THE GREAT MEXICAN EMIGRATION Gordon H. Hanson and Craig McIntosh*

Abstract—In this paper, we examine net emigration from over the ing the results difficult to generalize to the country as a period 1960 to 2000. The data are consistent with labor supply shocks having made a substantial contribution to Mexican emigration, accounting whole. for two-fifths of Mexican labor flows to the over the last two In this paper, we examine net decades of the twentieth century. Net emigration rates by Mexican state from 1960 to 2000. To measure net labor outflows, we birth year cohort display a strong positive correlation with the initial size of the Mexican cohort relative to the corresponding U.S. cohort. In states compare the size of birth cohorts in Mexican states between with long histories of emigration, the effects of cohort size on emigration decennial censuses. By taking state birth cohorts as the unit are relatively strong, consistent with the existence of preexisting networks. of analysis, we ignore how migration varies with schooling, income, or other individual characteristics, on which previ- ous literature dwells. The advantage of our approach is that 1. Introduction we can study emigration across regions within Mexico over N the past two and a half decades, migration from long time periods that have seen large changes in labor IMexico to the United States has surged. As a share of market conditions in the country relative to the United Mexico’s national population, the number of Mexican im- States. migrants living in the United States remained at 1.5% from One seemingly obvious explanation for labor outflows 1960 to 1970, before rising to 3.3% in 1980, 5.2% in 1990, from Mexico, which to date has received little attention in and 10.2% in 2005. Mexico is by far and away the largest the literature, is that labor supply in Mexico has grown source country for U.S. , accounting for one- relative to the United States, putting downward pressure on third of the current U.S. foreign-born population. relative wages and making emigration more attractive.2 Mexico-to-U.S. labor flows are a major policy issue for Figure 1 shows that the U.S. baby boom matched rapid both countries. The United States spends large sums on population growth in Mexico between 1940 and 1960. enforcing borders against illegal immigration. In Mexico, Subsequently, Mexican birth cohorts continued to grow for the exodus of labor has reduced the population of working- another two decades, while the size of U.S. birth cohorts age adults (Hanson, 2006), while creating a financial wind- began to fall. Between 1960 and 1980, there was a large fall in the form of (Woodruff & Zenteno, 2006). shift in the relative size of U.S.-Mexican cohorts, from 4:1 Given the importance of migration for labor markets in to less than 2:1. Given that birth cohorts enter the labor North America, it is surprising that little academic research market with a fifteen- to twenty-year lag, the labor supply has examined the scale of regional labor flows. Existing effects should have triggered emigration from Mexico be- literature provides scant analysis of why—despite long- ginning in the late 1970s, consistent with observed patterns. standing income differences between Mexico and the The focus of our analysis is to assess the contribution of United States—labor outflows from Mexico have grown relative labor supply shocks over the past four decades to dramatically only recently. Mexico’s great wave of emigration. There is work on other aspects of Mexican emigration, Clearly factors besides labor supply affect Mexican labor including how labor flows affect U.S. and Mexican wages outflows. Since 1980, Mexico has been beset periodically (Mishra, 2006; Borjas & Katz, 2007; Aydemir & Borjas, by financial crises. Its per capita GDP fell sharply in 1983 2007), the self-selection of emigrants (Chiquiar & Hanson, (after the onset of the Mexican debt crisis) and again in 2005; Ibarraran & Lubotsky, 2007; Fernandez-Huertas, 1995 (after the crisis), leaving the difference 2008), and the assimilation of immigrants in the United in Mexico-U.S. per capita income in 2005 little changed States (Borjas, 1996; Grogger & Trejo, 2002; Smith, 2003; relative to two and a half decades before (table 1). Previous Blau & Kahn, 2007).1 Although there is research on indi- work finds that Mexico-to-U.S. migration increases follow- vidual migration decisions (Taylor, 1987; Massey & Espi- ing real wage declines (Hanson & Spilimbergo, 1999; Or- nosa, 1997; Orrenius & Zavodny, 2005; McKenzie & Rap- renius & Zavodny, 2005). U.S. immigration policy and oport, 2007), much of this work uses data from Mexican migrant networks also affect migration. Illegal immigrants communities chosen for having high migration rates, mak- appear to account for most new arrivals from Mexico in the United States. With the buildup in U.S. border enforcement Received for publication February 7, 2008. Revision accepted for since 1990, the fees that smugglers charge migrants at the publication October 20, 2008. * Hanson: University of California, , and NBER; McIntosh: border have risen (Gathmann, 2004). At the same time, University of California, San Diego. expanding migrant networks have made moving abroad We thank seminar participants at Columbia University, Princeton Uni- more attractive (Munshi, 2003; Orrenius & Zavodny, 2005). versity, and UCSD for valuable advice and Jeffrey Lin for excellent research assistance. 1 See Hanson (2006) for a review of literature on Mexico-U.S. migration 2 There is cross-country evidence on the relationship between demo- and Massey and Zenteno (1999) for work on migration dynamics using the graphic structure and international migration. See Hatton and Williamson Mexican Migration Project data. (2003, 2005).

