National Park Service. Among the twelve recommendations the consultants made, Finding #9 "Stewardship and Interpretation of Agency History" serves as both the purpose and need for this Special Resource Study on Human Conservation Programs at Catoctin Mountain Park. The authors charge that the NPS, despite its vast institutional archives, considers its own story as somehow separate from the history it is mandated with preserving or interpreting. Staff and historians working at Catoctin Mountain Park have made progress in documenting the area’s history, including the NPS’s role. This study, however, brings both the area’s pre-park history and agency history together using one framework. It encourages park staff to use this framework to direct future research initiatives, preservation, and management strategies, while also enriching interpretation and public engagement. "Human conservation" is an idea that originated in the Progressive Era at the turn of the twentieth century and loosely parallels the natural conservation movement that created the national park system during the same period. Shaped by land economists, politicians, and recreation advocates, the guiding principle behind human conservation is that human beings are a vital, national resource (like trees, soil, and water) that should and can be carefully managed to reach their highest potential. Catoctin Mountain Park serves as an important case study in charting these programs over the twentieth century from the removal of local farm families to create a park in 1936 to the opening of the nation's very first Job Corps Center in 1965 and the installation of a pilot Youth Conservation Corps camp in 1971. State and federal officials began investigating the Catoctin Mountain area in rural Frederick County, Maryland during the throes of the Great Depression as a possible location for a Recreational Demonstration Area (RDA). Their chief aim was to retire submarginal land into a park area and resettle the local population to better farms. However, the agencies involved in the park development project never developed a plan to resettle these families, exacerbating an already difficult situation. Despite this disruption, many of these families remained in Frederick and Washington counties and continued to farm. Beginning in 1936, the Works Progress Administration (WPA) hired a number of former residents and area locals to construct the park, making it a uniquely local project. The Civilian Conservation Corps (CCC) established a camp in 1939, which brought young men between the ages of 16 and 21 from adjacent states to provide manpower for project work. The CCC remained at Catoctin until 1941. Together with the WPA, they transformed the landscape from a collection of farmsteads and timber lots to a park complete with roads, trails, picnic areas, and three organized cabin camps. The cabin camps provided low-cost recreational opportunities to children and their families from Washington, D.C. and Baltimore. Before World War II, the Maryland League for Crippled Children, Salvation Army, Boy and Girl Scouts, and Federal Employees Council rented these cabin camps. In January 1965, Catoctin opened the very first Job Corps Conservation Center (JCCC) in the country. Congress established the Job Corps program when it passed the Economic Opportunity Act of 1964. This piece of legislation was key to President Lyndon B. Johnson's War on Poverty. The Job Corps program was modeled after the CCC and it is no coincidence that the Job Corps built the new center on the foundations of the old CCC camp in the area now referred to as ii Round Meadow, which the NPS continues to use for various administrative functions. However, the two programs were very different. First, administrators purposely integrated the Job Corps during the Civil Rights movement, while the CCC was segregated. The CCC was primarily concerned with unemployment and conservation work. The Job Corps focused on education and vocational training, while also hoping to solve the issue of poverty in America. Administrators learned very quickly that they were poorly equipped to solve the issue of poverty. After years of heavy political pressure from Republicans, President Richard Nixon closed the Catoctin Job Corps center in 1969. The center had a profound impact on the lives of corpsmen and staff that lived and worked there, and blazed the path for the current Job Corps centers still in operation today as well as subsequent youth programs. Only weeks after the last Job Corps staff member left, the NPS used the center for new environmental education initiatives. Inner-city children camped at the former Job Corps center in Round Meadow during the summer of 1969 and 1970 as part of the “Summer in the Parks” initiative aimed at expanding park programming to urban populations. In 1971, the NPS chose Catoctin as the site of a pilot Youth Conservation Corps (YCC) residential camp. The YCC program was open to high school boys and girls between the ages of 15 and 18 and focused on environmental education while completing much needed park maintenance work. Some of the first YCC participants testified to Congress in support of expanding the program and making it permanent, which Congress did in 1974. The Catoctin YCC continued to be a popular summer program and expanded throughout the 1970s. However, President Ronald Reagan cut YCC funding in 1980. Catoctin now receives its YCC support through a regional NPS fund. Today, the park maintains a crew of about eight student-employees that work at the park for eight weeks during the summer carrying out essential park maintenance