We Agree That Statistical Significance Proves Essentially Nothing: a Rejoinder to Thomas Mayer

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

We Agree That Statistical Significance Proves Essentially Nothing: a Rejoinder to Thomas Mayer Discuss this article at Journaltalk: http://journaltalk.net/articles/5791 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 10(1) January 2013: 97-107 We Agree That Statistical Significance Proves Essentially Nothing: A Rejoinder to Thomas Mayer Stephen T. Ziliak1 and Deirdre N. McCloskey2 LINK TO ABSTRACT We are happy to reply a second time to Tom Mayer, and are flattered that he has devoted so much time to our book. Long before most readers here were born, Professor Mayer was already making major contributions to economics—as recognized by a festschrift in his honor (Hoover and Sheffrin, eds., 1996). Mayer (2012, 2013) strongly agrees with us on four of the five major claims we make in our book about the theory and practice of significance. We are not surprised. As we noted in Ziliak and McCloskey (2004a, b), in reply to other critics from Graham Elliott and Clive Granger (2004) to Jeffrey Wooldridge (2004), Edward Leamer (2004), and Arnold Zellner (2004), leading econometricians find on reflection that they agree with our points, and realize with us that most of modern econometrics has to be redone, focusing on economic significance and not on mere statistical sig- nificance. So we have been saying since 1985 (McCloskey 1985). Mayer limits his complaints to certain aspects of theoretical and empirical claims we make about significance testing in economics, in the 1990s American Economic Review. He is ignoring, for example, Ziliak’s archival work, especially on William Sealy Gosset and Ronald A. Fisher, and our chapters on the 20th century history, philosophy, sociology, and practice of significance testing in the life and human sciences, from agronomy to zoology and from Gosset to Joshua Angrist (Ziliak and McCloskey 2008, chs. 1, 6-7, 16-24). We wish Mayer took a wider view. 1. Roosevelt University, Chicago, IL 60605. 2. University of Illinois at Chicago, 60607. VOLUME 10, NUMBER 1, JANUARY 2013 97 ZILIAK AND MCCLOSKEY Our complaints about statistical significance have been routine in other fields for a century, and are not “sweeping claims” (Mayer 2013, 87). It is quite mistaken, as Mayer asserts without citation, “that [our] point has also been criticized repeatedly for an equally long time” (88). No, it has not been. No one has refuted our central theses, not ever. In several dozen journal reviews and in comments we have received—from, for example, four Nobel lau- reates, the statistician Dennis Lindley (2012), the mathematician Olle Häggström (2010), the sociologist Steve Fuller (2008), and the historian Theodore Porter (2008)—no one, Tom Mayer included, has tried to actually defend null hypothesis significance testing. True, people sometimes express anger. Given the large impli- cations for science and policy, we understand. But no one has offered real arguments. We praised Kevin Hoover and Mark Siegler (2008) for attempting to use significance tests in step-wise fashion, that is, as a mechanical screening device for sorting possibly important from unimportant relationships (McCloskey and Ziliak 2008, 46-47). But they fumbled the ball, and for the same reason that Mayer (2013, 94) does and must: statistical significance does not and cannot do the job of interpretation and decision-making. But the main point here is that Mayer mostly agrees with us. We are in fact in complete agreement about four of the five major claims we make in The Cult of Statistical Significance (Ziliak and McCloskey 2008, passim): 1.) Economic significance is not the same thing as statistical significance: Each can exist without the other—without, that is, either the presence or the prospect of the other—though economists often confuse and conflate the two kinds of significance. Mayer agrees. As he admits in his second assessment of our work by quoting his first assessment: But, far from supporting the orthodox view of significance tests I wrote: “Z-M are right…one must guard against substituting statistical for sub- stantive significance…. They are also right in criticizing the wrong-way- round use of significance tests” ([Mayer 2012,] 278), and that in tests of maintained hypotheses the latter error “is both severe enough and occurs frequently enough to present a serious—and inexcusable— problem” (279). (Mayer 2013, 88) 2.) Economists allocate far more time, space, and legitimacy to calculating statisticalstatistical significance than to exploring what they should: economiceconomic signif- icance. 98 VOLUME 10, NUMBER 1, JANUARY 2013 REJOINDER TO MAYER Mayer agrees: “[I]n countering the mechanical way in which significance tests are often used, and in introducing economists to the significance-test literature in other fields, Z-M have rendered valuable services” (Mayer 2012, 279, quoted in Mayer 2013, 88). A few pages on, he goes further, fixing on the main point of our agreement: “M-Z claim that a significance test is ‘not answering the scientific or policy or other human question at issue’…. Yes, I agree” (Mayer 2013, 90). 