Barter and Economic Disintegration Author(S): Caroline Humphrey Source: Man, New Series, Vol

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Barter and Economic Disintegration Author(S): Caroline Humphrey Source: Man, New Series, Vol Barter and Economic Disintegration Author(s): Caroline Humphrey Source: Man, New Series, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Mar., 1985), pp. 48-72 Published by: Royal Anthropological Institute of Great Britain and Ireland Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2802221 . Accessed: 17/10/2014 05:02 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Royal Anthropological Institute of Great Britain and Ireland is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Man. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 110.22.32.138 on Fri, 17 Oct 2014 05:02:16 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions BARTER AND ECONOMIC DISINTEGRATION CAROLINE HUMPHREY Universityof Cambridge The mainstreameconomists' view thatbarter should be seen as a 'natural'phenomenon of human natureand as the originof moneyis rejected.Barter occurs in specificsocio-economic conditionswhich may obtainalso in economieswhich know money.When thereis a verylow supply of currency,money may cease to functionas an index of value forall goods and itself become an item bartered.This is likely to occur when small discretesocial groups wish to maintainautonomy. Unlike moneypayment, which requires a furthertransaction before value is realised,barter satisfies demand immediatelyand is of its naturediscontinuous. As with car trade-insin our economybarter occurs when people cannotafford to keepmoney, and it becomes a systemwhen societyis atomised to the extentthat people do not exploit the variationsin exchangeratios between different communities. Using thecase ofthe Lhomi of north-east Nepal, it is shown thatalthough the exchange of commonproduce, as opposed to rarevaluables, is most likelyto approximateto a notional'equilibrium price', the practice of barterwith no established measuresof weight and volumemeans that there can be no underlyingindex of value /numeraire. Each transactionexists virtuallyon its own. Thus, althoughbarter is an egalitarianmode, it containsno protectionagainst changing exchange ratios which may harmone partner.Barter tendsto takeplace betweenpeople who know one another,because it is onlyby theestablishment of customarytimes and places forexchange that the costs of searchingfor partners, waiting etc. areavoided. Delayed barter,which often occurs with valuables, requires non-economic means of ensuringrepayment, but the ritualisedtrade-partnerships which the Lhomi employ are self- limiting:restricted relations cut tradersoff from the wide, unpredictableworld of the capitalist end sale. Businessoften fails and thetraders suffer. Barteris at once a cornerstoneof modern economic theoryand an ancient subjectof debate about politicaljustice, fromPlato and Aristotleonwards. In bothdiscourses, which are distinct though related, barter provides the imagined preconditionsfor the emergenceof money. Why should anthropologistsbe interestedin logical deductionsfrom an imaginedstate? No exampleof a barter economy,pure and simple,has ever been described,let alone the emergence fromit of money;all availableethnography suggests that there never has been sucha thing.But thereare economies today which are nevertheless dominated by barter,and hereanthropology can bothlearn from and add to theancient debate. In Plato, non-monetaryexchange provides the firstmeans of satisfying complementaryneeds established by thedivision of labour, which is a condition of the ideal Republic (Plato I908: II, 369-72). Aristotledevelops the idea of 'proportionalexchange', relative to social evaluationsof the worthof persons and theirproducts, in his considerationof whatis just. Here money,which can measureeverything, is introducedby conventionas a 'kind of substitutefor Man (N.S.) 20, 48-72 This content downloaded from 110.22.32.138 on Fri, 17 Oct 2014 05:02:16 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CAROLINE HUMPHREY 49 need or demand', its value being derived not from nature but from law (AristotleI895: 5, I-I7). Economistsof the contemporaryorthodoxy, on the otherhand, which stems at least fromAdam Smithand was revivedin the marginalisteconomics of Menger andJevons and reachesClower in thepresent, propose an evolutionarydevelopment of economieswhich