while learning about the environment and gaining job experience. This Special Resource Study builds upon the work of previous historians and incorporates a large amount of source material in one thematic structure. This study encourages staff at Catoctin Mountain Park to use this framework to expand stewardship of park resources and build stronger relationships with the public. It recommends invigorating existing interpretation to demonstrate how complex human relationships have transformed this natural area. The park is encouraged to partner with groups with a vested interest in this history, such as the Maryland League for People with Disabilities, Job Corps alumni, and current YCC participants through temporary exhibits, documentary projects, and anniversary events. The park should recognize the authority of these groups in telling their own stories. This study also deepens the context for the park's cultural resources and sheds light on those areas that remain to be documented, particularly the Job Corps center at Camp Round Meadow. Catoctin Mountain Park is one of the first parks to examine the War on Poverty in its history, and hopefully this study will serve as a useful model for other parks wishing to examine their own role in social reform and human conservation. iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This Special Resource Study has been my public history doctoral residency for Middle Tennessee State University between August 2013 and May 2014. This residency was made possible through a partnership between the National Capital Region and Catoctin Mountain Park of the National Park Service and the Public History Program at Middle Tennessee State University. My gratitude goes to Scott Bell, Chief of Resource Management at Catoctin Mountain Park, who hired me to work as a Cultural Resource Specialist for the park for a summer, during which time I read widely about cultural landscapes. I began to see the Catoctin park landscape with new eyes and inspired me to propose a version of this study to Scott and Perry Wheelock, Associate Regional Director for Resources Stewardship, Partnerships, and Science. This residency was able to get off the ground with guidance and support from Scott and Superintendent Mel Poole and National Capital Regional cultural resources staff Joy Beasley, Dean Herrin, Kathryn Smith, Catherine Dewey, Martha Tempkin, and Jennifer Talken- Spaulding. I must express special thanks to Dean Herrin, Regional Historian, for serving as my professional mentor during this residency year. I hope that this project may serve as a model to future partnerships between doctoral students and the National Park Service. I appreciate those individuals who contributed to this research project including Park Ranger Debbie Mills and Park Carpenter Mark Hauver, as well as those that shared their personal memories: Tom McFadden, Elwood Hauver, Beatrice Stottlemyer, Clyde "Al" Maxey, Charles Riebe, and Lamar Marchese. It was honor to hear their stories. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF FIGURES .............................................................................................................................. vii ABBREVIATIONS .................................................................................................................................. x RESEARCH METHODS ...................................................................................................................... 1 CHAPTER ONE: PROGRESSIVE ROOTS OF HUMAN CONSERVATION ...................... 6 Introduction ........................................................................................................................................................
Recommended publications
  • Evaluating the Relevance of Critical Schools of Law and Economics for the Equality Rights of Workers with Disabilities in Canada and the United States
    Law and Economics and Equality Rights of Workers with Disabilities 935 Evaluating the Relevance of Critical Schools of Law and Economics for the Equality Rights of Workers with Disabilities in Canada and the United States Ravi A. Malhotra' This article examines the contributions ofmodern Hans eel article. I 'auteur examine les contributions schools oflaw and economics to the equality rights of des e'coles de droit el dc commerce modernes aux workers with disabilities. While neo-classical law and droits d'e'galite des Iravailleurs souffrant d'invalidile. economics generally advocates the supremacy offree Alors que le droit el I'economic neo-classiques markets to operate without government interference defendent habituellemenl la suprematie du marche and legal regulation, many ofthe newer schools oflaw libre pour fonclionner sans ingerence du and economics offer highly creative solutions and gouvernement ni re'gleinentation juridique, un grand dynamic approaches that may offer real hope to people nombre d 'e'coles de droit el de commerce plus recentes with disabilities. The merits and weaknesses of the proposenl des solutions Ires cre'alives el des approches theories oflhese modern schools are discussed in light dymimiques pouvant offrir un veritable espoir aux of the social model of disability. The schools are personnes sauffrant d'invalidite. Les merites el les examinedby drawing on examplesfrom Canadian and lacunes des theories de ces e'coles modernes font American jurisprudence. Specifically, the extent to I"ohjeld'ime discussion a la lumiere dtt modelesocial which the schools provide robust explanations for d'invalidite. I.es e'coles sonl examinees au moyen labour market policy is explored.