3.) The probability of the hypothesis given the available evidence is not equal to the probability of the evidence assuming the null hypothesis is true. Thus the null hypothesis test procedure is illogical in its primitives, equations, and conclusions. The illogic of the test is an example of what is known as the fallacy of the transposed conditional. Mayer again agrees, in this case with mere logic and common sense. As he said both in his first assessment of our work and in the current reply: “They [Z-M] are also right in criticizing the wrong-way-round use of significance tests” (Mayer 2012, 278, quoted in Mayer 2013, 88 and 93; see also Mayer 2012, 271). The null test of significance is illogical because it measures the probability of the evidence assuming a true null hypothesis but then pretends to answer a much more important question: the probability of the hypothesis, given the new evidence. Thus economists do not know the probability of their hypotheses. 4.) Assessing probabilities of hypotheses (Bayesian, classical, and other), comparing expected loss functions, and demonstrating substantive signifi- cance ought to be the central activities in applied econometrics and in most other statistical sciences. Here again, Mayer agrees. “M-Z criticize my argument ([Mayer 2012,] 264, third paragraph) that a variable may be important regardless of its oomph. In this they are right; my argument was muddled, and I withdraw it with apologies to the readers” (2013, 91). In other words, Mayer agrees that statistical signifi- cance—though conventional and even required by modern institutions of science, politics, and finance—is a dangerously broken instrument, one that in most cases needs to be put back on the shelf. Statistical significance proves nothing. Let’s get back to science. End of story, off to the pub. With such overlap in our positions the impartial spectator will begin to suspect that the remaining differences could be not very important ones. But Mayer hesitates, perhaps out of an admirable loyalty to other economic scientists, such as Kevin Hoover and Aris Spanos. He persists in trying to defend another side of the story, as though there was one, kicking at a horse that has long been dead, as Thomas Schelling (2004) has noted. Then he falls back into the main and highly ubiquitous confusion, which our work has sought to repair. Mayer (2013, 89-90) VOLUME 10, NUMBER 1, JANUARY 2013 99 ZILIAK AND MCCLOSKEY offers a hypothetical test of y > x in 98 cases out of 100 as evidence of a “significant difference.” Wait a minute. Suppose y was 4.2 and x was 4.1 and there was no scientific or policy reason to care about a difference of 0.1. “A binomial sign test does tell us something,” he writes (90). Yes, but it does not tell us that a difference is im- portant, which is overwhelmingly the scientific point at issue, a point which Mayer elsewhere understands and accepts. 5.) Applying our 19-item questionnaire to all of the 187 full-length empirical articles published in the 1990s in the AmericanAmericanEconomicEconomicReviewReview, we find that about 80% of economists made the significance mistake, equating statistical significance with economic importance, and lack of statistical significance with unimportance. Mayer (2012, 279) agrees that the error is “inexcusable” but he disagrees with our estimate (2013, abs. and 93). Notice that of the five main claims we make in The Cult, the only real difference of opinion between Mayer and us is not a difference in kind but of degree. This makes our point rather well that quantitative oomph, not a qualitative statement that p < .05, is the main point of science. Mayer did not conduct a replication of our survey of significance testing in American Economic Review articles from the 1990s. Neither did he attempt to replicate our survey of 182 articles published in the same journal during the 1980s (Ziliak and McCloskey 2008, chs. 6-7; Ziliak and McCloskey 2004a, b; McCloskey and Ziliak 1996). He did not use our survey at all. And yet he expresses discontent with the estimate that emerges from our application of our survey to the pages of the AER. We find, to repeat, that 80% or more of our colleagues who published in the AER in the 1990s made the significance mistake—the mistake of not under- standing claim number (1) above—causing incorrect decisions about models, vari- ables, and actual economies. Mayer says he disagrees. We do not accept his alleged evidence, but even if we did we do not believe that a failure rate of 20% (his lower bound) or of 50% (his upper bound), though lower than the 80% rate we found, would be cause for jubilation. A 50% failure rate in significance testing would still be akin to choosing hypotheses, estimates, and economic policies on the basis of random coin-flipping.