places barter,as a 'natural'human characteristic, at themost primitive stage, to be supersededby monetaryexchange as soon as people become aware of the latter'sgreater efficiency. Anthropologistshave also tendedto see barteras a transactionof the primitive economy, although in the classic examples, such as Malinowski (I922), Thurnwald(I934-5) and Sahlins(I972) theethnographic diversity and com- plexityof distributionis recognised.Dominated by otheractivities considered to be 'more socially embedded', such as ceremonialexchange, gift-giving, sharingof food, or dues to chiefs,barter is foundin a cornerof the economy -and one that is despised by the people and anthropologistsalike. Barter, accordingto Sahlins summarisinga wide range of ethnography,is 'negative reciprocity,the unsociable extreme'. Characterised as 'haggling',barter is held to takeplace withoutsiders, along with'chicanery' and 'theft',each participant tryingto outwitthe other with an eye to his own benefit(I972: I95). There is somethingunsatisfactory about each of thesemodern arguments. If we take barterto be the more or less simultaneousexchange of one good for anotherwith the possibility of bargaining,the anthropologists have no justifi- cation in regardingit as 'negative reciprocity'.By definition,barter is a complementaryexchange in whicheach participantbargains until he or she is satisfied.It does not necessarilyimply antagonism. As faras the economists' argumentis concerned,we know fromthe accumulated evidence of ethnogra- phy that barter was indeed very rare as a system dominatingprimitive economies.' Money of variouskinds has been aroupd forover two millennia, and in thelast century,in its purest,non 'commodity-money'form, has pen- etratedvirtually every economy on earth,and yet barteris common todayin economieswhich also know money.I shallpropose in thisarticle that barter in thepresent world is, in thevast majorityof cases, a post-monetaryphenomenon (i.e. it coexistswith money),and thatit characteriseseconomies which are, or have become, de-coupled from monetarymarkets. In these circumstances bartercan become a dominantprinciple of transaction,to whichmoney itself is subject.As was well known to Marx and even Aristotle(I895: 5, 14), but has somehow escaped the generalattention of anthropologists,currency may be barteredlike any othercommodity. As an idea 'barter'is partof thehistory of economicsand anthropology,and theassumption that it was theforerunner of monetaryexchange is crucialin the way it is normallyconceptualised. Polanyi's suggestion, in Thegreat transform- ation,that the evolutionarydoctrine of the economistspreoccupied with the emergenceof marketsmight virtually be reversed,has been largelyignored (I957: 58).2 His own view is considerablycloser to thatof the ancientphil- osophers,suggesting as he does theprior existence of long-distancetrade as a resultof regionalenvironmental differences and only laterthe emergenceof local marketsand bargainingor barter.In thisarticle I shouldalso liketo escape This content downloaded from 110.22.32.138 on Fri, 17 Oct 2014 05:02:16 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 50 CAROLINE HUMPHREY fromthe notion of 'truck'or 'barter'as a naturalhuman propensity which still appearsas a mythof our subject.This impliesthe disentangling of two concepts of barter,(a) the notion of a simple exchangeof goods withoutmoney and without specifyingthe mode of the non-monetarytransaction, and (b) the processof barterin timeas a practicewhich involves bargaining. It is thelatter thatwill be my focus. The word barteras I use it impliesan open-ended,potentially innovative, negotiable,transaction, in whichneed not onlyanswers need but can also create a new demand: 'If you don't want thesepotatoes, perhaps you would like this pair of scissors?'Furthermore, barter, which in itselfrefers only to a social relationof transaction and not to economicvalues, can encompassthe idea ofan exchangeof goods whichhave one value to one side and anotherto theother. I use 'barter'in thissense to differentiateit from 'primitive trade' in which, as Malinowskishowed, sociallydetermined rates of exchangeoutweigh bargain- ing in thegreat majority of typesof transaction. For barterto become dominantin an area, such thatit can incorporateeven puremoney, we mustsuppose not only economic but also someparticular social and culturalconditions which allow the 'construction'of barteras a system.I shallattempt to describethis on thebasis of the economy of the Lhomi3 and their neighboursof the Nepal-Tibetborder in I979-80. The Lhomi are farmersbut also traders,and clearly theirhistorical role as intermediariesbetween the highlandpastoral economy of theTibet hillsand theagriculture of the Nepali hills,is a basis forthe cultureof tradingwhich they find so attractive.I would argue, however, thatit is not because the Lhomi were tradersthat they now engagein barter.Similar Himalayan peoples are now almostentirely
