Malthus the Economist

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Malthus the Economist A Reprint from THE SOCIAL CONTRACT ISSN 1055-145X Thomas Robert Malthus The Economist by Vernon M. Briggs, Jr. Reprinted from THE SOCIAL CONTRACT Volume VIII, Number 3 Spring 1998 © 1998 The Social Contract Press 445 E. Mitchell Street Petoskey, MI 49770 (231) 347-1171 (Fax -1185) socco n@freeway. net Spring 1998 THE SOCIAL CONTRACT Malthus: The Economist He held the very first British Chair in 'political economy' by Vernon M. Briggs, Jr. As a Founding Father In 1804, at the age of 39, Malthus was appointed hroughout history societies have built statues, to the first professorship established in Great Britain monuments and even pantheons to memo­ for the study of political economy. It was at the newly Trialize the accomplishments of their founders, established East India College located east of London leaders, and inspirational heroes. Yet many of at Haileybury. He assumed the post in 1805 and held history's most influential contributors seldom receive the position continuously until his death in 1834. In such recognition. Such has been the fate of a number preparation for this appointment, Malthus had earned of writers in the field of economics. As Robert a bachelor of arts degree from Jesus College at Heilbroner has so aptly observed, economics has Cambridge University in 1788. Shortly afterwards he produced "a handful of men" whose contributions to took the vows of Holy Orders at the College and, mankind have been "more decisive for history than subsequently, he received a Master of Arts degree in many acts of statesmen who basked in brighter glory, 1791 and was elected as a fellow in 1793 at the same often more profoundly disturbing than the shuttling of institution. For a short spell, he served as a parish armies back and forth across frontiers, and more priest prior to his marriage in 1804, after which he powerful for good and bad than the edicts of kings and 1 pursued a career as an academician. legislatures." For, as he put it, the "extraordinary As a consequence, Malthus has been ennobled by power of their ideas" has "shaped and swayed men's 2 John Maynard Keynes who described him as being minds." One such person cited by Heilbroner is "the first of the Cambridge economists."3 It is a Thomas Robert Malthus. statement of deference. It places Malthus among a Malthus was a "founding father" of the discipline hallowed subgroup of economic of economics. But more important than his role as an scholars whose intellectual intellectual pioneer has been the II flaithus was considered lineage over the past two impact of the conceptualizations • " 'the outstanding centuries has left an indelible he proffered and the imprint on the evolution of economist of ail Europe.' methodological approach he economic doctrines. For championed as the way economic subsequent "Cambridge issues should be studied and policy conclusions economists" included such luminaries as Alfred derived. Marshall, who formalized the principles of what is Although the topical range of his interests was today referred to as microeconomics, as well as wide, Malthus is best remembered for his inquiry into the causes and effects of population growth. Others Keynes himself, who formalized the principles of what before him had speculated on population issues but he we now label macroeconomics. was the first to produce a general theory of population Malthus is better known for having been among in a systematic manner. the founding members of the "classical school" of economic writers.4 Collectively, they laid the Vernon M. Briggs, Jr. is Professor of Economics, Cornellintellectua l foundation upon which much of modern University School of Industrial and Labor Relations. He economics has been built. In the immediate decades is the author of Mass Immigration and the National following the publication in 1776 of Adam Smith's Interest (M.E. Sharpe, 1996). The Wealth of Nations — which is regarded as the 206 Spring 1998 THE SOCIAL CONTRACT masterwork that unified a host of miscellaneous ideas Landowners, merchants and manufacturers pros-pered into economics as a distinct subject of inquiry — there while the working class masses sank deeper into lives was immense scholarly activity. But it would not be of poverty and squalor. Wages of agricultural workers until 1817, when David Ricardo published his were set by local government officials who did not Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, that the permit them to rise. As for the wages of the growing refinement and the advancement of the corpus of ranks of manufacturing workers associated with the economic doctrines re-commenced in earnest. It was advancement of the Industrial Revolution, severe labor in this interim 41-year period that the writings of market competition kept these wages depressed as Malthus catapulted him to the status of being women and children were recruited to fill these jobs. considered "the outstanding economist of all Europe."3 When Napoleon surrendered in 1813, a host of During these early years of disciplinary new problems surfaced in