The Review of Economics and Statistics, November 2010, 92(4): 798–810 © 2010 The President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 THE GREAT MEXICAN EMIGRATION 799

FIGURE 1.—LABOR SUPPLY,UNITED STATES VERSUS MEXICO (1910 ϭ 1) do in section 5, recent rapid declines in Mexican fertility should diminish binational differences in labor supply growth as a motivation for emigration from Mexico. The 5 total fertility rate in Mexico was 7 in 1965; it plummeted over the next several decades, dropping to 2.5 by 2000, 4 close to the U.S. level of 2.1 (Tuiran et al., 2002). Holding other factors constant, the dramatic decline in Mexico’s 3 population growth implies that emigration rates from Mex- ico should peak with the 1980 birth cohort and decline for 2 successive birth cohorts, such that those born in 2010 would have emigration rates less than half as large as those born in 1 1980. 0

1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 II. Data Bi r t h year

USnative born MX To calculate labor outflows from Mexico, we use the net migration method, which takes Mexican state, gender, and birth year cohorts as the unit of analysis and apply it to data from Mexico’s population census in 1960, 1970, 1990, and In the presence of network effects, migration may be self- 2000.3 We begin by identifying the base size for a cohort, reinforcing (Carrington, Detragiache, & Viswanath, 1996). which is the population the first time a cohort is observed in Our empirical framework attempts to control for how these the census. For example, we can count the number of boys other shocks have affected Mexican emigration. born in the state of aged 8 who appear in the 1960 In section 2, we present data on net labor outflows. In Mexican census. By then observing how many men born in section 3, we outline a simple dynamic model of emigration Zacatecas are age 18 in the 1970 census, age 38 in the 1990 that yields an estimating equation specifying the current census, and age 48 in the 2000 census, we are able to emigration rate for a cohort in Mexico as a function of construct a series of ten-year emigration rates that are initial differences in Mexico-U.S. labor supply, plus other specific to gender, age, state of birth, and year of birth. For controls. The model allows migration networks and internal birth year i, gender j, and birth state s, the fraction of migration within Mexico. In section 4, we present estima- individuals that has emigrated as of time t is, tion results in which we control the initial level of devel- opment in Mexican states, subsequent shocks to GDP, base cohort sizeijs Ϫ current cohort sizeijst migration costs, and other factors. mijst ϭ . (1) To preview the findings, the data are consistent with labor base cohort sizeijs supply shocks having made a substantial contribution to The ten-year time difference in m is the decadal emigra- Mexican emigration to the United States. Our estimates ijst tion rate.4 In the regression analysis, we exclude cohorts indicate that Mexican population growth can account for two-fifths of total out-migration for the twenty years prior to 3 Data are from http://www.ipums.umn.edu. The 1980 census was con- 1997. Initial cohort size in Mexico (relative to the United ducted but never made available. States) has a strong, positive correlation with net emigration 4 Wherever possible, the base cohort size is taken from a cohort between rates by Mexican state. The effects of cohort size are the ages of 1 and 10. However, in the case of cohorts born before 1950 or between 1970 and 1980, we have no census that lets us measure this strongest in states with long histories of migration, consis- quantity, and so we use instead the population at the time the cohort first tent with network effects. Looking forward in time, as we appears in the data.