Recommended publications
  • Gifts and Commodities (Second Edition)
    GIFTS AND COMMODITIES Hau BOOKS Executive Editor Giovanni da Col Managing Editor Sean M. Dowdy Editorial Board Anne-Christine Taylor Carlos Fausto Danilyn Rutherford Ilana Gershon Jason Throop Joel Robbins Jonathan Parry Michael Lempert Stephan Palmié www.haubooks.com GIFTS AND COMMODITIES (SECOND EditIon) C. A. Gregory Foreword by Marilyn Strathern New Preface by the Author Hau Books Chicago © 2015 by C. A. Gregory and Hau Books. First Edition © 1982 Academic Press, London. All rights reserved. Cover and layout design: Sheehan Moore Typesetting: Prepress Plus (www.prepressplus.in) ISBN: 978-0-9905050-1-3 LCCN: 2014953483 Hau Books Chicago Distribution Center 11030 S. Langley Chicago, IL 60628 www.haubooks.com Hau Books is marketed and distributed by The University of Chicago Press. www.press.uchicago.edu Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper. For Judy, Polly, and Melanie. Contents Foreword by Marilyn Strathern xi Preface to the first edition xv Preface to the second edition xix Acknowledgments liii Introduction lv PART ONE: CONCEPTS I. THE COmpETING THEOriES 3 Political economy 3 The theory of commodities 3 The theory of gifts 9 Economics 19 The theory of modern goods 19 The theory of traditional goods 22 II. A framEWORK OF ANALYSIS 25 The general relation of production to consumption, distribution, and exchange 26 Marx and Lévi-Strauss on reproduction 26 A simple illustrative example 30 The definition of particular economies 32 viii GIFTS AND COMMODITIES III.FTS GI AND COMMODITIES: CIRCULATION 39 The direct exchange of things 40 The social status of transactors 40 The social status of objects 41 The spatial aspect of exchange 44 The temporal dimension of exchange 46 Value and rank 46 The motivation of transactors 50 The circulation of things 55 Velocity of circulation 55 Roads of gift-debt 57 Production and destruction 59 The circulation of people 62 Work-commodities 62 Work-gifts 62 Women-gifts 63 Classificatory kinship terms and prices 68 Circulation and distribution 69 IV.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Do the Indians Wear Adidas? Or, Culture Contact and the Relations of Consumption Richard R
    1984 Unpublished Article Why do the Indians Wear Adidas? Or, Culture Contact and the Relations of Consumption Richard R. Wilk and Eric J. Arnould Abstract Page 1 of 31 The study of the consumption of goods has never achieved the JBA 5(1): 6-36 prominence in anthropology of either production or exchange. Yet the Autumn 2016 accelerating consumption of western goods in non-western societies is © The Author(s) 2016 one of the most obtrusive cultural and economic trends of the last three ISSN 2245-4217 centuries. This article addresses the general issue of why goods flow www.cbs.dk/jba between cultural groups by re-examining the concept of consumption. It raises questions of importance to studies of development, material culture, ethnohistory, and symbolic anthropology. Keywords Economic anthropology, consumption, acculturation, symbolic anthropology, material culture Wilk and Arnould / Why do the Indians Wear Adidas? Introduction Peruvian Indians carry around small rectangular rocks painted to look like transistor radios.1 San Blas Cuna households hoard boxes of dolls, safety pins, children's hats and shoes, marbles, enamelware kettles, and bedsheets with pillowcases in their original cellophane wrappings. Japanese newlyweds cut three-tiered white frosted inedible cakes topped with plastic figures in western dress. Q’eqchi’ Maya swidden farmers relax at night listening to Freddie Fender on a portable cassette player while Bana tribesmen in Kako, Ethiopia, pay a hefty price to look through a Viewmaster at “Pluto Tries to Become a Circus Dog.” Tibetans, bitterly opposed to Chinese rule, sport Mao caps. Young Wayana Indians in Surinam spend hours manipulating a Rubik's cube.
