The Crazy Curse and Crude Domination: Toward an Anthropology of Oil

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Crazy Curse and Crude Domination: Toward an Anthropology of Oil The crazy curse and crude domination: Toward an anthropology of oil Stephen Reyna and Andrea Behrends Abstract: Oil has turned out to be something of a curse. Most developing petro- states have found that their economies have worsened, their political regimes have become more authoritarian, and their conflicts have intensified. Further, this curse is a bit crazy because oil brings wealth, which would seem to bring peace and pros- perity, not the trouble that so often accompanies it. The goal of this introduction is to propose a research strategy for the anthropological analysis of oil. It does so by examining existing oil literatures, discussing the implications for research aris- ing from the articles contained here, and, finally, formulating an anthropology of oil in a turbulent world. This formulation proposes a ‘crude domination’ approach to explain oil’s crazy curse. Keywords: anthropology of oil, development, conflict, domination approach, Africa, Latin America The oil price is very high, it’s crazy. There is no additional supply. —Pumomo Yusgiantoro, OPEC president, in 2004 Immanuel Wallerstein has written of a “system- Alan Greenspan, former chairman of the U.S. ic crisis” that he believes will produce “disinte- Federal Reserve, respected elder statesman of U.S. gration of our existing historical social system” finance, and an architect of neoliberal global- within twenty-five to fifty years (1997: 1256)— ism, has written The age of turbulence: Adventures strong rhetoric from a person dedicated to pain- in a new world (2007). Here he suggests that it is staking investigation of the longue durée of the now a time of instability, a world of turbulence. modern world system and not to histrionics. It Naomi Klein, a journalist covering global calami- might be objected that Wallerstein is to the left, ties, has written The shock doctrine: The rise of and besides, that he is an intellectual and so not disaster capitalism (2007), in which she strips a practical person of the world. Consider the away neoliberal cloaking rhetoric to reveal con- practical world of government and journalism. temporary capitalism in shockingly complicit Focaal—European Journal of Anthropology 52 (2008): 3–17 doi:10.3167/fcl.2008.520101 4|Stephen Reyna and Andrea Behrends bondage with disaster. So there you have it. On rising transportation costs. Furthermore, reduc- the left and right, academics, statesmen, and tion of petroleum supplies will compromise food journalists currently talk of systemic crisis in a production, giving rise to possible mass human world of turbulence characterized by disaster starvation, because contemporary industrial ag- capitalism. Why? riculture is dependent on cheap oil (for fertil- Responding to this question brings us to oil. izer, herbicides, pesticides, and machinery fuel). Oil is the key scarce, strategic resource needed Additionally, the carbon dioxide released into for almost all capitalist enterprise (Homer-Dixon the atmosphere by the utilization of fossil fuels 2001; Klare 2002). It is not renewable. One con- is a major cause of global warming. This means cern of those studying oil has been how to con- that global warming will accompany consump- ceptualize its supply. M. King Hubbert sug- tion of the remaining oil supplies “during the gested in the 1950s that it might be imagined as 21st century” and “could lead to a relatively a bell curve. This meant it would have an as- abrupt lowering of the ocean” temperature due cending slope as output increased; a highest point to melting ice packs, which, in turn, could lead before decrease set in; and a descending slope as to “harsher winter weather … , sharply reduced output decreased. The high point has come to soil moisture and more intense winds,” leading be known as Hubbert’s Peak. Hubbert’s work al- finally to reduction in “the human carrying ca- lowed yearly projections of what the oil supply pacity of the Earth’s environment” (Schwartz bell curve would look like. In 1956 he predicted and Randall 2003: 1). It should be noted that that U.S. oil production would peak around 1970 the preceding judgment does not come from and decline thereafter (1956). He was correct. ‘radical’ ecologists. Schwartz and Randall work His simulation methods have been improved for the U.S. Department of Defense. Under such and found to be reliable (Deffeyes 2006). Thus, conditions, according to one observer, “If the the approach helps answer the question: what U.S. controls the sources of energy of its rivals— years will be those of Hubbert’s Peak, after Europe, Japan, China and other nations aspir- which production subsides? Available evidence ing to be more independent—they win” (Daya- suggests that Hubbert’s Peak is fast approach- neni and Wing 2002: 2). Thus, there is a gather- ing. There are 98 oil-producing countries in the ing turbulence due to systemic crisis because, as world; 64 of