Recommended publications
  • Foreword Jack Reardon
    Int. J. Pluralism and Economics Education, Vol. 6, No. 1, 2015 1 Foreword Jack Reardon Department of Management and Economics, School of Business, Hamline University, 1536 Hewitt Avenue, MS-A1740, St. Paul, MN 55104-1284, USA Email: [email protected] 1 A look back at the first five volumes of the IJPEE It is a pleasure to begin the sixth volume of the International Journal of Pluralism and Economics Education. Looking back on our first five volumes, we published 141 articles in 19 issues, with authors from 31 nations, including: the USA, Canada, Great Britain, Ireland, Germany, France, Austria, Denmark, Norway, Sweden, Belgium, Italy, the Netherlands, Switzerland, Greece, Portugal, Latvia, Romania, Russia, China, India, Australia, New Zealand, Pakistan, Mexico, Brazil, Colombia, Taiwan, Thailand and Malaysia. I am particularly proud that the IJPEE has given voice to authors in developing nations. In our first five volumes, we published four special issues: 1 implementing a new curriculum for economics after the crisis – a call for action 2 economics education in India 3 contending perspectives: 20 years out: what have our students learned? 4 Marx and Marxism: still relevant after the crisis. We also published special sections and/or symposia on the following topics: economics education in China; the Eurozone; sustainable development and economic growth; the environment; challenging economic icons; money, banking and the financial crisis; measurement and conception in economics; and institutional economics. The IJPEE has published articles by authors representing every school of thought in economics; and in addition, we have published authors from sociology, anthropology, psychology, physics, mathematics, management and finance.
    [Show full text]
  • The Statistical Legacy of William Sealy Gosset (“Student”)
    cdh Volume 25 Number 4 December 2008 Community Dental Health In this issue Effect of tooth loss on quality of life amongst the elderly in Sri Lanka Caries levels amongst teenagers in Milan, Italy Access to dental services for people with a physical disability in the UK The journal of the British Association for the Study of Community Dentistry and the European Association Published by of Dental Public Health FDI World Dental Press Ltd Community Dental Health Volume 25 Number 4 December 2008 Editorial 194 Original Communications Effect of tooth loss and denture status on oral health-related quality of life of older individuals from Sri Lanka C. Pallegedara and L. Ekanayake 196 The distribution of general dental practitioners with NHS contract numbers in relation to the distance of their practices from the seven dental undergraduate teaching hospitals in England outside London R. J. McCormick, R. Smith, D. Edwards, D. White and J. Langford 201 Evaluation of oral health-related quality of life questionnaires in a general child population L.G. Do and A. J. Spencer 205 Retention and effectiveness of fissure sealants in Kuwaiti school children R. Francis, A.K. Mascarenhas, P. Soparkar and S. Al-Mutawaa 211 Loss of sealant retention and subsequent caries development in a mobile dental clinic S. Tianviwat, V. Chongsuvivatwong and B. Sirisakulveroj 216 Oral health and treatment needs among 15-year-olds in Tehran, Iran R. Yazdani, M.M. Vehkalahti, M. Nouri and H. Murtomaa 221 The frequency of periodontal infrabony defects on panoramic radiographs of an adult population seeking dental care N.