    [Show full text]
  • Open Dissertation-Final-Bryan.Pdf
    The Pennsylvania State University The Graduate School College of the Liberal Arts NATURE AND THE NEW SOUTH: COMPETING VISIONS OF RESOURCE USE IN A DEVELOPING REGION, 1865-1929 A Dissertation in History by William D. Bryan 2013 William D. Bryan Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy August 2013 The dissertation of William D. Bryan was reviewed and approved* by the following: William A. Blair Liberal Arts Professor of American History Dissertation Advisor Chair of Committee Mark E. Neely McCabe Greer Professor in the American Civil War Era Solsiree Del Moral Assistant Professor of History Robert Burkholder Associate Professor of English Adam Rome Associate Professor of History and English The University of Delaware Special Member David G. Atwill Director of Graduate Studies in History *Signatures are on file in the Graduate School iii ABSTRACT This dissertation examines conflicting visions for natural resource use and economic development in the American South in the years between the end of the Civil War and the beginning of the Great Depression. Emancipation toppled the region’s economy and led many Southerners to try to establish a “New South” to replace their antebellum plantation society. Their task was unprecedented, and necessitated completely reimagining the economic structure of the entire region. Although most Southerners believed that the region was blessed with abundant natural resources, there were many competing ideas about how these resources should be used in order to achieve prosperity. By examining how these different visions shaped New South economic development, this dissertation reconsiders a longstanding interpretation of the postbellum American South, and provides a fresh historical perspective on the challenges of sustainable development in underdeveloped places worldwide.
    [Show full text]
  • Nomadic Pastoralism and Agricultural Modernization
    NOTES AND COMMENTS NOMADIC PASTORALISM AND AGRICULTURAL MODERNIZATION Robert Rice State University ofNew York INTRODUCTION This paper presents a model for the integration of pastoral nomads into nation-states. To this. end, two areas of the world in which pastoral nomadism had been predominent within historic times-Central Asia and West Africa-were examined. Security considerations tended to overshadow economic considerations in the formation of state policy toward nomadic peoples in the two areas. However, a broader trend, involving the expansion of the world economic system can also be discerned. This pattern held constant under both capitalistic and socialistic governments. In recent times, the settlement of pastoral nomads and their integration into national economies has become a hotly debated issue in a number of developing nations. Disasters such as the Sahel drought and famine in the early 1970s have brought world attention on the economic and ecological consequences of nomad­ ism and settlement. Similarly, armed uprisings by nomadic peoples against the governments of Morocco, Ethiopia, the Chad, Iran and Afghanistan have brought the politicalgrievances..0J nomads _ to world attention. This' paper will compare two attempts by modern nation states to transform the traditional economies of nomadic pastoralist Soviet Central Asia and West Africa. In both cases the development policies pursued by the central government sought to change the traditional power relationship within nomad­ ic society, as well as its economic activities. These policies were a natural outgrowth of attempts by the central governments in­ volved to integrate nomadic peoples into the larger world econ­ omy. Two schools of thought have emerged from the debate over the future of nomadic pastoralism.