these are believed to have passed the head of OPEC put it in 2004, there is “no their geologically imposed production peak; additional supply” of oil—“it’s crazy” (Trotti and of those, 60 are in terminal production de- 2005: 2). cline (Deffeyes 2006). Oil prospecting has turned One point to draw from the preceding is that sour. Nine barrels of oil are consumed for every in some sense the future of the world depends new one barrel discovered (ibid.). Peak oil spe- upon oil and how humans use it. As the past cialists predict that Hubbert’s Peak has occurred, and the present are the only predictors of the fu- or will occur, between 2000 and 2010 (Kunstler ture, this means to some extent that the fate of 2006). Indeed, Deffeyes has asserted that it oc- humanity depends upon inquiries into how oil curred in 2005 (Green Car Congress 2006). affects the dynamics of human social forms. As Consumption of oil, on the other hand, is pre- we shall see below, anthropological inquiry into dicted to rise 60 percent between 2003 and 2025 oil is limited, while that of other social sciences (IAGS 2003). So, oil production declines, very is richer. So the goal of this introduction is to soon, under conditions of rising demand. Its re- propose a research strategy for anthropological placement is theoretically possible, though not analysis of oil. It will do so by interrogating find- currently economically or technically feasible. ings of existing oil literatures, discussing the re- What will the loss of oil mean? There is a gen- search implications of the articles that compose eral concurrence that there will be severe and the offerings of this section in Focaal, and fi- lengthy worldwide depression resulting from nally sketching on the basis of these analyses an shrunken economic activity, high inflation, and anthropology of oil in a turbulent world. This Introduction: The crazy curse: Toward an anthropology of oil |5 sketch, offered in the third section, will propose triple conjunction in petrostates of stagnating a ‘crude domination’ approach, whose goal is social development and poverty; high conflict, explaining oil’s crazy curse. often violent; and a tendency toward authori- tarian regimes. The preceding suggests a paradox: If money The crazy ‘curse’: Current approaches is a condition for development, and it surely is, why do petrodollars buy petrocurse rather than The oil literature to be discussed is that in eco- petro-utopia? Because this paradox is so puz- nomics, political science, and anthropology zling—what is supposed to create prosperity in starting in the 1970s, because it was at this time fact produces the reverse—let us recognize that that the current turbulence began. The turbu- oil producers suffer from a crazy curse. Crazy lence began on a high note. Oil prices boomed phenomena, important for human welfare, beg in the years following the early 1970s, bringing, for solution, and, accordingly, investigation of according to one oil minister,“more money than oil’s crazy curse is the research object of this an- we ever in our wildest dreams thought possible” thropology of oil. Some major contributions to (Karl 1997: 3).‘Petro-states, as understood here, this literature are considered next. are capital-intensive oil exporters with high ra- tios of oil to total exports, petroleum industry enclaves, and enormous rents or royalties (from Resource curse, Dutch Disease, and greed oil sales), which accrue directly to the central government. Social development is any sequence Economics, often labeled the dismal science, of events that leads to beneficent, sustainable strengthens this reputation with its handling of economic, social, and political change for all seg- oil’s crazy curse. Classical economists in the ments of a population. The 1970s boom meant eighteenth and nineteenth centuries first formu- that oil rents became enormous. Petrodollars, lated theory relevant to the curse. They observed people dreamed, would buy petrostates’ devel- that Spain and England had marched down opment. Dream and reality marched down dif- vastly different developmental paths—Spain to ferent paths. decline, England to growth. Adam Smith ex- Oil turned out to be a development “curse” plained this with a theory of resources, which (Auty 1993; Ross 1999). Most developing petro- warned of the perils of natural resource rents. states found that their economic performance Rents or royalties are payments to owners of worsened in the 1990s (Attiga 1981; Gelb 1988; land for using its various raw materials in the Karl 1997, 1999). Some ‘oil-rich’ petrostates production of goods and services. Economies found themselves ‘dirt poor’ in the sense that based on renting natural resources motivate their poor became poorer (Gary and Karl 2003). rent-seeking behavior and not profits from pro- Michael Ross (2001) found democracy unlikely ductive activity (Smith 1776). Further, raw ma- and authoritarian regimes likely in petrostates. terial rents were exhaustible and, thus, experi- Worse, oil is ‘black gold’ over which social pi- enced diminishing returns (Mill 1851).