Britain, associated with the development, Malthus established a close friendship re-conversion of the economy. Due to the magnitude with his contemporary, David Ricardo. In 1811, of the public debt, payments of the debt by specie had Malthus and Ricardo began an on-going exchange of been suspended; taxes remained high; prices soared letters that extended over while wages lagged so that the next ten years. It wmmmmmm—mmmm—mmtmm•Mm^HMi ^ the working masses resulted "in the most "...tumultuous events occurred in continued to be pauperized; precious literary the powerful agricultural correspondence in the Britain and continental Europe..." interests, fearing an influx history of economic m^m—m^mmmaaa—mmmm immmmmmmma^m^mmmm of cheaper imported grains, thought."6 Their written demanded tariff protection; dialog, as well as the conversations they had during and the manufacturing and shipping interests were numerous personal visits, served as a form of clamoring for concessions and subsidies from intellectual pollination. Through vigorous criticism, parliament. they stimulated each others' thoughts.7 Yet, despite the The supposedly harmonious course of economic fact that they typically held polar opposite viewpoints, development portrayed earlier by Adam Smith was their mutual admiration only intensified as the years exposed as being at best only an ephemeral description passed.s of a bygone pre-industrial era. Seemingly, The Wealth During the years when Malthus rose to of Nations had little of relevance to say about a British prominence, tumultuous events occurred in Britain society caught in the throes of urbanization, and continental Europe that dramatically influenced industrialization, and internationalization. The key the course of economic thinking. The French concerns of economics — production, exchange, and Revolution began in 1789 and, after ten years of near distribution — were being radically transformed by anarchy and general mayhem, it led to the seizure of these new social forces. dictatorial power by Napoleon Bonaparte. For the next Illustrative of the search for new ideas was the 15 years, he kept Europe in a nearly continuous state debate over the tariff question. Both Malthus and of warfare. As a consequence, the perilous state of Ricardo wrote widely circulated pamphlets on the international commerce in grains was revealed, while subject. For centuries, England had adopted various government purchases of foodstuffs greatly stimulated "corn laws" that placed duties on such imports and, at the demand for domestic grain suppliers. In Britain, as times, provided government bounties on such exports. elsewhere, extensive amounts of pasture land were The word "com" was generically used to apply to any converted into arable land (which meant the more edible grain (e.g., wheat, rye, barley or oats). During costly cultivation of marginally productive lands). the Napoleonic conflict, domestic corn prices had Large increases in the supply of money in circulation soared since imports had virtually stopped while occurred as the result of the government's need to demand sharply increased. Agricultural land owners, provision its soldiers and sailors. Prices skyrocketed. therefore, were fearful after the defeat of Napoleon 207 Spring 1998 THE SOCIAL CONTRACT that the British Isles would be flooded with gram lost as a result of high food prices. In other words, imports from continental Europe. They argued that it food prices and profits moved inversely. Hence, was in the public interest to protect them from foreign Ricardo attacked the Corn Law with its high tariff competition. They emphasized that they had sustained provisions. If the duty on imports was abolished, major costs associated with expanding domestic marginal (i.e., more costly) land would be taken out of production during the war years which they had a right production, the price of food would fall, and Britain to recoup. They also contended that it was not in the would prosper.9 national interest for the country to become dependent Malthus, on the other hand, defended agricultural on foreign food suppliers. Hence, they proposed a protectionism. Malthus, like Adam Smith, saw Britain sizable increase in the duties on imported corns to as primarily being an agricultural society. As a true prohibitive levels. The proposal triggered a domestic successor to Smith, Malthus viewed rent as the chief form of surplus (i.e., wealth) that society was creating. Agriculture essentially created its own demand. For "...it was not in the national interest while other commodities were not necessary after they were produced, food was, as it represented a demand for [Britain] to become dependent on for population. The reason food prices were high, therefore, lay in its abundance, not its scarcity as is the foreign food suppliers." case with other commodities. Rent was a gift of nature to the owners of land that ultimately increased the wealth of society.10 Malthus, however, claimed that his struggle between the powerful land-owning class and support for agricultural protectionism was not the emerging merchant and manufacturing class.