TABLE 1.—POPULATION AND GDP (PPP) IN MEXICO AND THE UNITED STATES Mexico United States Ratio, Mexico/United States GDP per Size of Birth GDP per Size of Birth Number of High GDP per Size of Birth Mexico Birth Cohort/U.S. Year Capita Cohort Capita Cohort School Dropouts Capita Cohorts High School Dropouts 1920 584,776 2,281,441 1,115,098 0.26 0.52 1930 753,616 2,223,977 884,869 0.34 0.85 1940 4,498 743,566 8,820 2,097,851 605,711 0.51 0.35 1.23 1950 5,385 1,002,387 12,009 3,209,845 408,878 0.45 0.31 2.45 1960 6,138 1,438,300 13,840 4,107,562 381,367 0.44 0.35 3.77 1970 8,341 1,792,770 18,391 3,221,446 350,870 0.45 0.56 5.11 1980 11,976 2,153,340 22,666 3,250,323 431,330 0.53 0.66 4.99 1990 12,594 2,273,444 28,429 4,041,951 0.44 0.56 2000 15,279 2,018,483 34,759 3,703,392 0.44 0.55 Note: GDP in both countries is measured in 2000 U.S. dollars.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 800 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 2.—COHORT SIZE AND AGE there is little misreporting the ages of young children. Age Ends in Age Does Not Test of However, the subsequent net emigration of cohorts ending 0or5 Endin0or5 Difference in 0 or 5 is less than a quarter the rate of other cohorts. As Log base Mexico 9.588 9.632 0.044 respondents age, misreporting may cause them to “leave” cohort size (0.034) (0.016) (0.038) unrounded cohorts and “enter” rounded cohorts. We address Subsequent 0.032 0.145 0.114 migration rate (0.006) (0.003) (0.006)** the issue by aggregating cohorts around years in which 8 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. **significant at 1%. rounding occurs, using three- or five-year intervals. A final concern arises as a result of cohort-specific mor- tality. Martinez and Woodruff (2007), who use only 1990 younger than 16 years old since their emigration is likely and 2000 data, correct their net migration estimates using due to decisions made by their parents, or older than 50, cohort- and age-specific mortality rates. However, no such after which age few individuals emigrate.5 These restric- data exist for 1960 or 1970, and Mexican mortality data are tions leave us with 6,081 observations on ten-year net based on the state in which the individual dies, making it emigration rates for cohorts born between 1920 and 1984. impossible to ascribe mortality to the state of birth. For the The net migration method has several advantages. At a period from 1990 to 2000, mortality is a nonnegligible share mechanical level, because the Mexican census asks both the of the observed net migration. In cohorts aged 23 to 27, only state of birth and the state of residence, we can calculate net 8.8% of the observed decrease in cohort size comes from emigration over the state of birth and avoid the bias in mortality, but in cohorts aged 43 to 47, observed net migra- population by state of residence that results from internal tion has fallen to 7.4% and mortality is 3.1%, meaning that migration within Mexico.6 A more nuanced advantage can deaths account for 42% of the missing individuals. Since we be seen in the debate over the composition of Mexican use state and birth year fixed effects, mortality would migrants to the United States. Studies on Mexican immi- introduce bias into our parameter estimates only if there is grants using U.S. data find that emigrants have schooling variation that is both cross-state and cross-time. To examine levels close to that of Mexico’s national mean (Chiquiar & this possibility, we regress 2000 state- and cohort-level Hanson, 2005; Orrenius & Zavodny, 2005), while some mortality rates on 1990 rates, including fixed effects for the analyses based on Mexican data (which contain information state and five-year birth year cohorts. The R2 in the regres- on which family members have emigrated) find that emi- sion is 0.96, suggesting that the fixed effects absorb most of grants have below-mean schooling (Ibarraran & Lubotsky, the regional heterogeneity in mortality.9 2007; Fernandez-Huertas, 2008). Either data source is sub- Subject to these caveats, what do estimates of net migra- ject to bias: the U.S. census may undercount lower-skilled tion tell us? Not surprisingly, net labor outflows from recent immigrants, and estimates of migration based on Mexico have increased sharply over time. In 1970, 57,000 Mexican household data miss higher-skilled households that individuals aged 26 had left Mexico over the previous have emigrated in their entirety. Martinez and Woodruff decade; in 1990, 165,000 26 year olds had left over the (2007) find that the net migration method generates esti- previous decade; and in 2000, 336,000 individuals had left mates of total emigration and emigrant schooling between over the previous decade. Figure 2 plots smoothed age- and those arising from U.S. and Mexican data, suggesting this gender-specific net emigration rates. For men, a substantial method may be less subject to biases affecting other ap- fraction of individuals migrate by age 16, with emigration proaches.7 increasing sharply until around age 30 and decreasing there- One concern about the net migration method is that after, presumably as a result of return migration. The pattern estimates tend to be noisy, particularly when constructed for women is different. There is less emigration by age 16, from the 1% population samples available for the 1960 and with subsequent rates being relatively stable over the course 1970 censuses. Also, older respondents appear to round of their lives. By age 50, women have a net emigration rate their age (Martinez & Woodruff, 2007), which could cause that is similar to that for men. us to misestimate age-specific net migration rates. Table 2, To examine how labor supply affects emigration from on cohort sizes and age, illustrates this problem in a simple Mexico, we exploit intertemporal and interregional varia- way. There is no significant difference in base size between tion in the relative size of birth cohorts. Table 1 shows the cohorts whose age ends in 0 or 5 and other cohorts, meaning 8 Age-specific fixed effects will absorb systematic errors in estimates of 5 Although the migration of children under age 16 may also be related to net migration particular to individuals of a given age. The three-year demographic pressures, the driving factors likely relate to the parents’ aggregation scheme calculates cohorts using birth years 1959, 1960, and cohorts and not those of the child. In this paper, we focus on the effects 1961; then 1962 and 1963; then 1964, 1965, and 1996; and so on. The of own cohort size and therefore consider only cohorts old enough to be five-year scheme calculates cohorts using birth years 1958–1962, then making their own migration decisions. 1963–1967, and so on. The intent is to center cohorts around years in 6 The U.S. census asks the country but not the state of birth for which rounding occurs, thereby decreasing the likelihood that an individ- immigrants, and hence does not allow us to observe subnational Mexican ual is placed in the wrong birth cohort. variation in labor supply or migration. 9 In addition, an unreported analysis of the 1990–2000 changes in birth 7 See Buck et al. (2007) for an application of the net migration method cohort ratios and cohort-level mortality rates found the cross-state, cross- in and Mexico. time correlation in these variables to be insignificant.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 THE GREAT MEXICAN EMIGRATION 801