Recommended publications
  • Can Corporate Power Positively Transform Angola and Equatorial Guinea?
    Can Corporate Power Positively Transform Angola and Equatorial Guinea? Published in Wayne Visser ed. Corporate Citizenship in Africa. Greenleaf Publications, UK, 2006. Authors: Jose A. Puppim de Oliveira Brazilian School of Public and Business Administration – EBAPE Getulio Vargas Foundation – FGV Praia de Botafogo 190, room 507 CEP: 22253-900, Rio de Janeiro - RJ, BRAZIL Phone: (55-21) 2559-5737 Fax: (55-21) 2559-5710 e-mail: [email protected] & Saleem H. Ali Rubenstein School of Environment and Natural Resources University of Vermont 153 S. Prospect St., Burlington VT, 05452, USA Ph: 802-656-0173 Fx: 802-656-8015 Email: [email protected] 1 ABSTRACT While there is considerable literature on the adverse effects of oil development on developing economies through “Dutch Disease” or “Resource Curse” hypotheses, studies have neglected to pose the question in terms of positive causal factors that certain kinds of oil development might produce. We do not dispute the potential for negative effects of certain kinds of oil development but rather propose that some of the negative causality can be managed and transformed to lead to positive outcomes. Using a comparative study of oil company behavior in Angola and Equatorial Guinea, the research detects three main factors that have affected the behavior of oil companies since the Earth Summit in 1992. First, there is a growing movement of corporate social responsibility in businesses due to changes in leadership and corporate culture. Second, the ‘globalization’ of environmental movements has affected the behavior of companies through threats of litigation and stakeholder action. Third, governments in Africa have increasingly become stricter in regulating companies for environmental and social issues due to a transformation of domestic norms and international requirements.
    [Show full text]
  • White Elephant‟ Industrialization in Algeria”
    Clement Henry, “Between the Shocks: „White Elephant‟ Industrialization in Algeria” Algeria took major strides in the late sixties and seventies toward building an industrial base. The first oil shock of 1973-74 permitted Belaid Abdesselam, who founded Algeria‟s Société Nationale des Hydrocarbures (SONATRACH) in 1964 and then served from 1965 to 1977 as minister of industry and energy, to double the planned investments and ride roughshod over any reservations or criticisms of economic planners, finance ministers, or rival politicians. He enjoyed the full support of President Houari Boumediene, who had seized power in 1965, consolidated it by 1968, and aspired to legitimacy based on economic achievement. Not only were some $45 billion invested from 1967 to 1978. Price controls apparently inoculated Algeria against Dutch disease – the presumed illness of other oil or gas rentier economies -- during these boom years, but at the cost of rising discontent due to housing and other shortages.1 Industrialization from above already seemed dysfunctional in 1977, when Boumediene broke up Abdesselam‟s industrial empire and demoted him to be minister of light industry, hence in charge of developing those enterprises that in the perspective of “industrializing industry” were supposed to mushroom from a heavy industrial base. Within a year of Boumediene‟s death in December 1978 Algeria‟s industrialization policies were reversed: not only was yet another import substituting factory project of tires for trucks and automobiles stopped, but so also was an extension of a gas liquefaction plant, designed to maximize oil and gas exports to accumulate the capital for further industrial investment.
    [Show full text]
  • How Territory, Bureaucratic Power and Culture Coalesce in the Venezuelan Petrostate
    Culture as renewable oil: how territory, bureaucratic power and culture coalesce in the Venezuelan petrostate Book Accepted Version Plaza Azuaje, P. (2018) Culture as renewable oil: how territory, bureaucratic power and culture coalesce in the Venezuelan petrostate. Routledge Research in Place, Space and Politics. Routledge, Taylor and Francis Group, United Kingdom, pp192. ISBN 9781138573772 Available at http://centaur.reading.ac.uk/72517/ It is advisable to refer to the publisher’s version if you intend to cite from the work. See Guidance on citing . Publisher: Routledge, Taylor and Francis Group All outputs in CentAUR are protected by Intellectual Property Rights law, including copyright law. Copyright and IPR is retained by the creators or other copyright holders. Terms and conditions for use of this material are defined in the End User Agreement . www.reading.ac.uk/centaur CentAUR Central Archive at the University of Reading Reading’s research outputs online It’s July 2014. On a weekly routine trip to the nearest PDV petrol station in Caracas, whilst waiting for the tank to fill (Venezuela has the cheapest fuel in the world) I looked up to the fuel dispenser and its empty shelves, instead of the usual adverts for PDV lubricants or motor oil, it featured the nineteenth century white filigree gazebo of El Calvario park in Caracas; looming over it appeared a Gulliver-scale version of an oil worker wearing red coloured gear. I got off my car to take a photograph and noticed that the dispenser on the opposite lane also had a similar advert with another giant oil worker grazing the multicolour ceramic mural that covers Libertador Avenue in Caracas.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Do Resource Abundant Countries Have Authoritarian Governments?