Recommended publications
  • The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: a Critique of Received Explanations
    The Neglect of the French Liberal School in Anglo-American Economics: A Critique of Received Explanations Joseph T. Salerno or roughly the first three quarters of the nineteenth century, the "liberal school" thoroughly dominated economic thinking and teaching in F France.1 Adherents of the school were also to be found in the United States and Italy, and liberal doctrines exercised a profound influence on prominent German and British economists. Although its numbers and au- thority began to dwindle after the 1870s, the school remained active and influential in France well into the 1920s. Even after World War II, there were a few noteworthy French economists who could be considered intellectual descendants of the liberal tradition. Despite its great longevity and wide-ranging influence, the scientific con- tributions of the liberal school and their impact on the development of Eu- ropean and U.S. economic thought—particularly on those economists who are today recognized as the forerunners, founders, and early exponents of marginalist economics—have been belittled or simply ignored by most twen- tieth-century Anglo-American economists and historians of thought. A number of doctrinal scholars, including Joseph Schumpeter, have noted and attempted to explain the curious neglect of the school in the En- glish-language literature. In citing the school's "analytical sterility" or "indif- ference to pure theory" as a main cause of its neglect, however, their expla- nations have overlooked a salient fact: that many prominent contributors to economic analysis throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries expressed strong appreciation of or weighty intellectual debts to the purely theoretical contributions of the liberal school.
    [Show full text]
  • The Shifting Geopolitics of Coronavirus and the Demise of Neoliberalism – (Part 2)
    Reports The Shifting Geopolitics of Coronavirus and the Demise of Neoliberalism – (Part 2) Dr. Mohammed Cherkaoui March 22 2020 Al Jazeera Centre for Studies Tel: +974-40158384 [email protected] http://studies.aljazeera.n Terrible decisions have to be made when hospitals are overwhelmed in Italy [Getty] European economic historians fear some déjà vu memories of the Black Death, which spread in the continent in the mid-14th century and led to the death of one third of the population. This reduction of demography caused scarcity of labor, increase in wages, decrease in inequality, and contested the then-feudal system in Europe. It also paved the way for the Industrial Revolution which Industrial Britain was hit by ‘King Cholera’ in 1831-32, 1848-49, 1854 and 1867. Tuberculosis also was responsible for the death of one-third of the casualties in Britain between 1800 and 1850. This nightmarish refrain comes back now stronger as epidemics have been ‘great equalizers’, and may initiate long-term implications nor only for European economic growth, but also for the world economy. After the US Federal Reserve decided to slash the benchmark interest rate to between zero and 0.25 percent (down from a range of 1 to 1.25 percent) and to buy $700 billion in Treasury bonds and mortgage-backed securities in a Sunday emergency meeting, the Dow Jones industrial average plunged 2,250 points at the open and trading suspended almost immediately the following day Monday, March 16. President Trump has framed the pandemic in xenophobic terms and made the wildly- irresponsible claim that “it will go away.
    [Show full text]
  • Social Economy As Social Science and Practice
    CAHIERde RECHERCHE 2004 # 6 Efficience et Mutations des Organisations Industrielles Social Economy as Social Science and Practice : Historical Perspectives on France 1 Danièle DEMOUSTIER Damien ROUSSELIERE Octobre 2004 Laboratoire d’Economie de la Production et de l’Intégration Internationale – FRE2664 UPMF-BP47 -38040 GRENOBLE Cedex 9 [email protected] Tél. : 04 76 82 56 92 http://www.upmf-grenoble.fr/lepii 1 Social Economy as Social Science and Practice: 1 Historical Perspectives on France Danièle DEMOUSTIER ESEAC, Equipe de Socio-Economie Associative et Coopérative Institut d’Etudes Politiques de Grenoble [email protected] Damien ROUSSELIÈRE LEPII, Laboratoire d’Economie de la Production et de l’Intégration Internationale CNRS-Grenoble II [email protected] Forthcoming in CLARY J., DOLFSMA W., FIGART D. (eds) Ethics and the Market: Insights from Social Economics, London & New York, Routledge, Advances in Social Economics, 2005. 2 Introduction Nowadays social, economic, political and cultural changes have exercised wide influence transforming the surrounding context, affecting organizations that recognize themselves in “social economy” due to their status (cooperative, mutualist and associative). They seem to live off the very contradictions that distance some among them from the solidarity built up, which leads others, in turn, to redefine their projects (Vienney 1994). On the other hand, they provoke the emergence of new organizations that identify themselves as belonging to the sphere of “civil and solidarity-based economy” [économie solidaire]. Thus the actors themselves, the authorities and public opinion on the whole, demand more legibility, in order to recognize the particularity of forms of economic production that assert themselves increasingly in a service economy (Gadrey 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Happiness and Unhappiness of the Economic Agent 19Th International Conference of the Charles Gide Society University Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne
    Happiness and Unhappiness of the Economic Agent 19th International Conference of the Charles Gide Society University Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne. 7-9 July 2022 Call for Papers The 19th conference of the Charles Gide Society will take place at the University Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne from the 7th to the 9th of July 2022. This event, organized by PHARE (Philosophie, Histoire et Analyse de la Pensée Econonmique, University Paris 1), LED (Laboratoire d’Economie Dyonisien, University Paris 8) and CES (Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne, University Paris 1) will address the topic “Happiness and Unhappiness of the Economic Agent”. Emerging during the French and Scottish enlightenments, political economy was developed as a narrative of the origins, which presented history as taking us away from unhappiness and progressing towards a future of happiness. The stages theories of Smith or Turgot illustrate this perspective. During the same period, the philosophy of Rousseau presented an opposite view, fledging society being characterized by happiness from which civilization led us away. These considerations were part of an empiricist philosophy of knowledge inspired by Locke and Condillac, stressing that human beings were more sensible to pain than to pleasure. What has become of these ways of relating happiness and unhappiness, pleasure and pain, on the one hand, and the progress of wealth and civilization, on the other, during the process of economic development? Since the end of 18th century, the question of happiness, like that of unhappiness, was a central concern of classical Utilitarianism. This is true of Bentham and his precursors, of course, but it is also true of those, such as J.