FIGURE 2.—DECADAL MIGRATION RATES BY GENDER, 2000 FIGURE 3.—TIMING OF DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION, BY MEXICAN STATE 8 15 6 10 4 5 Migration in percent 2 Children ever born to women over 40 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 Year of Birth

0 Distrito Federal 16 21 26 31 36 41 Campeche Mexican Average age Zacatecas B.C. Sur

Males Females Rank of 1960 Fertility: Chiapas=1, Zacatecas=9, Campeche=16, B.C. Sur=24, DF=32

data behind figure 1. The increase in Mexico’s population changes in birth cohort size, we take these changes to be relative to the United States is a result of differences in the predetermined for our analysis. We assume that, given state, timing of the demographic transition in the two countries. In year, and cohort fixed effects, the most plausible explana- the United States, fertility rates began to fall in the late tion for correlation between state-level birth cohort size and 1950s, while in Mexico they did not drop for another two subsequent migration is the cohort size itself. Of course, the decades. Between 1950 and 1980, the Mexico-U.S. ratio of size of birth cohorts may summarize more about a state than birth cohort size grew from 0.31 to 0.66. its labor supply. In section IV, we discuss alternative inter- Table 1 also shows the number of U.S. natives who fail to pretations of our results. complete high school according to birth year (where the Another source of variation among Mexican states is the number of high school dropouts is measured the first time a strength and persistence of migration networks. The corre- cohort is observed after age 19).10 U.S. high school dropouts lation in state-level emigration rates to the United States are the group that Mexican immigrants appear mostly likely from the mid-1950s with those from the mid-1990s is 0.72 to compete with (Aydemir & Borjas, 2007). As the share of (Hanson, 2006). The literature relates the emergence of U.S. natives without a high school education has declined, migration networks in Mexico to the hiring practices of U.S. Mexico’s relative labor supply has grown. In 1970, the ratio , which used Mexico’s railroad network to recruit of 20 year olds born in Mexico to 20-year-old high school workers in the country’s interior. Communities close to rail dropouts born in the United States was 2.45; by 1990, it was lines have had the highest emigration rates in the country 4.99. since at least the 1920s (Durand, Massey, & Zenteno, 2001). Within Mexico, there is considerable regional variation in Following Woodruff and Zenteno (2006), we proxy for the the timing of fertility declines. Figure 3 plots the number of strength of migration networks using historical state-level children ever born to women over age 40 by year of birth for migration rates and state access to Mexico’s railroad net- the states that represent the quintiles of the 1960 distribution work. of fertility rates. Fertility is lower and the demographic transition occurs earlier in wealthy, industrialized states such as the Federal District, whereas states in Mexico’s poor III. Theory south, such as Chiapas, have a quite different fertility A. Model trajectory. This cross-state, cross-time variation in the tim- ing of the demographic transition provides the identification To understand emigration from Mexico, consider a model for our analysis of Mexican labor supply shocks. Explana- of two national labor markets that are linked by migration. tions for heterogeneity in timing include differential In each economy, there is one sector of production. Workers changes in female job opportunities, industrialization, mor- from Mexico are differentiated by age but are not otherwise tality, or inequality across states (Tuiran et al., 2002). distinguished by their skill.11 To highlight the workings of Because realizations on migration are observed between the model, we suppress internal migration in Mexico. Our sixteen and fifty years after the shifts that caused the specifications of labor demand and labor mobility costs

10 For cohorts aged 16 to 19, we use the number of U.S. high school 11 We ignore other aspects of skill because in order to measure net dropouts observed in the following U.S. census so as to avoid miscounting migration by state of birth in Mexico, we need to track populations by the size of cohorts that are still acquiring high school education. characteristics that are invariant to time.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 802 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