    [Show full text]
  • Is There Life After Samuelson's Economics? Changing the Textbooks
    Is There Life after Samuelson’s Economics? Changing the Textbooks by Arjo Klamer, Deirdre McCloskey, and Stephen Ziliak forthcoming Post Autistic Economics Review May 2007 Obviously, yes. Samuelson's text, imitated now in literally hundreds of versions since 1948, is only the most recent model, each with roughly a sixty-year reign. Before Samuelson came Marshall’s Principles. And before that Mill’s Principles, and before that The Wealth of Nations. It's been sixty years since Samuelson. With most of our colleagues in the Post-Autistic Economics community, we believe it's time to change. Mainstream economics—or as we prefer here to call it, “Samuelsonian economics”—has reached sharply diminishing returns. Economics and its many hundreds of knock-offs are not suited to the needs of the current generation. Nowhere is the defensive scientific posture of Samuelsonian economics more evident than in today’s introductory textbooks. Economics is a plurality of conversations, but with a few honorable exceptions today’s textbooks don't deign to mention the fact. The actual economic conversation is heterogeneous. Yet the textbooks are startlingly homogeneous. The actual economic conversation is conducted by feminists and libertarians, empirical Marxists and postmodern Keynesians, historical institutionalists and mathematical Samuelsonians. But most of today’s textbooks teach Samuelsonianism pure and simple, period. They are dogmatic, one voiced, unethical. At bottom the monological textbooks are hostile to the student: "Enter our restricted version of economics, oh ye pathetic undergraduate, or be damned!" In The Economic Conversation we're trying a new approach.i We want to produce a book that reflects the actual conversation of economics, Samuelsonian to Post-Autistic.
    [Show full text]
  • Reply to Deirdre Mccloskey and Stephen Ziliak on Statistical Significance
    Discuss this article at Journaltalk: http://journaltalk.net/articles/5790 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 10(1) January 2013: 87-96 Reply to Deirdre McCloskey and Stephen Ziliak on Statistical Significance Thomas Mayer1 LINK TO ABSTRACT Deirdre McCloskey and Stephen Ziliak (2012) have graciously replied to my essay titled “Ziliak and McCloskey on Statistical Significance: An Assessment” (Mayer 2012). McCloskey and Ziliak’s (M-Z) criticisms can be grouped into fourteen points. I will discuss them in the sequence that M-Z do. Page references, unless otherwise indicated, are to M-Z’s reply, or to my paper. 1. M-Z say that although I got it right in 1980 I have now “reverted to an erroneous, pre-1980 understanding” (298). I am not aware of such a change. On re-reading my 1980 article (which devoted only one page to significance tests), I do not see the large difference between the “old Tom” and the “new Tom” that M- Z see, though I did make two points in 1980 that I omitted in 2012. One is that statistics courses warn students about the wrong-way-round use of significance tests; the other is that for some reason significance tests are not used in maximum likelihood methods to see whether the regression that gives the best fit is really better than another regression that attributes a very different value to the strategic coefficient. But, all in all, my 1980 paper is no closer than is my 2012 paper to Ziliak and McCloskey’s sweeping claims in The Cult of Statistical Significance (2008).