    Why do Resource Abundant Countries Have Authoritarian Governments? Leonard Wantchekon Yale University October 15, 2002 Abstract This article provides a theoretical and empirical investigation of the correlation between resource wealth and authoritarianism. Building on the rentier state literature, I argue that resource wealth facilitates the consolidation of an already established authoritarian government. Re- source wealth also generates a breakdown of democratic regimes due to a combination of incumbency advantage, political instability, and po- litical repression. There is strong empirical support for the theoretical argument. Controlling for GDP, human capital, income inequality and other possible determinants, I find a robust and statistically significant association between resource dependence measured by the ratio of fuel and mineral exports as a percentage of total exports and authoritari- anism. 1 I. INTRODUCTION This study investigates the following surprising and troubling empiri- cal regularity: natural resource dependence and rentier economies tend to undermine democratic governance and generate authoritarian governments. Although the correlation between dictatorships and resource dependence has been mentioned in various case studies, there has never been an empirical or a theoretical investigation of such correlation.1 There are, however, a few noticeable exceptions to these perverse effects of resource dependence on democratic governance such as Botswana, Venezuela, and Norway. This raises several questions. For instance,
    [Show full text]
  • Authoritarianism and the Rentier State - Venezuela and Nigeria
    Fordham University Fordham Research Commons Senior Theses International Studies Spring 5-22-2021 Authoritarianism and the Rentier State - Venezuela and Nigeria Victoria Zobeida Castillo Fordham University Follow this and additional works at: https://research.library.fordham.edu/international_senior Part of the International Relations Commons Recommended Citation Castillo, Victoria Zobeida, "Authoritarianism and the Rentier State - Venezuela and Nigeria" (2021). Senior Theses. 60. https://research.library.fordham.edu/international_senior/60 This is brought to you for free and open access by the International Studies at Fordham Research Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Senior Theses by an authorized administrator of Fordham Research Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected]. “Authoritarianism and the Rentier State - Venezuela and Nigeria” Victoria Z. Castillo Abdallah [email protected] B.A, International Studies, Global Affairs Fordham University - Lincoln Center Thesis Advisor: Professor Jose Aleman Seminar Advisor: Professor Caley Johnson Castillo 1 Table of Contents I. Abstract…………………………………………………………………………………p 2 II. Introduction……………………………………………………………………………..p 3 III. Literature Review……………………………………………………………………….p 5 IV. Overview of Case Studies…………………………………………………………… p 13 V. Historical and Colonial Context……………………………………………………...p 14 VI. Nationalization………………………………………………………………………..p 19 VII. Analysis………………………………………………………………………………p 29 A. A Rentier Effect……………………………………………………………….p 29 B. A Repression Effect…………………………………………………………p 31 C. A Modernization Effect………………………………………………………p 33 VIII. Conclusion…………………………………………………………………………… p 34 IX. Bibliography…………………………………………………………………………p 36 Castillo 2 I. Abstract The oil states scattered throughout the developing world are no more democratic or peaceful than they were at the beginning of the twentieth century's natural resource era. In fact, some countries are worse, tainted by civil unrest, plummeting per capita income, and rising inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Why the Global Energy Transition Does Not Mean the End of the Petrostate
    Why the global energy transition does not mean the end of the petrostate Short version of title: energy transition and petrostates Andreas Goldthau, Royal Holloway, University of London Kirsten Westphal, German Institute for International and Security Affairs (SWP), Berlin Abstract The world going low carbon is believed to put an end to petrostates, and to force incumbent oil pro‐ ducers to diversify their economies away from fossil fuels. This article challenges this assumption. Whether petrostates are in for the long game or end up with a ‘panic and pump’ strategy, it is ar‐ gued, is a function of the lifting costs and the social costs of producing oil. What is more, the low car‐ bon energy transition may well throw petrostates an additional lifeline, as fast decarbonizing OECD countries will shed some of their most energy‐intensive sectors, including refineries and petrochemi‐ cals, which opens up new export opportunities. Particularly for Middle Eastern petrostates it may therefore be very rational to further specialize in the high‐carbon segment. The policy challenge, therefore, will be two‐fold: managing a rapidly changing energy system in order to secure the trans‐ formation dividends it will bring, for human security and economic welfare; and balancing the (geo)political afterpains of the incumbent fuels leaving the system. Petrostates and the low carbon energy world The global energy transformation is believed to fundamentally threaten incumbent oil producers. Not only will the Paris climate targets require a third of all oil reserves to stay in the ground and leave the balance sheets for good (along with 80 percent of current coal reserves and half of natural gas) (McGlade and Ekins 2015).