    [Show full text]
  • Coaching the Global Nomad Katrina Burrus, PH.D., M.C.C
    Coaching the Global Nomad Katrina Burrus, PH.D., M.C.C. This article first appeared in the International Journal of Coaching in Organizations, 2006, 4(4),6-15. It can only be reprinted and distributed with prior written permission from Professional Coaching Publications, Inc. (PCPI). Email John Lazar at [email protected] for such permission. Journal information: www.ijco.info Purchases: www.pcpionline.com 2006 ISSN 1553-3735 © Copyright 2006 PCPI. All rights reserved worldwide. 6 | IJCO Issue 4 2006 6 | IJCO Issue 4 2006 Coaching the Global Nomad Coaching the Global Nomad KATRINA BURRUS, PH.D., M.C.C. KATRINA BURRUS, PH.D., M.C.C. Executives who work in various PROLOGUE – IN THE BEGINNING Executives who work in various PROLOGUE – IN THE BEGINNING cultures bring a multitude of cultural I was fiveyears old, playing on the living room couch, when my mother cultures bring a multitude of cultural I was fiveyears old, playing on the living room couch, when my mother backgrounds, identities, and called out to me from the kitchen that we were going to move again. backgrounds, identities, and called out to me from the kitchen that we were going to move again. orientations with them. They are Having already left the US, Italy, and then Germany, we were now orientations with them. They are Having already left the US, Italy, and then Germany, we were now called in to new situations because moving to Switzerland. My father started up a soft drink brand in Italy. called in to new situations because moving to Switzerland. My father started up a soft drink brand in Italy.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Wealth? What Is Wealth Creation and What Is Wealth Conversion?
    An essay to set the tone What is Wealth? What is Wealth Creation and what is Wealth Conversion? What is the relationship between Wealth and Technology? Wealth creation occurs when Matter and Energy and Intelligence are combined to enable humans to live better. Intelligence Wealth is a human value and humanity’s values change, based on circumstances. For nomads, wealth was livestock. The more sheep and cattle the tribe owned the richer they were. For the Haida Indians of the Pacific Northwest, where the food supply of fish and game was naturally abundant year Wealth round, wealth was the opposite. The richest person was the one who could give away the most in the potlatch ceremony. Matter Predation Energy Wealth conversion occurs when no value is added, but Pollution Poverty one party takes wealth created by another. It also occurs when wealth is created but someone else gets saddled with negative side effects such as predation, pollution or impoverishment. Strip mining where no land restoration occurs afterwards Let us agree that on earth reality consists of three comes to mind. When a warrior says to a farmer he will protect spheres: matter, energy and intelligence. him from another warrior who wants to steal the farmer’s On earth, matter is a closed system – all the matter food, both warriors are converting wealth. When a lawyer which exists has always been here, all we can do is convert it writes a contract to assure two parties will mutually create from one form to another. Earth holds 6 sextillion tons of more wealth, that clarity is wealth creating.
    [Show full text]
  • Sacredness in an Experimental Chamber
    BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29, 161–209 Printed in the United States of America Moneyastool,moneyasdrug:The biological psychology of a strong incentive Stephen E. G. Lea University of Exeter, School of Psychology, Washington Singer Laboratories, Exeter EX4 4QG, United Kingdom [email protected] http://www.exeter.ac.uk/SEGLea Paul Webley University of Exeter, School of Psychology, Washington Singer Laboratories, Exeter EX4 4QG, United Kingdom [email protected] http://www.exeter.ac.uk/pwebley Abstract: Why are people interested in money? Specifically, what could be the biological basis for the extraordinary incentive and reinforcing power of money, which seems to be unique to the human species? We identify two ways in which a commodity which is of no biological significance in itself can become a strong motivator. The first is if it is used as a tool, and by a metaphorical extension this is often applied to money: it is used instrumentally, in order to obtain biologically relevant incentives. Second, substances can be strong motivators because they imitate the action of natural incentives but do not produce the fitness gains for which those incentives are instinctively sought. The classic examples of this process are psychoactive drugs, but we argue that the drug concept can also be extended metaphorically to provide an account of money motivation. From a review of theoretical and empirical literature about money, we conclude that (i) there are a number of phenomena that cannot be accounted for by a pure Tool Theory of money motivation; (ii) supplementing Tool Theory with a Drug Theory enables the anomalous phenomena to be explained; and (iii) the human instincts that, according to a Drug Theory, money parasitizes include trading (derived from reciprocal altruism) and object play.