    [Show full text]
  • Toward a History of Management Thought
    Toward a History of Management Thought Charles Howell SyracuseUniversity The historyof managementthought suffers from a constricteddefinition of its subject.Constituent fields (marketing) and cognate fields (economics and law) areoften neglected in studiesof the subject.The term"thought" tends to be equated to knowledge,and thus given a positivistcast, or describedin instrumentalterms andthereby reduced to a generalizedform of practice.The historyof management thought,in short,invites more expansive treatment than it hashitherto received. Thispaper explores the potential benefits of an enlargeddefinition. The paperfocuses on two economists,Edwin Gay of Harvardand Richard Ely of the University of Wisconsin,who influencedthe developmentof managementthought, and whosecareers illuminate aspects of it that havebeen neglectedin previoushistories. Both are associated with institutionsthat promoted scholarship,education, and public discourse about business and its socialfunction-- institutionswhose role in shapingmanagement thought has received little attention. Both showeda keeninterest in the role of the statein economiclife. Their advocacy of regulatoryand fiscal policies suggests that ideas about techniques of managing grewup alongsideideas about political and social life, andthat in any satisfactory accountof managementthought these two strandsmust be interwoven.Both played a role in the professionalizationof economicsin the early twentiethcentury: their contributionto managementthought highlights interconnections between the two fieldsthat
    [Show full text]
  • El Darwinismo Social Recurrente O La Propuesta De Esterilizar a Las Personas Desempleadas
    El darwinismo social recurrente o la propuesta de esterilizar a las personas desempleadas Daniel Raventós 21/01/2018 Un amigo me envía una nota periodística sobre las declaraciones de un diputado conservador del Reino Unido en las que propone esterilizar a los desempleados para que dejen de cobrar ayudas por hijos. El tipo, un tal Ben Bradley, asegura que “Hay cientos de familias en el Reino Unido que ganan más de 60.000 libras en beneficios sin mover un dedo porque tienen tantos hijos (¡y para el resto de nosotros ese es un salario de más de 90.000 libras antes de impuestos!)”. Este simpático pimpollo tiene solamente 28 años. Parece algo horrible y desvergonzado. Pero hay precedentes espectaculares mucho más sonados. La nota enviada por mi amigo me recordó un artículo escrito para Sin Permiso hace casi 8 años al que voy a desempolvar un poco. Situémonos en los años 30 del siglo pasado. Se discutía por entonces en EEUU la conveniencia del subsidio de desempleo. Se acabó implantando en el año 1935, bajo la presidencia de Franklin D. Roosevelt, este subsidio. Hubo grandes debates, antes y después de promulgada la ley, entre políticos, economistas, intelectuales, periodistas y población en general. No ha pasado ni un siglo entero, pero se emitían declaraciones del siguiente tono sobre lo que supondría este subsidio: “La dominación definitiva del socialismo sobre la vida y la industria” (Asociación Nacional de Fabricantes); “Destruirá la iniciativa, desalentando el ahorro y ahogando la responsabilidad individual” (James L. Donnelly, de la Asociación de Fabricantes de Illinois); “En un momento u otro, traerá consigo, ineluctablemente, el final del capitalismo privado” (Charles Denby, Jr., de la Asociación Americana de Abogados).