    [Show full text]
  • Nigeria: a Prime Example of the Resource Curse? Revisiting the Oil-Violence Link in the Niger Delta
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Mähler, Annegret Working Paper Nigeria: A Prime Example of the Resource Curse? Revisiting the Oil-Violence Link in the Niger Delta GIGA Working Papers, No. 120 Provided in Cooperation with: GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies Suggested Citation: Mähler, Annegret (2010) : Nigeria: A Prime Example of the Resource Curse? Revisiting the Oil-Violence Link in the Niger Delta, GIGA Working Papers, No. 120, German Institute of Global and Area Studies (GIGA), Hamburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/47794 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die
    [Show full text]
  • Crisis in Venezuela – Briefing Paper the Organization of American States Washington D.C., United States of America • 10 July 2019
    Crisis in Venezuela – Briefing Paper The Organization of American States Washington D.C., United States of America • 10 July 2019 “In Venezuela, the purpose of politics has been lost, they have forgotten to defend the general and collective long-term good, over short-term individual gain ... Immoral politics loses this vision because its only interest is staying in power.” Luis Almagro, Secretary General of the Organization of American States (OAS) The Organization of American States The Organization of American States (OAS), a regional organization founded in 1948, is mandated to promote peace and stability in the Western hemisphere. The organization has 35 member states representing most countries in North, Central and South America, as well as the Caribbean. The OAS is tasked with promoting peace and security on the continent, promoting representative democracy and the peaceful resolution of domestic and international disputes. The bloc also seeks to promote the economic, social and cultural development of the region through cooperative action and coalition building. The OAS was founded by a Charter that explicitly includes the sovereign right of each member state and the principles and rights of each member state, including a commitment to collective security of all member nations. Background Information: Venezuela, the Petro State The ongoing crisis in Venezuela has deep economic, political and cultural roots dating back decades. In the 1920s speculators discovered crude oil in Venezuela, instantly bringing the small South American nation into the forefront of global energy production. Over time, it was discovered that Venezuela held the world’s largest reserves of crude oil, surpassing other oil- producing nations like Saudi Arabia or the United States of America.
    [Show full text]
  • Oil and Conflict- Technical Brief
    TECHNICAL BRIEF OIL AND CONFLICT December 2011 | DCHA/CMM Introduction of UCLA argued that “oil hinders democracy,” and many subse- Oil is an essential, high-value commodity for both industrialized quent studies reached a similar conclusion.2 The rentier effect is and developing countries. Owing to the diverse uses of oil and the most widely-cited causal mechanism to explain this relation- its direct links to economic and social well-being, the demand for ship, but there may also be other anti-democratic effects of oil.3 it continues to grow as incomes rise and populations expand in For example, scholars have argued that elites in petrostates im- most developing countries. Oil prices have risen markedly in re- pede democratization for fear that it will lead to expropriation of cent years, making control over oil resources an important poten- their assets, or that oil generates corruption, which in turn pre- tial driver of development. Oil income can be a source of national vents democratization.4 The geopolitics of oil may also lead pow- prosperity, bolstering public finances, encouraging investment, and erful oil-importing states to support friendly autocratic regimes providing employment in a range in petrostates, thereby limiting of activities directly and indirect- democracy.5 In short, however, ly related to the oil itself. How- the proliferation of hypothesized ever, oil extraction and trade, micro-mechanisms linking oil to and the associated revenues, can authoritarianism generates some also bring significant challenges, uncertainty about the precise especially in countries with frag- nature of the causal relationship, ile social and political institu- and the subject remains con- tions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Bottom of the Barrel: Saudi Aramco and Global Climate Action