    [Show full text]
  • Women and the Gift Economy: Part 2
    II. GIFTS EXPLOITED BY THE MARKET CLAUDIA VON WERLHOF Capitalist Patriarchy and the Negation of Matriarchy The Struggle for a “Deep” Alternative In her important book, For-Giving: A Feminist Criticism of Exchange, Genevieve Vaughan states: “In order to reject patriarchal thinking we must be able to distin- guish between it and something else: an alternative” (1997: 23). I fully identify with this statement as I, too, have tried “to think outside patriarchy” although being inside it most of the time. At the “First World Congress of Matriarchal Studies,” held in Luxemburg in 2003, where Vaughan and I first met, she stated, “If we don’t understand society in which we live we cannot change it; we do not know where the exit is!” Therefore, “we have to dismantle patriarchy.” In this article, I would like to add to Vaughan’s analysis of capitalist patriarchy and tackle the task of dismantling patriarchy. “A Different World is Possible!” This has been the main slogan of the worldwide civilian movement against glo- balization for years. I have to add: “A radically different world is possible!”—it is not only possible but also urgently needed. But without a vision of this radically different world we will not be able to move in this direction. Therefore we need to discuss, first of all, a radically different worldview. For this purpose we have to analyze what is happening today and why. Only then will we be able to define a really different world, worldview and vision. “Globalization:” An Explanation A radically different worldview is necessary because today we are observing global social, economic, ecological, and political developments that are completely different from what they should be.
    [Show full text]
  • The Anthropology of Money
    ANRV287-AN35-02 ARI 13 August 2006 6:41 The Anthropology of Money Bill Maurer Department of Anthropology, University of California, Irvine, California 92697–5100; email: [email protected] Annu. Rev. Anthropol. 2006. 35:15–36 Key Words First published online as a Review in abstraction, commensuration, currency, finance, number, Advance on July 6, 2006 quantification The Annual Review of Anthropology is by University of California - Irvine on 09/21/06. For personal use only. online at anthro.annualreviews.org Abstract This article’s doi: This review surveys anthropological and other social research on Annu. Rev. Anthropol. 2006.35:15-36. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org 10.1146/annurev.anthro.35.081705.123127 money and finance. It emphasizes money’s social roles and meanings Copyright c 2006 by Annual Reviews. as well as its pragmatics in different modalities of exchange and circu- All rights reserved lation. It reviews scholarly emphasis on modern money’s distinctive 0084-6570/06/1021-0015$20.00 qualities of commensuration, abstraction, quantification, and reifi- cation. It also addresses recent work that seeks to understand the social, semiotic, and performative dimensions of finance. Although anthropology has contributed finely grained, historicized accounts of the impact of modern money, it too often repeats the same story of the “great transformation” from socially embedded to disembedded and abstracted economic forms. This review speculates about why money’s fictions continue to surprise. 15 ANRV287-AN35-02 ARI 13 August 2006 6:41 INTRODUCTION: THE COIN’S The difficulty in reviewing the anthropol- MANY SIDES ogy of money is compounded by the reliance of much anthropological research on theories A special difficulty arises when reviewing the of meaning and symbol that derived analyt- anthropology of money.
    [Show full text]
  • Downloaded From
    J. Alexander P. Alexander Commodification and consumption in a central Borneo community In: Bijdragen tot de Taal-, Land- en Volkenkunde 151 (1995), no: 2, Leiden, 179-193 This PDF-file was downloaded from http://www.kitlv-journals.nl Downloaded from Brill.com10/02/2021 07:02:47PM via free access JENNIFER ALEXANDER AND PAUL ALEXANDER Commodification and Consumption in a Central Borneo Community A long-established tradition of explanation in anthropology and social history has seen money as the principal mechanism promoting individu- alism and greed, and consequently subverting values of community. When money enters a society, so the argument runs, commodification rapidly follows, initially altering consumption patterns and later transforming pro- duction relationships as well. In one recent formulation, money conquers the internal economy of non-monetized societies, setting free the 'drive inherent in every exchange system towards optimum commoditization' (Kopytoff 1986:72). Other anthropological studies, however, suggest that this view of the association between monetization and commoditization is far too simple; when they have had the power to do so, non-industrialized communities have demonstrated a remarkable ability to domesticate money and to resist any presumption that equality in price is equivalent to equal- ity in value (e.g., Parry and Bloch 1989; Humphrey and Hugh-Jones 1992). This essay is concerned with the ways in which a relatively remote and very small Central Borneo community, that of the Lahanan, has responded to its increasingly rapid incorporation into the world system. The speed and the extent of changes, more often than not initiated from outside, are undeniable. In the past thirty years, new forms of political power have been established; new medical, educational and, to a much lesser degree, agricultural services have been welcomed; and some parts of the economy have been commodified.