build on the models of internal migration in Blanchard and To allow for adjustment costs in labor mobility between Katz (1992) and Borjas (2006). countries, we assume that migration from Mexico to the In Mexico, the national wage for age group i at time t is United States in any period t is a function of the lagged given by difference in wages between the two countries: ␩ ␯ ϭ ␴ ͑ Ϫ Ϫ ͒ Wit ϭ Xit͑Lit͒ , (2) *it * ln W*i,tϪ1 ln Wi,tϪ1 Ci,tϪ1 , (7) ␯ ϭ⌬ where Wit is the wage, Xit is a labor demand shifter, Lit is the where *it Mit/Li0 is the net emigration rate for group i population of working-age adults in Mexico, and ␩ Յ 0is in Mexico at time t, ␴* is the supply elasticity, and Ci,tϪ1 is the inverse labor demand elasticity. The supply of labor in a wage discount that Mexican nationals associate with Mexico is the population of group i that has not emigrated, living in the United States. The wage discount reflects the such that disamenity of living in the United States. To capture net- work effects associated with emigration, we assume this Lit ϭ Li0 Ϫ Mit, (3) disamenity is decreasing in the fraction of an individual’s cohort that has previously migrated abroad, such that where Li0 is the preemigration population of group i and Mit is the number of individuals in i who have emigrated to the tϪ1 ϭ Ϫ ␥ ͸ ␯ United States by period t. Putting equations (2) and (3) Ci,t C is, (8) together, sϭ1 Յ ␥ Յ ln Wit ϭ ln Xit ϩ ␩ ln Li0 Ϫ ␩mit, (4) where we assume 0 C (to ensure migration stops at or before U.S. and Mexican wages are equalized). Using ϭ where mit Mit/Li0 is the fraction of group i in Mexico that equations (7) and (8), the period t emigration rate from has emigrated.12 Mexico is An individual in Mexico has the option of staying in the country or moving to the United States, in which the wage tϪ1 for experience group i is ␯* ϭ ␴*ͩ ln W* Ϫ Ϫ ln W Ϫ ϩ ␥ ͸ ␯ Ϫ Cͪ. (9) it i,t 1 i,t 1 ir rϭ1 ␩ W*it ϭ X*it͑L*i0 ϩ ␶Mit͒ , (5) A larger existing stock of emigrants in the United States where W*it is the U.S. wage, X*it is the U.S. labor demand makes future emigration more attractive. In equation (9), shifter, ␶ ʦ [0, 1] is the productivity discount associated migration networks operate within cohorts (through siblings with immigrant labor, L*i0 is the U.S. labor supply (assumed and cousins) rather than between cohorts (through fathers equal to the population of U.S. native-born high school and uncles).14 In the empirical analysis, we control for dropouts), and ␩ is the inverse labor demand elasticity, networks between cohorts by allowing for birth-state fixed assumed equal to that in Mexico. effects and by letting the supply elasticity, ␴*, vary accord- The wage equation in equation (5) implies that when ing to the strength of historical migration networks. expressed in productivity-equivalent units, native and im- To solve the model, define the premigration effective migrant labor in the United States are perfect substitutes.13 wage differential between the United States and Mexico as However, the productivity discount, ␶, ensures that one immigrant worker substitutes for less than one native ␻*i0 ϭ ln W*i0 Ϫ ln Wi0 Ϫ C ϭ ␩ ln ᐉ*i0 ϩ ln x*i0 Ϫ C, (10) worker. Immigrant workers may be less productive because ᐉ ϭ Ϫ they are less educated, have a weaker command of English, where ln *i0 ln L*i0 ln Li0 is the log difference in U.S. ϭ Ϫ or are less knowledgeable about U.S. production practices. and Mexico initial labor supplies, and ln X*i0 ln X*i0 ln Expressing equation (5) in log form, Xi0 is the log difference in U.S. and Mexico initial labor demand shifters. The U.S.-Mexico premigration wage dif-

ln W*it ϭ ln X*it ϩ ␩ ln L*i0 ϩ ␩␶␭mit, (6) ference is decreasing in U.S.-Mexico relative labor supply (since ␩Ͻ0), increasing in U.S.-Mexico relative labor 15 where ␭ϭLi0/L*i0 is the relative size of Mexico’s initial demand, and decreasing in the migration disamenity. Us- population. ing equations (4), (6), and (9), we solve for the t ϭ 0

12 In equation (4), we utilize the approximation that for small values of 14 Orrenius and Zavodny (2005) find that the likelihood that a young X/Y, ln(X ϩ Y) Ϸ lnX ϩ Y/X. Mexican male migrates to the United States is positively correlated with 13 U.S. evidence on the substitutability of native and immigrant labor is the father having migrated and with the number of siblings who have mixed. While Aydemir and Borjas (2007) find native and immigrant migrated. workers are perfect substitutes (within skill groups), Ottaviano and Peri 15 Here we assume that labor demand is constant over time such that (2006) find they are not. Borjas, Grogger, and Hanson (2008) show that Xit ϭ Xi0 and X*it ϭ X*i0. Unreported results (available on request) allow once one adopts conventional definitions of who is in the labor force, time variation in labor demand shocks and internal migration within Ottaviano and Peri’s results also support perfect substitutability. Mexico.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 THE GREAT MEXICAN EMIGRATION 803