    Working Paper The Bottom of the Barrel: Saudi Aramco and Global Climate Action Jim Krane, Ph.D. Wallace S. Wilson Fellow for Energy Studies © 2021 by Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy This material may be quoted or reproduced without prior permission, provided appropriate credit is given to the author and Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy. Wherever feasible, papers are reviewed by outside experts before they are released. However, the research and views expressed in this paper are those of the individual researcher(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the Baker Institute. This paper is a work in progress and has not been submitted for editorial review. ABSTRACT For Saudi Arabia’s absolute monarchy, climate action represents a combined threat and opportunity in retaining the oil rents that underpin domestic political institutions and the kingdom’s international influence. Saudi Aramco, the largest source of greenhouse gas-emitting fossil fuel among all firms worldwide, is exposed to numerous risks around continued use of fossil fuels. However, Aramco is also the producer with the world’s lowest cost basis and lowest intensity of greenhouse gas emissions per barrel produced. These attributes suggest that oil from the kingdom should retain a prominent role in oil markets, particularly under climate constraints. While Saudi Aramco’s April 2019 bond prospectus outlines steps the company is taking to ensure that it continues marketing oil far into the future, this paper argues that Aramco’s quest to remain the “last man standing” in global oil depends not just on its substantial cost advantages.
    [Show full text]
  • Algeria's Agonies
    Algeria’s Agonies: Oil Rent Effects in a Bunker State CLEMENT M. HENRY The Resource Curse Hypothesis Oil rentier states, if not damned definitively by their wealth, are thought to share several failings arising from the atrophy of their tax extractive capacity.1 Blessed with substantial oil revenues, they need not tax their populations as much as other states enjoying similar per capita incomes. Consequently, the argument goes, they are less accountable to their citizenry than more extrac- tive states. The rentier state enjoys relative autonomy as long as the rents keep flowing. The petroleum industry is capital intensive, employs few workers and lacks substantial linkages with the broader economy, further insulating it against social and political pressures.2 Dependence on oil revenues can lead to overspending, debt and fiscal crises because of the volatility of international petroleum markets. The economy becomes distorted by the Dutch disease, whereby periods of resource-dependent economic growth diminish the value of other tradable goods, real estate and services, leading to even greater dependence on pet- roleum revenues and reducing the kinds of manufacturing and service exports that contribute to long-term growth. After the Netherlands’ discovery of natural gas in the late 1950s and early 1960s raised the value of its currency and inflated labour and other production costs, for example, its other manufac- tured goods become less competitive and exports fell. Oil-dependent states can subsidise education and other social services but cannot encourage occupational specialisation, further distorting the labour economy and the educational system.3 When oil prices tumble, rentier states face political as well as economic instability.
    [Show full text]
  • Confronting the Resource Curse: Advice for Investors and Partners
    Working Paper in THE ROLE OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN RESOURCE-RICH REGIONS Confronting the Resource Curse: Advice for Investors and Partners David Goldwyn, JD, MPA President, Goldwyn Global Strategies, LLC Andrea Clabough, MA Associate, Goldwyn Global Strategies, LLC February 2020 © 2020 Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy This material may be quoted or reproduced without prior permission, provided appropriate credit is given to the authors and Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy. Wherever feasible, papers are reviewed by outside experts before they are released. However, the research and views expressed in this paper are those of the individual researcher(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the Baker Institute. David Goldwyn and Andrea Clabough “Confronting the Resource Curse: Advice for Investors and Partners” Confronting the Resource Curse: Advice for Investors and Partners Introduction Developing countries which experience major foreign investment and revenue flows from natural resource development have struggled long and mostly unsuccessfully to manage the economic, political and social impacts of this newfound wealth. These problems, often called the “natural resource curse” or “paradox of plenty”, have been extensively researched in recent decades, but avoiding the “curse” remains a challenge. While every nation that anticipates the income from a major discovery of oil, gas or minerals hopes to convert this wealth into sustainable development and long-term prosperity, most often the results are just the opposite. Public accountability declines, authoritarianism rises, currencies are distorted and non-extractive industries atrophy. Borrowing rises in anticipation of income and monies are not spent wisely. Expectations of newly-invested private companies fluctuate from cautious optimism for taking on the initial investment risk, to excitement when discoveries are made, to resentment at the length of time it takes for projects to mature and repay costs.
    [Show full text]