    [Show full text]
  • Nomadism, Evolution and World-Systems: Pastoral Societies in Theories of Historical Development
    Nomadism, Evolution and World-Systems: Pastoral Societies in Theories of Historical Development Nikolay N. Kradin INTRODUCTION n the modern social sciences and history, there are four groups of theories that Ivariously explain basic principles of origin, further change and, sometimes, collapse of complex human social systems. Th e fi rst of these groups is the vari- ous unilinear theories of development or evolution (Marxism, neoevolutionism, modernization theories etc.). Th ey show how humanity has evolved from local groups of primitive hunters to the modern post-industrial world society. Th e second ones are theories of civilizations. Th e proponents of these theories argue that there is no unifi ed world history. Rather there are separate clusters of cul- tural activity that constitute qualitatively diff erent civilizations. Th e civilizations, like living organisms, are born, live and die (Spengler 1918; Toynbee 1934 etc.). Th e world-systems perspective and multilinear theories of social evolution are intermediate between these poles. Th e world-system approach (Wallerstein 1974 etc.; Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997; Sanderson 1999 etc.), like unilinear theo- ries of development distinguish three models of society: mini-systems, world- empires and world-economies. But they are considered in space rather than in time. Th is makes the conceptualisation of history more complete. Th e modern multilinear theories (Bondarenko and Korotayev 2000; Korotaev, Kradin, de Munk, Lynsha 2000 etc.) suppose that there are several possible paths of socio-political transformation. Some of these can lead to complexity, e.g. from a chiefdom to a true state; while others suppose the existence of the supercomplex community without a bureaucracy (e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • 314131983.Pdf
    Economic Anthropology History, Ethl:)ography, Critique Chris Han� and Keith Hart 'I Dolity ' II ' I I Copyright© Chris Hann and Keith Hart 2011 The right of Chris Hann and Keith Hart to be identified as Authors ofthis Work has been asserted in accordance with the UK Copyright, Designs and Patents Act Contents 1988. First published in 2011 by Polity Press Reprinted in 2011 Polity Press 65 Bridge Street Cambridge CB2 1 UR, UK Polity Press Preface lX 350 Main Street Malden, MA 02148, USA 1 Introduction: Economic Anthropology 1 3 All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purpose Some Issues of Method 'r of criticism and review, no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored 'I 6 :,1, The Human Economy in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, Critical Anthropology 9 mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission Organization of the Book 15 of the publisher. 2 Economy from the Ancient World to the Age of the ISBN-13: 978-0-7456-4482-0 Internet 18 ISBN-13: 978-0-7456-4483-7(pb) 'I 1 8 I, Economy as Household Management Medieval and Early Modern Roots of Economic A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. Theory 20 24 Typeset in 11 on 13 pt Sabon The Rise of Political Economy by Servis Filmsetting Ltd, Stockport, Cheshire The Economic Anthropology of Karl Marx 27 Printed and bound in the United States by Odyssey Press Inc., Gonic, New Hampshire National Capitalism and Beyond 29 Conclusion 34 The publisher has used its best endeavours to ensure that the URLs for external 3 The Rise of Modern Economics and Anthropology 37 websites referred to in this book are correct and active at the time of going to The German Tradition 39 press.
    [Show full text]