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Economics Broadly Considered Jeff E
    Marquette University e-Publications@Marquette Economics Faculty Research and Publications Economics, Department of 1-1-2001 Introduction to Economics Broadly Considered Jeff E. Biddle John B. Davis Marquette University, [email protected] Steven G. Medema Published version. "Introduction," in Economics Broadly Considered: Essays in Honor of Warren J. Samuels. London: Taylor & Francis (Routledge), 2001: 1-29. Permalink. © 2001 Taylor & Francis (Routledge). Used with permission. Introduction Economics broadly considered: a glance at Warren J. Samuels' contributions to economics Jeff E. Biddle, John B. Davis, and Steven G. Medema Warren J. Samuels was born in New York City and grew up in Miami, Florida. He earned his B.A. from the University of Miami in 1954 and his Ph.D. from the University of Wisconsin in 1957. After holding positions at the University of Missouri, Georgia State University, and the University of Miami, Samue1s was Professor of Economics at Michigan State University from 1968 until his retirement in 1998 (for biographical details, see Samuels 1995 and Blaug 1999). Samuels' contributions to economics range widely across the discipline, but his most significant work, and the largest share of his corpus, falls within the history of economic thought, the economic role of government (and par­ ticularly law and economics), and economic methodology. All of this work has been undertaken against the backdrop of an institutional approach to economics and economic thought. Samuels was exposed to the institutional approach already during his undergraduate days at Miami, and he pursued the Ph.D. at Wisconsin because of its institutionalist tradition (then drawing to a close), as evidenced in faculty members such as Edwin Witte, Harold Groves, Martin Glaeser, Kenneth Parsons, and Robert Lampman.
    [Show full text]
  • URMC 19280404.Pdf (4.971Mb)
    r sr* ——— Summer School fa* 1 Have of Edition you thought attending summer school? The C. A. C. Section One session is us attractive as the cool The Rocky Mountain Collegian climate Publilhed the by Allocated Student, of the Colorado Agricultural College Suing xxxvii mm miu.iNa, wi.uuaho. wednesdav, april t, 1928 NUMBER 27 28 SILVER SPRUCE ■ f A. W. S. CHOOSE CAMPUS TO BE POLLED FOR RATING U. S. PRESIDENTIAL CHOICE LINS RICH TWO DELEGATES Rocky Mountain Collegian To Sponsor Student Elect- YEAR ion May 3 MONG BOOKS FOR CONVENTION Each Colorado Aggie student will be given a chance to vote for bis choice for president of the United States on May 3 during L Year Annual Haa Entered the chapel hour. Ballots will he printed for the poll, which is All-American Content Dorothea Ynn Horn and Janet | sponsored* by the Rocky Mountain Collegian. Wallace Will Represent i * "j A poll such as is being sponsored Local Organization I fi.aces tenth increase in interests by the Collegian haa been carried on that the political in of the eastern schools; con- in the colleges and universities is a GO TO SEATTLE many die and Hither and Yon returning interest nte tests were only recently run at Ne- good sign of the Commented ip braska and Montana State of the for governmental af- fcctions Especially University public Sectional Convention With Sixty College. fairs. The elections also serve to Colleges Represented and The “collegiate the student-electors with Contest rating*, o* collegiate pre-presidential ncquaint the candidates. tchovl annuals have recently campaign elections” have been prais- .