    [Show full text]
  • Institutions in Economic Thought Call for Papers
    13th Charles Gide Conference Institutions in Economic Thought Call for papers (Deadline: November 27, 2009) International Conference of the Charles Gide Association Organised by PHARE (Pôle d’Histoire de l’Analyse et des Représentations Economiques) Paris – May 27 to 29, 2010 PHARE (University of Paris I Panthéon‐Sorbonne) organizes in Paris from May 27 to 29, 2010 the 13th Biennial International Conference of the Charles Gide Association for the Study of Economic Thought (ACGEPE). The theme of the conference is “Institutions in Economic Thought”, but communications in history of economic thought on other issues are also welcomed. A reflection on institutions is essential to understand the economic world, from organizational routines to crises, from transaction to public intervention. The history of economic thought emphasizes that all economic theories, and not only those that declare themselves as such, integrate institutions in their arguments. Whether mere rules of the game or embedded in the economic life, chosen or spontaneous, legal or informal, institutions are indeed necessary for coordination among agents. Proposals for communications on the conference theme fall within one or several of the following topics: 1. The history of theories that make institutions an object of economic analysis. Themes of the communications may be the study of specific trends (for example, New Institutional Economics: Transaction Cost Theory, Public Choice, Law and Economics), concepts (the action in the institution, efficiency, justice, evolution…) or methods. 2. The history of theories that make institutions a tool of analysis, such as institutional theories of the economy (Old American Institutionalism, German Historical Schools, Theory of Regulation, Economics of Conventions, New Economic History, Classical, Marxist, Keynesian and Austrian trends…).
    [Show full text]
  • Clive Morrison-Bell, the Tariff Walls Map, and the Politics of Cartographic Display
    1 ‘The map that would save Europe’: Clive Morrison-Bell, the Tariff Walls Map, and the politics of cartographic display Mike Heffernan and Benjamin J. Thorpe School of Geography University of Nottingham Nottingham NG7 2RD Abstract This essay uses the personal archives of Clive Morrison-Bell (1871-1956), a campaigning Conservative politician who made extensive use of maps and cartographic models, to consider the entangled histories of cartography, economics and geopolitics in early twentieth-century Britain. Particular attention is paid to Morrison-Bell’s Tariff Walls Map (TWM), a large three-dimensional model of Europe on which international borders were represented by actual physical walls, the varying heights of which indicated average tariff restrictions imposed on traded goods by each European country. The TWM was one of the most widely debated maps of the 1920s and 1930s. Versions were exhibited in national parliaments, government ministries, chambers of commerce, and at international conferences across Europe and the United States, part of an ultimately unsuccessful campaign against economic protectionism. By depicting nation- states as volumetric spaces separated by physical barriers, the TWM contributed significantly to the idea of the ‘wall’ as an economic and geopolitical division. Keywords: Clive Morrison-Bell; European cartography; free trade; protectionism; tariff reform. ‘Something there is that doesn’t love a wall’ Robert Frost, Mending Wall, 1914 Clive Morrison-Bell (1871-1956) was a British member of parliament who made repeated use of maps and cartographic models in political campaigns before and after World War One, some associated with the Conservative Party, others of a more general character (Figure 1).