emigration rate and then iterate forward, solving for the grants follows the literature (Aydemir & Borjas, 2007). wage and emigration rate in each period. This reveals that However, it may introduce endogeneity into the estimation. the emigration rate for age group i in period t is16 If the decision by U.S. natives to complete high school depends on the U.S. wage for high school dropouts, then ␯ ϭ ␻ ␴ ϩ ␻ ␪͑ Ϫ ͒ *it *i0 * *i0 t 1 , (11) shocks to Mexican emigration may play a role in determin- ing the number of U.S. high school dropouts. Mexican ␪ϭ ␴ 2 ␥ϩ␩ ϩ␶␭ where ( *) [ (1 )]. The first term on the emigration and the supply of low-skilled U.S. natives would right-hand side of equation (11) indicates that the emigra- then be jointly determined. A related concern is that the tion rate is higher the larger is the initial wage differential number of high school dropouts may be a poor measure of between the United States and Mexico. Larger monetary the supply of low-skilled U.S. workers, introducing mea- gains to emigration naturally make emigration more attrac- tive. Thus, emigration from Mexico will be greater the surement error into the estimation. Many high school drop- smaller is the U.S. labor supply relative to Mexico (ᐉ* )or outs in the United States appear to have a weak attachment i0 to the labor force (Borjas et al., 2008), meaning they may the stronger is U.S. labor demand relative to Mexico ( x*i0). The second term in equation (11) captures emigration not compete with full-time immigrant workers for jobs. dynamics. Over time, emigration pushes wages up in Mex- We address concerns regarding endogeneity and mea- ico and down in the United States.17 Assume for a moment surement error in the U.S. labor supply by instrumenting for that ␽ϭ0, such that there are no network effects. In this the number of U.S. high school dropouts using the size of case, ␪ϭ(␴*)2␩(1 ϩ␶␭) Ͻ 0, which implies that the the corresponding U.S. birth cohort. Our identifying as- emigration rate for group i declines over time as emigration sumption is that the size of current U.S. birth cohorts is across successive periods erodes the binational wage differ- uncorrelated with expected immigration from Mexico ence. Now allow for network effects, such that ␥Ͼ0. The (twenty years in the future). In the first-stage estimation, the emigration rate may accelerate or decelerate over time. If log size of U.S. birth cohorts, along with dummy variables ␥ϽϪ␩(1 ϩ␶␭), then ␪Ͻ0 (recall that ␩Ͻ0). Network for gender, census year, and birth year, can account for 97% effects are weak or labor demand is inelastic (or both) (␩ϽϽ of the variation in the log number of U.S. native high school 0), meaning that networks effects are not strong enough to dropouts. counteract the depressive effect that emigration has on the We model the initial wage in a Mexican state relative to wage differential. Alternatively, if ␥ϾϪ␩(1 ϩ␶␭), ␪Ͼ0. the United States as a function of the size of a state birth Network effects are sufficiently strong to compensate for cohort relative to the size of the corresponding U.S. birth the emigration-induced decline in the wage differential, cohort (as well as initial differences in labor demand). To indicating that emigration accelerates over time until U.S.- allow for the fact that similarly aged individuals are likely to Mexico wage parity (adjusted for the emigration disame- be highly substituable in production, we group birth cohorts nity) is reached.18 The estimating equation follows directly by three- or five-year intervals (which also mitigates round- from equation (11). ing error in birth years). The implicit assumption is that each age group has its own production function and that other B. Specification Issues production factors, including younger or older groups, can For estimation purposes, we use equation (10) to rewrite be subsumed in to state per capita GDP, or the gender, birth equation (11) as year, and birth state fixed effects included in the regression. In the estimation, we consider the robustness of the results

␯*it ϭ ln ᐉ*i0͓␩␴* ϩ ␩␪͑t Ϫ 1͔͒ to this assumption by adding controls for the size of adja- (12) cent birth cohorts. We also examine how the results are ϩ ͓ Ϫ ͔͓␴ ϩ ␪͑ Ϫ ͔͒ ln x*i0 C * t 1 affected by different aggregation schemes. We use U.S. high school dropouts to measure U.S. labor ᐉ supply (the numerator of *i0). Treating U.S. high school IV. Empirical Results dropouts as the relevant labor market for Mexican immi-

16 A. Empirical Specification The precise solution to the model is ␯*i0 ϭ␴*␻*i0(1 ϩ␴*[␥ϩ ␩(1 ϩ␶␭)])tϪ1. We obtain the expression in equation (11) by applying the approximation that (1 ϩ x)t Ϸ 1 ϩ tx. The dependent variable for our analysis is the flow of net 17 The key predictions of the model for Mexican emigration still apply emigration, ⌬mijst, which is the ten-year time difference in even if migration from Mexico to the United States leaves U.S. wages the emigrant stock in equation (1) and corresponds exactly unchanged. This case is equivalent to setting ␭ equal to 0 in equation (11). 18 Implicit in our setup is that emigration is reversible, in which case to ␯*it in equation (12). This value is the net share of a birth individuals reoptimize their migration decision in each period. There is no year (i), gender ( j), and birth state (s) cohort that has option value to delaying emigration, as in Carrington et al. (1996). Our approach thus allows for return migration, though it does not explicitly emigrated during the previous ten-year interval. In the main model why it might occur. results, we group birth cohorts by three-year intervals, and