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Frank A. Fetter's Capital, Interest, and Rent
    Introduction to Frank A. Fetter’s Capital, Interest, and Rent di Murray N. Rothbard Frank Albert Fetter (1863-1949) was the leader in the United States of the early Austrian school of economics. Born in rural Indiana, Fetter was graduated from the Indiana University in 1891. After earning a master’s degree at Cornell University, Fetter pursued his studies abroad and received a doctorate in economics in 1894 from the University of Halle in Germany. Fetter then taught successively at Cornell, Indiana, and Stanford universities. He returned to Cornell as professor of political economy and finance (1901-1911) and terminated his academic career at Princeton University (1911-31), where he also served as chairman of the department of economics. Fetter is largely remembered for his views on business “monopoly” (see his Masquerade of Monopoly [New York: Harcourt, Brace and Co., 1931]). But long before he published his work on monopoly in the 1930s, he developed a unified and consistent theory of distribution that explained the relationship among capital, interest, and rent. While Fetter’s theoretical work, like much of capital and interest theory in recent decades, has been generally neglected, much of it is still valuable and instructive today. In my opinion, microeconomic analysis has a considerable way to go to catch up to the insight that we find in Fetter’s writings in the first decade and a half of this century. Apart from his two lucidly written treatises (The Principles of Economics [New York: The Century Co., 1904]; and Economic Principles [New York: The Century Co., 1915]), Fetter’s major contributions to distribution theory appeared in the series of journal articles and shorter papers that I have collected to form this volume.
    [Show full text]
  • Thurman Arnold (1891‐1969)
    Interpreters of Economic Ideas: Thurman Arnold (1891‐1969) ( I am grateful to Bruce Caldwell and Steve Medema for comments on an earlier draft) Craufurd Goodwin August, 2016 “…lawyers and economists have always been a frustrating force in American society. There is no more possibility of getting rid of them than a dog has of getting rid of fleas.” Thurman Arnold to Rexford G. Tugwell, August 22, 1967 (Gressley 474) Background A category of public intellectuals that resides at the fringes of what we think of today as economic science has received little attention from historians of economics and should, I suggest, receive more. The main objective of those in this category has been to discover how economics could be useful in explaining and solving policy problems in fields different from but adjacent to those that are thought of as economic and along paths that are different from the conventional ones of applied economics. These “fringe economists” are seldom interested in economics for its own sake, only for what it can do for them. One of their main achievements has been to bring economic thinking of a certain kind to an audience that is much broader and more diverse than is typically reached by conventional disseminators of economics such as textbook writers and specialists on economics in the media. The impact that these interpreters have had on the economic policies that they address, and sometimes backward onto economic science as well, has yet to be fully understood. The economic public intellectuals that I have examined have several qualities in common that help to justify their treatment as a group.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Nixon Carver, How Ought Wealth to Be Distributed? (1906)1
    AMERICAN POLITICAL THOUGHT Keith E. Whittington Supplementary Material Chapter 8: The Progressive Era – Political Economy Thomas Nixon Carver, How Ought Wealth to be Distributed? (1906)1 Born on an Iowa farm at the end of the Civil War, Thomas Nixon Carver entered college late and completed a Ph.D. in economics at Cornell University in 1894. He spent most of his career at Harvard University, where he taught a blend of economic theory and social philosophy influenced by Herbert Spencer and emerged as a vocal critic of socialism in the early twentieth century. [A]lthough there is so much unanimity in the opinion that wealth ought not to be distributed as it now is, there is still a wide diversity of opinion, where there is any definite opinion at all, as to how it really ought to be distributed. These opinions may, however, be reduced to three fundamentally distinct theories, which I shall call the aristocratic, the socialistic, and the democratic, or liberalistic, theories. The aristocratic theory is that the good things of the world belong more particularly to certain groups or classes than to others, by virtue of some circumstances connected with their birth or heredity, and independently of their individual achievements. The socialistic theory is that wealth ought to be distributed according to needs, or according to some similar plan arranged beforehand, and independently of the individual’s ability to acquire wealth in the rough-and-ready struggle of life. The democratic, or liberalistic, theory is that wealth ought to be distributed according to productivity, usefulness, or worth.