    [Show full text]
  • Carmen Elena Dorobăţ
    THE JOURNAL OF PHILOSOPHICAL ECONOMICS: REFLECTIONS ON ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL ISSUES Volume VIII Issue 2 Spring 2015 ISSN 1843-2298 Copyright note: No part of these works may be reproduced in any form without permission from the publisher, except for the quotation of brief passages in criticism. A brief history of international trade thought: from pre-doctrinal contributions to the 21st century heterodox international economics Carmen Elena Dorobăţ A brief history of international trade thought: from pre-doctrinal contributions to the 21st century heterodox international economics Carmen Elena Dorobăț Abstract: The present paper outlines the development of international trade thought, from the pre-doctrinal contributions of Greek philosophers and scholastic theologians, through the theories of the first schools of economic thought, and up to modern and contemporary trade theories. I follow filiations of ideas in a chronological order, and show how theoretical investigation into the causes and effects of international trade—and the rationale for government intervention—has evolved over the last two centuries. Keywords: international trade, history of economic thought Introduction For centuries, international trade in goods and services, and the development of the international division of labor have constituted a focus point of study for economists and philosophers alike. Research in this field usually revolves around three main lines of inquiry (Wu 2007): (a) what are the causes of international trade? (b) what are the effects of international trade?, and given these two aspects, (c) is government intervention in international trade necessary or beneficial? Broadly speaking, the first two questions belong to economic theory, while the latter is concerned with economic and trade policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Ziliak and Mccloskey's Criticisms of Significance Tests
    Discuss this article at Journaltalk: http://journaltalk.net/articles/5775 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 9(3) September 2012: 256-297 Ziliak and McCloskey’s Criticisms of Significance Tests: An Assessment Thomas Mayer1 LINK TO ABSTRACT If economists have natural constants, then the most well-known is 0.05. —Hugo Keuzenkamp and Jan Magnus (1995, 16) Significance tests are standard operating procedures in empirical economics and other behavioral sciences. They are also widely used in medical research, where the prevalence of small samples makes them particularly welcome. And—mainly in the form of error bars—they are also at home in the physical sciences (see Horowitz 2004). But they have many critics, particularly among psychologists, who have done much more work on the topic than have economists.2 Some members of the American Psychological Association even tried to ban their use in all journals published by the Association. That proposal was easily defeated, but some of the editors of those journals moved on their own to discourage significance tests, although with little effect; significance tests still reign in psychology. In medical research, however, the critics appear to have had considerable influence.3 1. University of California, Davis, Davis, CA 95616. I am indebted for excellent comments to Kevin Hoover and Deirdre McCloskey and to three outstanding referees for this journal. An earlier version was presented at the 2010 meeting of the Society of Government Economists. 2. For telling quotations from critics see Johnson (1999). 3. Fidler et al. (2004b, 626) explain the spread of the reform in part by a shift from testing to estimation that was facilitated by the medical literature, unlike psychology, using a common measurement scale, to “strictly enforced editorial policy, virtually simultaneous reforms in a number of leading journals, and the timely re-writing [of] textbooks to fit with policy recommendations.” But their description of the process suggests that an accidental factor, the coincidence of several strong-willed editors, also mattered.
    [Show full text]
  • September 2010
    THE ISBA BULLETIN Vol. 17 No. 3 September 2010 The official bulletin of the International Society for Bayesian Analysis AMESSAGE FROM THE membership renewal (there will be special provi- PRESIDENT sions for members who hold multi-year member- ships). Peter Muller¨ The Bayesian Nonparametrics Section (IS- ISBA President, 2010 BA/BNP) is already up and running, and plan- [email protected] ning the 2011 BNP workshop. Please see the News from the World section in this Bulletin First some sad news. In August we lost two and our homepage (select “business” and “mee- big Bayesians. Julian Besag passed away on Au- tings”). gust 6, and Arnold Zellner passed away on Au- gust 11. Arnold was one of the founding ISBA ISBA/SBSS Educational Initiative. Jointly presidents and was instrumental to get Bayesian with ASA/SBSS (American Statistical Associa- started. Obituaries on this issue of the Analysis tion, Section on Bayesian Statistical Science) we Bulletin and on our homepage acknowledge Juli- launched a new joint educational initiative. The an and Arnold’s pathbreaking contributions and initiative formalized a long standing history of their impact on the lives of many people in our collaboration of ISBA and ASA/SBSS in related research community. They will be missed dearly! matters. Continued on page 2. ISBA Elections 2010. Please check out the elec- tion statements of the candidates for the upco- In this issue ming ISBA elections. We have an amazing slate ‰ A MESSAGE FROM THE BA EDITOR of candidates. Thanks to the nominating commit- *Page 2 tee, Mike West (chair), Renato Martins Assuncao,˜ Jennifer Hill, Beatrix Jones, Jaeyong Lee, Yasuhi- ‰ 2010 ISBA ELECTION *Page 3 ro Omori and Gareth Robert! ‰ SAVAGE AWARD AND MITCHELL PRIZE 2010 *Page 8 Sections.