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 804 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 3.—BASELINE RESULTS FOR NET MIGRATION,NATIONAL BIRTH COHORTS (1) (2) (3) (4) Men Only Women Only Dependent Variable: Decadal Change in Net Migration Rate OLS IV IV IV log (MX cohort size/U.S. High school dropouts) 0.030 0.071 0.147 0.017 (2.24)* (4.12)** (5.09)** (0.83) log (MX GDP/U.S. GDP) at age 16 Ϫ0.219 Ϫ0.263 Ϫ0.359 Ϫ0.193 (3.32)** (3.94)** (3.74)** (2.25)* 10-year change log(MX GDP/U.S. GDP) Ϫ0.055 Ϫ0.146 Ϫ0.054 Ϫ0.127 (0.27) (0.71) (0.16) (0.48) Time trend 0.001 Ϫ0.002 Ϫ0.005 0.001 (0.24) (1.51) (2.34)* (0.53) Female cohort dummy Ϫ0.039 Ϫ0.045 (3.62)** (4.08)** Observations 166 166 83 83 R2 0.17 0.13 0.15 Note: Mexican cohort size is fixed at its initial value; the number of native U.S. high school dropouts is contemporaneous. The analysis is performed using one-year birth cohorts. GDP refers to GDP per capita. In IV regressions, log (MX birth cohort size/U.S. birth cohort size) is used as an instrument for log (MX birth cohort size/U.S. high school dropouts). T-statistics in parentheses: *significant at 5%; **significant at 1%.

in later results we use one- and five-year intervals. Follow- rate may increase or decrease as a cohort ages, depending on ing equation (12), the regression equation we estimate is whether network effects dominate wage-convergence ef- fects. As specified by equation (13), we interact initial labor ⌬ ϭ ͓␣ ϩ ␣ ͑ Ϫ ͔͒ mijst ln lijs 1 2 t 1 market conditions with the time since a cohort entered the Ϫ ϩ ln x ͓␤ ϩ ␤ ͑t Ϫ 1͔͒ (13) labor market (t 1). Networks may also affect the respon- is 1 2 siveness of emigration to labor market shocks (␴*), which

ϩ zst␾ ϩ I ϩ J ϩ S ϩ T ϩ εijst, we allow for by interacting initial state labor market condi- tions with measures of historical state migration networks. where lijs is the size of a Mexican state birth cohort relative to the number of U.S. high school dropouts in that birth B. Baseline Estimation Results cohort; xis is initial labor demand for a state birth cohort relative to the United States; zst captures labor market We begin with results for a sample of national aggregate shocks to state s in year t; and I, J, S, and T are fixed effects birth cohorts for Mexico and the United States, shown in for birth year, gender, birth state, and census year.19 By table 3. Though we have only 166 observations on one-year equation (12), the relative initial size of a Mexican birth birth and gender cohorts at the national level, the specifi- cohort (lijs) should be positively correlated with emigration, cation is useful for seeing whether there is any correlation while relative initial labor demand in Mexico ( xis) should between emigration and relative labor supply in aggregate be negatively correlated with emigration. We specify the data. initial difference in labor demand as the log ratio of state per In table 3, there is a strong, positive correlation between capita GDP to U.S. per capita GDP in the year a cohort first the size of a Mexican birth cohort (relative to the number of enters the labor market (assumed to be age 16). This is an U.S. high school dropouts in that cohort) and the emigration admittedly crude measure of labor demand, and we view the rate for the cohort. Our dependent variable is expressed as variable as controlling for initial conditions in a state more a share and the explanatory variables are in logs, so our broadly. We control for current-period labor market shocks parameter estimates give the decadal labor supply elasticity in a state using the ten-year change in state per capita GDP. of net migration. In column 1, based on OLS, a 10% We discuss results using other variables as well. increase in the relative size of a Mexican cohort is associ- From equation (12), the coefficient on initial relative ated with an increase in the decadal emigration rate of 0.3 labor supply in equation (13), ␣1 ϭ␩␴*, depends on the percentage points, with the effect precisely estimated. Con- emigrant supply elasticity, ␴*, which may vary by gender, sistent with theory, larger Mexican birth cohorts have higher age, or region. We begin with results that pool across emigration rates. Initial relative per capita GDP in Mexico is gender, age, and state and then disaggregate across Mexican negatively correlated with emigration, also as predicted by states and report results for specific age and gender sub- theory. State-level changes in per capita GDP enter with a groups. Under the dynamics specified by the model, the negative sign, as predicted by theory, but are imprecisely impact of initial labor market conditions on the emigration estimated. Column 2 gives instrumental variable estimates, where we control for measurement error or endogeneity in 19 To be precise, comparing equations (12) and (13), lijs is the inverse of the U.S. supply of low-skilled labor by instrumenting for the ᐉ* * i0, and xis is the inverse of x i0. We use the inverses to make the ratio of Mexican birth cohort size to U.S. high school regression results easier to interpret (such that in Mexico, positive labor supply shocks increase emigration, and positive labor demand shocks dropouts with the ratio of Mexican birth cohort size to U.S. decrease emigration). birth cohort size. The IV estimates are twice as large as the

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 THE GREAT MEXICAN EMIGRATION 805