    [Show full text]
  • 16Th International Conference of the Charles Gide Association for the Study of Economic Thought Strasbourg, 14–16 April 2016
    16th international conference of the Charles Gide Association for the Study of Economic Thought Strasbourg, 14–16 April 2016 Call for papers st (Deadline for the submission of proposals: 1 of January 2016) The 16th international conference of the Charles Gide Association for the Study of Economic Thought will take place at the University of Strasbourg, 14–16 April 2016. This conference is organised by the laboratory Bureau d’Economie Théorique et Appliquée (BETA). This international conference will propose sessions on the theme “expectations, conjectures and coordination”, although any other proposal in the fields of the history of economic thought and philosophy of economics is also welcome. Expectations, conjectures and coordination Contemporary economic analysis was born with the study of strategic interactions between individuals. At the turn of the 17th and 18th centuries, Boisguilbert placed the issue of the available information and of expectations at the core of his explanation of economic fluctuations. For Boisguilbert, expectations of future prices formed by agents on agricultural markets can prove either stabilising or destabilising, depending on whether the economy is in a situation of free trade or prohibition. Later, Smith warned us about market exchange: “it is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest”. Here, the issue is about an interpersonal relationship: a consumer who would count on the acquisition of a good thanks to the benevolence of a producer is most likely to see his conjecture invalidated. Satisfying one’s needs through market exchange thus requires accurate forecasting of the behaviour of other agents, which is to forecast their own conjectures.
    [Show full text]
  • The Social Economy
    THE SOCIAL ECONOMY : THE WORLDWIDE MAKING OF A THIRD SECTOR Jacques Defourny & Patrick Develtere Centre d’Economie Sociale HIVA University of Liège Catholic University of Leuven This text is the first chapter of a collective book entiteld L’économie sociale au Nord et au Sud, compiled by J. Defourny, P. Develtere and B. Fonteneau (De Boeck, 1999). INDEX Introduction 3 I. Sources of the social economy 4 The association, a phenomenon as old as society itself 4 The ideological pluralism of the social economy in the XIX century 5 The range of religious influences 7 The forces of nationalism and the quest for a third way 8 The cultural entrenchment of the social economy 9 The complexion of a society is constantly changing 10 II. A contemporary definition of the social economy 11 The legal and institutional approach 11 The normative approach 15 Social economy or non-profit sector? 17 III. Conditions for developing the social economy 23 The social economy, child of necessity 23 The condition of necessity in the South 23 The condition of necessity in the North 24 Collective identity and shared destiny 25 Community forces in the South 26 What are the mobilising forces in the North? 28 Conclusion 30 Bibliography 31 3 INTRODUCTION The term "social economy" first appeared in France during the first third of the XIX century. For a long time, its meaning was much broader and amorphous than it is today. Anyone can develop their own a priori conception of the social econ- omy, simply by placing more or less emphasis on either its economic or its social dimensions, both of which are wide-ranging.
    [Show full text]
  • Professional Economists and Policymaking in the United States, 1880-1929
    ABSTRACT Title of Dissertation: IRRELEVANT GENIUS: PROFESSIONAL ECONOMISTS AND POLICYMAKING IN THE UNITED STATES, 1880-1929 Jonathan S. Franklin, Doctor of Philosophy, 2014 Dissertation Directed By: Professor David B. Sicilia, Department of History The rapid establishment and expansion of economics departments in colleges across the United State in the late nineteenth century indicates a significant shift in the way Americans understood economic science and its importance to federal economic policy. This dissertation addresses that phenomenon by explaining how American economists professionalized; and how that process influenced economic policymaking in the U.S. from the formation of the American Economic Association in 1885 to the Great Depression of the 1930s. Chapters alternate between analyzing the dilemmas economists faced while crafting a distinct academic discipline and investing early professional economists’ role in the federal economic policymaking process. Three emerging themes help explain the consistent failure of early U.S. economists to translate modern economic theory to economic policy in a timely fashion. First, public skepticism and the persistence of folk economics proved to be a powerful deterrent to professionally-trained economists’ authority in debates over policy matters. The combination of democratic idealism, populist politics, and skepticism regarding the motivations of professionally-trained economists undercut much of the social prestige professional economists garnered as educated elites. Second, disagreement among professional economists, often brought on by young economists’ efforts to overturn a century’s worth of received wisdom in classical economic theory, fostered considerable dissent within the field. Dissent, in turn, undermined the authority of professional economists and often led to doubt regarding economists’ abilities among the public and policy compromises that failed to solve economic problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Social Economy As Social Science and Practice: Historical Perspectives On