    [Show full text]
  • Significance Redux
    The Journal of Socio-Economics 33 (2004) 665–675 Significance redux Stephen T. Ziliaka,∗, Deirdre N. McCloskeyb,1 a School of Policy Studies, College of Arts and Sciences, Roosevelt University, Chicago, 430 S. Michigan Avenue, Chicago, IL 60605, USA b College of Arts and Science (m/c 198), University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan, Chicago, IL 60607-7104, USA Abstract Leading theorists and econometricians agree with our two main points: first, that economic sig- nificance usually has nothing to do with statistical significance and, second, that a supermajority of economists do not explore economic significance in their research. The agreement from Arrow to Zellner on the two main points should by itself change research practice. This paper replies to our critics, showing again that economic significance is what science and citizens want and need. © 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. JEL CODES: C12; C10; B23; A20 Keywords: Hypothesis testing; Statistical significance; Economic significance Science depends on entrepreneurship, and we thank Morris Altman for his. The sympo- sium he has sparked can be important for the future of economics, in showing that the best economists and econometricians seek, after all, economic significance. Kenneth Arrow as early as 1959 dismissed mechanical tests of statistical significance in his search for eco- nomic significance. It took courage: Arrow’s teacher, the amazing Harold Hotelling, had been one of Fisher’s sharpest disciples. Now Arrow is joined by Clive Granger, Graham ∗ Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (S.T. Ziliak), [email protected] (D.N. McCloskey). 1 For comments early and late we thank Ted Anderson, Danny Boston, Robert Chirinko, Ronald Coase, Stephen Cullenberg, Marc Gaudry, John Harvey, David Hendry, Stefan Hersh, Robert Higgs, Jack Hirshleifer, Daniel Klein, June Lapidus, David Ruccio, Jeff Simonoff, Gary Solon, John Smutniak, Diana Strassman, Andrew Trigg, and Jim Ziliak.
    [Show full text]
  • Keukentafel Economics and the History of British Imperialism
    Forthcoming South African Economic History Review Keukentafel Economics and the History of British Imperialism Deirdre McCloskey Economics, History, English, and Communication, University of Illinois at Chicago Philosophy and Art and Cultural Studies, Erasmus University of Rotterdam I visited South Africa for the first time in September of 2006, thanks to Grietjie Verhoef and a great number of hosts around the country, for nearly two and a half weeks.1 In that time I watched some South African TV in English, and when English subtitles were provided I could follow the Afrikaans soap operas, too, noting the interesting contrasts with Dutch. I spoke at some length about the country with a couple of dozen South Africans. I read hurriedly most of Robert Ross’ Concise History of South Africa and some of Leonard Thompson’s A History of South Africa, as well as certain relevant parts of the Lonely Planet’s travel guide to South Africa. On Professor Verhoef’s recommendation I bought and read Robert Guest’s The Shackled Continent. And I have least bought Nelson Mandella’s autobiography, and some poetry in Afrikaans. You can add to this impressive scholarly activity a long acquaintance with certain Africanists, such as with Ralph Austen at the University of Chicago, who was a colleague of mine for twelve years, and with Phil Curtin at Johns Hopkins, whose former wife was an opera singer with my mother. I attended in 1974 a famous conference on the slave trade at Colby College in which the only black person in attendance, a Nigerian historian, was roundly attacked by Phil.