    [Show full text]
  • Manuscript Division, Library of Congress
    Charles Bowdoin Fillebrown Papers A Finding Aid to the Collection in the Library of Congress Manuscript Division, Library of Congress Washington, D.C. 2010 Contact information: http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.mss/mss.contact Catalog Record: https://lccn.loc.gov/mm2009085451 Additional search options available at: https://hdl.loc.gov/loc.mss/eadmss.ms010126 Prepared by Donna Ellis Finding aid encoded by Library of Congress Manuscript Division, 2010 Collection Summary Title: Charles Bowdoin Fillebrown Papers Span Dates: 1879-1928 Bulk Dates: (bulk 1897-1917) ID No.: MSS85451 Creator: Fillebrown, Charles Bowdoin, 1842-1917 Extent: 1,000 items Extent: 2 containers Extent: .8 linear feet Language: Collection material in English Location: Manuscript Division, Library of Congress, Washington, D.C. LC Catalog record: https://lccn.loc.gov/mm2009085451 Summary: Economist and author. Correspondence, speeches, and printed matter relating to Fillebrown's promotion of the single tax and the activities of the Massachusetts Single Tax League. Selected Search Terms The following terms have been used to index the description of this collection in the LC Catalog. They are grouped by name of person or organization, by subject or location, and by occupation and listed alphabetically. People Carver, Thomas Nixon, 1865-1961--Correspondence. Clark, John Bates, 1847-1938--Correspondence. Commons, John R. (John Rogers), 1862-1945--Correspondence. Ely, Richard T. (Richard Theodore), 1854-1943--Correspondence. Fetter, Frank A. (Frank Albert), 1863-1949--Correspondence. Fillebrown, Charles Bowdoin, 1842-1917. Hirsch, Max, 1853-1909--Correspondence. Johnson, Alvin Saunders, 1874-1971--Correspondence. Nicholson, J. Shield (Joseph Shield), 1850-1927--Correspondence. Plehn, Carl C. (Carl Copping), 1867- --Correspondence.
    [Show full text]
  • The Three “Furies” of Libertarianism: Rose Wilder Lane, Isabel Paterson, and Ayn Rand
    The Three “Furies” of Libertarianism: Rose Wilder Lane, Isabel Paterson, and Ayn Rand Jennifer Burns Downloaded from “They make all of us male writers look like Confederate money,” wrote the curmud- geonly cultural critic Albert Jay Nock in 1943. According to Congressman Howard Buf- fett, they “have talent that surpasses that of almost any mere male that I know in the country.” Reflecting on the rise of the Right over the course of the twentieth century, the http://jah.oxfordjournals.org/ journalist John Chamberlain noted, “If it had been left to pusillanimous males probably nothing much would have happened.” To William F. Buckley Jr., they were the “three furies” of libertarianism: the children’s author and magazine writer Rose Wilder Lane, the book critic Isabel Paterson, and the best-selling novelist Ayn Rand. Popular writers who are not typically remembered as significant intellectuals, Lane, Paterson, and Rand nonetheless exerted, according to their contemporaries, a powerful influence on the ideo- 1 logical development of the American Right. at Stanford University on December 14, 2015 But what exactly was this influence, and how should historians make sense of the striking presence of three women, bound by similar life experiences and tenuous bonds of friendship, at the core of modern antistatism? It seems more than coincidence to find three women at this pivotal moment, yet Lane, Paterson, and Rand resist easy analysis on the grounds of gender. They did not claim their womanhood as a source of particu- lar wisdom and did not identify with women as a group. The triumphant self that ran through their fiction could manifest itself in both male and female guise.