    Social economy as social science and practice : historical perspectives on France Danièle Demoustier, Damien Rousselière To cite this version: Danièle Demoustier, Damien Rousselière. Social economy as social science and practice : historical perspectives on France. Eleventh World Congress of Social Economics ”Social economics : a paradigm for a global society”, Albertville, 8-11 Juin 2004, 2004, pp.41. halshs-00102532 HAL Id: halshs-00102532 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00102532 Submitted on 2 Oct 2006 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Eleventh World Congress of Social Economics Social Economics: A Paradigm for a Global Society, Albertville, France June 8-11, 2004 Social Economy as Social Science and Practice: Historical Perspectives on France1 Danièle DEMOUSTIER ESEAC, Institut d‘Etudes Politiques de Grenoble Damien ROUSSELIERE LEPII, CNRS-Grenoble II Session : Social Economics and Economic Sociology Résumé Dans cet article, nous nous intéressons aux significations du terme polysémique d‘ « économie sociale », apparu à la fois comme concept dans le cadre de la création d‘une science sociale en lien avec les traditions libérale, chrétienne ou socialiste des économistes et pour désigner un ensemble de pratiques et/ou d‘institutions, avec l‘implantation du capitalisme en France.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy and the ’Modern View’ As Reflected in the History of Economic Thought
    n. 476 December 2012 ISSN: 0870-8541 Political Economy and the ’Modern View’ as reflected in the History of Economic Thought Mário Graça Moura 1;2 António Almodovar 1;2 1 FEP-UP, School of Economics and Management, University of Porto 2 CEF.UP, Research Center in Economics and Finance, University of Porto POLITICAL ECONOMY AND THE ‘MODERN VIEW ’ AS REFLECTED IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT * Mário Graça Moura 1, António Almodovar 2 Abstract: This paper focuses on the gradual decomposition of classical political economy and its transformation into ‘economics’, a process which was to culminate in the conception of ‘theory’ as a mere engine of analysis. Why exactly did modern ‘economics’ become accepted? What was meant to be achieved – and was it? And why did some writers reject both old political economy and modern economics? We intend to contribute to an understanding of these issues by analysing a set of representative histories of economic ideas from this period: those by Luigi Cossa (1880), John Kells Ingram (1915, originally published in 1888), and Charles Gide and Charles Rist (1915). Keywords: History of Economic Thought; Methodology; Classical Economics. JEL Classification: B1; B4 * This paper was presented at the Joint conference AHE, IIPPE, FAPE, July 5 – 7, 2012, Paris, France. We are grateful to the participants in this conference, especially to Nuno Martins for his written comments. 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Porto, and CEF.UP. CEF.UP is financially supported by FCT (Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia). Corresponding author: please email to [email protected] or address to Rua Dr Roberto Frias, 4200-464, Porto, Portugal.
    [Show full text]
  • Heterodox Economics Newsletter Issue 257 — January 06, 2020 — Web1 — Pdf2 — Heterodox Economics Directory3
    Heterodox Economics Newsletter Issue 257 | January 06, 2020 | web1 | pdf2 | Heterodox Economics Directory3 Yesterday, this year's ASSA meeting4 in San Diego has ended. The ASSA meeting is probably the greatest gathering of economists throughout the year and it is noteworthy insofar as the ASSA is one of the very few places, where exchange between heterodox and mainstream economists could be facilitated. I say 'could be', because actually this is only rarely the case: mainstream researchers typically do not participate in heterodox sessions, while heterodox economists, who do occasionally visit mainstream sessions, often remain invisible there as the standard mainstream session does not allow for much discussion. This separation has been further amplified by an evaluation system used by the AEA, which assigns future slots for sessions based on past attendance. This scheme creates an additional (and in my view unhelpful) incentive to stick in one's 'in- group' and abstain from interparadigmatic engagement (see also here5 for a specific criticism of this practice). By the way, the same incentive - stick with your in-group to maximize visibility for your own field or approach - emerges in the context of citation- based evaluation routines (see here6 for an elaboration). However, the ASSA is nonetheless a great to place to stay in touch with major debates in the profession and to find some potential insights and inspiration. Even if I cannot attend personally (as in this year; otherwise you would have gotten a more extended report:-), I always screen the contributions in the heterodox sessions, which can be quickly assessed here7 (Hint: You have to search of different heterdox associations first to not get lost - a compilation of these associations can be found here8 ).
    [Show full text]