    [Show full text]
  • December 2000
    THE ISBA BULLETIN Vol. 7 No. 4 December 2000 The o±cial bulletin of the International Society for Bayesian Analysis A WORD FROM already lays out all the elements mere statisticians might have THE PRESIDENT of the philosophical position anything to say to them that by Philip Dawid that he was to continue to could possibly be worth ISBA President develop and promote (to a listening to. I recently acted as [email protected] largely uncomprehending an expert witness for the audience) for the rest of his life. defence in a murder appeal, Radical Probabilism He is utterly uncompromising which revolved around a Modern Bayesianism is doing in his rejection of the realist variant of the “Prosecutor’s a wonderful job in an enormous conception that Probability is Fallacy” (the confusion of range of applied activities, somehow “out there in the world”, P (innocencejevidence) with supplying modelling, data and in his pragmatist emphasis P ('evidencejinnocence)). $ analysis and inference on Subjective Probability as Contents procedures to nourish parts that something that can be measured other techniques cannot reach. and regulated by suitable ➤ ISBA Elections and Logo But Bayesianism is far more instruments (betting behaviour, ☛ Page 2 than a bag of tricks for helping or proper scoring rules). other specialists out with their What de Finetti constructed ➤ Interview with Lindley tricky problems – it is a totally was, essentially, a whole new ☛ Page 3 original way of thinking about theory of logic – in the broad ➤ New prizes the world we live in. I was sense of principles for thinking ☛ Page 5 forcibly struck by this when I and learning about how the had to deliver some brief world behaves.
    [Show full text]
  • Balanced Versus Randomized Field Experiments in Economics: Why W
    Balanced versus Randomized Field Experiments in Economics: Why W. S. Gosset aka “Student” Matters By Stephen T. Ziliak1 Abstract: Over the past decade randomized field experiments have gained prominence in the toolkit of empirical economics and policy making. In an article titled "Field Experiments in Economics: The Past, the Present, and the Future," Levitt and List (2009) make three main claims about the history, philosophy, and future of field experiments in economics. They claim that field experiments in economics began in the 1920s and 1930s in agricultural work by Neyman and Fisher. Second, they claim that artificial randomization is essential for good experimental design because, they claim, randomization is the only valid justification for Student's test of significance. Finally, they claim that decision-making in private sector firms will be advanced by partnering with economists doing randomized experiments. Several areas of research have been influenced by the article despite the absence of historical and methodological review. This paper seeks to fill that gap in the literature. The power and efficiency of balanced over random designs - discovered by William S. Gosset aka Student, and confirmed by Pearson, Neyman, Jeffreys, and others adopting a balanced, decision-theoretic and/or Bayesian approach to experiments, is not mentioned in the Levitt and List article. Neglect of Student is regrettable. A body of evidence descending from Student (1911) and extending to Heckman and Vytlacil (2007) suggests that artificial randomization is neither necessary nor sufficient for improving efficiency, identifying causal relationships, and discovering economically significant differences. Three easy ways to improve field experiments are proposed and briefly illustrated.
    [Show full text]
  • Model: Mccloskey and the Craft of Economics
    Department of Economics Working Paper Series A ‘Model’ Model: McCloskey and the Craft of Economics Joshua C. Hall Working Paper No. 17-09 This paper can be found at the College of Business and Economics Working Paper Series homepage: http://business.wvu.edu/graduate-degrees/phd-economics/working-papers A “Model” Model: McCloskey and the Craft of Economics Joshua C. Hall Associate Professor of Economics Director, Center for Free Enterprise College of Business and Economics West Virginia University Morgantown, WV 26505-6025 [email protected] Abstract In this essay, I highlight some of the contributions of Deirdre McCloskey to the practice of economics as a teacher and scholar. I highlight her influence on my teaching and scholarship in the areas of economic education and economic freedom. JEL Codes: A00; A11; A23; B31 Keywords: rhetoric; economic freedom; storytelling Acknowledgements: This essay is based in part on comments made in honor of Deirdre McCloskey at a panel discussion on “The Ideas and Influence of Deirdre Nansen McCloskey, II” at Beloit College on November 3, 2016. A “Model” Model: McCloskey and the Craft of Economics 1 Introduction Deirdre Nansen McCloskey has made tremendous contributions to our understanding of the wealth and well-being of nations through both her teaching and scholarship. In thinking about how her work has influenced my own, I have to admit it was difficult to know where to begin given the breadth of her scholarship. Should I start with her work on open fields and enclosure in England that helped
    [Show full text]