    [Show full text]
  • GIPE-167155-Contents.Pdf
    Dhanan)ayarao Gadgll LIbrary 11111111111 111111111 ~II 111I nil III GlPE-PUNE-167155 ,LIBRARY , \~<t '. ECONOMIC ESSA YS CONTKIBUTED IN HONOK OJ' JOHN BATES CLARK .~ . ...9 0 THE MACMILLAN COMPANY N'BW VORK BOSTON· CHICAGO DALLAS ATLANTA SAN FRANCISCO MACMILLAN &: CO. LIMITED LONDON· BOMBAY· CALCtrnA MKLBOURNB THE MACMILLAN CO OF CANADA., 1m>. TOJlONTO ECONOMIC ESSAYS CONTRIBUTED IN HONOR OF JOHN BATES CLARK EDITED BY JACOB H. HOLLANDER Publi,hed em behalf of the American. Economic Al80ciatiem Jl1ttD !JDtk THE MACMILLAN COl\.IP ANY 1927 CoPYRIGHT, 1927, By THE MACMILLAN COMPANY. Set up and printed. Pubhshed November. 1927. x p/Fl /67/55 SZT Up BY BROWN .aOTHERS, Lltr01'YPEU I'al.TBD 1M THB UNITED STATES OP AIlOICA JlY TH. co •• WALL PRESI PUBLICATION COMMITTEE EDWIN R. A. SELIGMAN RICHARD T. ELY JACOB H. HOLLANDER BENJAMIN M. ANDERSON, JR. JOHN MAURICE CLARx CONTENTS PACB JOHN BATES CLARK AS AN ECONOMIST 1 Jacob H. Hollander, Ph D , Abram G Hutzler Professor of Po­ htlcal Economy, Johns Hopkins University STATIC EcONOMICS AND BUSINESS FORECASTING • 6 Benjamin M. Anderson, Jr., Ph D., Economist of the Chase National Bank of the City of New York THE ENTREPRENEUR AND THE SUPPLY OF CAPITAL 14 George E. Barnett, Ph.D, Professor of Statistics, Johns Hopkins Uwve1'Slty THE MALTHUSIAD: FANTASIA ECONOMICA • 22 James Bonar, M.A., LLD., Lately Deputy Master of the Can­ adian Branch of the Royal Mint at Ottawa, Ontario THE STATIC STATE AND THE TECHNOLOGY OF ECONOMIC REFORM 29 Thomas Nixon Carver, PhD., LL D , DaVid A. WeIls Professor of Pohtical Economy, Harvard Uwve1'Slty THE RELATION BETWEEN STATICS AND DYNAMICS • 46 John Maurice Clark, PhD., Professor of Economics, Columbia Uwversity ELASTICITY OF SUPPLY AS A DETERMINANT OF DISTRIBUTION 71 Paul H.
    [Show full text]
  • The Progressive Critique of Laissez Faire (Reviewing Barbara H
    University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Journal Articles Faculty Scholarship 1999 The Assault that Failed: The Progressive Critique of Laissez Faire (reviewing Barbara H. Fried, The Progressive Assault on Laissez Faire : Robert Hale and the First Law and Economics Movement (1998)) Richard A. Epstein Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/journal_articles Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Richard A. Epstein, "The Assault that Failed: The Progressive Critique of Laissez Faire (reviewing Barbara H. Fried, The Progressive Assault on Laissez Faire : Robert Hale and the First Law and Economics Movement (1998))," 97 Michigan Law Review 1697 (199 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE ASSAULT THAT FAILED: THE PROGRESSIVE CRITIQUE OF LAISSEZ FAIRE Richard A. Epstein* THE PROGRESSIVE ASSAULT ON LAISSEZ FAIRE: ROBERT HALE AND THE FIRST LAW AND ECONOMICS MovEMENT. By BarbaraH. Fried. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. 1998. Pp. x, 338. $55. PLAYING FOR ALL THE MARBLES Robert Lee Hale has long been an intellectual thorn in the side of the defenders of laissez faire, among whom I am quite happy to count myself. As Barbara Fried1 notes in her meticulous study of Hale's work, his name is hardly a household word. But both di- rectly and indirectly, his influence continues to be great. His best known work is perhaps Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State,2 published in 1923 as a review of Thomas Nixon Carver's Principles of NationalEconomy, 3 itself a defense of the classical principles of laissez faire, remembered today only for the drubbing that it took at Hale's hands.
    [Show full text]