TABLE 4.—BASELINE RESULTS FOR NET MIGRATION,STATE BIRTH COHORTS (1) (2) (3) (4) (4) Dependent variable: All Cohorts Men Only Women Only Decadal change in net migration rate OLS OLS IV IV IV log (MX state cohort size/U.S. high 0.0359 0.049 0.1443 0.1876 0.1053 school dropouts) (12.17)** (4.49)** (12.99)** (11.51)** (7.54)** log (MX state GDP/U.S. GDP) at Ϫ0.0788 Ϫ0.0307 Ϫ0.0217 Ϫ0.0261 Ϫ0.0168 age 16 (6.23)** (2.38)* (1.46) (1.13) (1.01) 10-year change log (MX state GDP/ Ϫ0.0148 0.0031 Ϫ0.0179 Ϫ0.0297 Ϫ0.0028 U.S. GDP) (0.63) (0.12) (0.62) (0.59) (0.09) Observations 2,258 2,258 2,258 1,124 1,134 R2 0.19 0.29 0.23 0.25 0.31 Fixed effects used State State, census year, sex, State, census year, sex, State, census year, sex, State, census year, sex, 10-year birth cohort 10-year birth cohort 10-year birth cohort 10-year birth cohort Note: Mexican state cohort size is fixed at its initial value; the number of native U.S. high school dropouts is contemporaneous. The analysis is performed using three-year birth cohorts. GDP refers to GDP per capita. In IV regressions, log (MX state birth cohort size/U.S. birth cohort size) is used as an instrument for log (MX state birth cohort size/U.S. high school dropouts). T-statistics in parentheses: *significant at 5%; **significant at 1%. Regressions in all tables use robust ses clustered at the cohort level and are weighted by birth cohort size.

OLS estimates and are precisely estimated.20 Columns 3 and common way across cohorts in our study (those aged 16 to 4 break out cohorts by gender, revealing that the effects of 50). Birth year fixed effects control for the size of the cohort size on emigration are larger for men than for average Mexican birth cohort, cohort-specific effects of women, a result we discuss below. U.S. enforcement policies, and other unexplained differ- Next we turn to the main results for the sample of ences in migration propensities between earlier and later- three-year birth cohorts using individual Mexican state birth born cohorts.22 cohorts as the unit of analysis. Given that small cohorts are These additional controls amplify the effect of labor measured with less precision, estimates using state-level supply on emigration but drive the effect of initial per capita census data are noisy, making net emigration heteroskedas- GDP to 0. Given the lack of substantial cross-state, cross- tic. To address measurement error, we use robust standard time variation in Mexican GDP per capita (Chiquiar, 2005), errors clustered at the level of birth states and trim the 2.5% census year and birth year fixed effects appear to remove tails of net emigration flows. most of the explanatory power of the initial level of devel- The first column of table 4 controls for birth state fixed opment. We do not interpret these results as evidence that effects only. Mexico has a long history of regional differ- labor demand is unimportant, but rather that even condi- ences in income levels, income growth, and population tioning on initial average income, there is a powerful inde- growth (Chiquiar, 2005). Birth state fixed effects remove pendent channel through which labor supply drives emigra- these and related sources of state-level heterogeneity from tion. the regression. Labor supply continues to work in the In column 3, we move from OLS to IV, following a manner that theory predicts: increases in Mexico’s cohort similar strategy of instrumentation as in table 3. The IV size (relative to the United States) drive emigration up. The estimates for labor supply are again larger. A 10% increase correlation between emigration and initial GDP remains in the base size of a Mexican cohort results in a 1.3% negative and precisely estimated. In column 2 of table 4, we increase in out-migration per decade over the working years introduce controls for gender, census year, and ten-year of that cohort. Columns 4 and 5 indicate that the impact of 21 birth cohorts. Census year fixed effects remove the effect labor supply on emigration is roughly twice as large for men of changes in border enforcement by U.S. immigration as for women. The migration decisions of men appear to be authorities, such as those introduced by the Immigration more responsive to labor market conditions on entry into the Reform and Control Act in the late 1980s and the expansion labor force, perhaps reflecting the tendency of families to in U.S. border fortifications in the 1990s (Hanson, 2006), invest in the migration of fathers and sons over mothers and provided the impact of these changes is experienced in a daughters. Later results suggest that over time, migration rates for women increase, allowing them to catch up (con- 20 These results suggest that in OLS regressions, inconsistency is due more to measurement error in the supply of low-skilled U.S. native labor sistent with the similar long-run migration rates for men and (which would tend to bias coefficient estimates on relative cohort size women seen in figure 2). toward 0) than to the endogeneity of U.S. labor supply to shocks to Based on the results in table 4, the correlation between initial Mexican migration (which would tend to introduce positive bias in the coefficient on relative cohort size). labor supply and emigration appears to be robustly positive. 21 Since a full set of birth year fixed effects would eliminate all variation The coefficient estimates in column 3 imply that moving a in U.S. labor supply, we limit the controls to dummies for ten-year birth Mexican state from the 25th to the 75th percentile of relative groups. In unreported results, we find that relative cohort size remains positively and significantly correlated with emigration, even with the full set of birth year dummies in the regression. in this specification, the effect 22 Based on theoretical results available on request from the authors, of cohort size on emigration is identified entirely on variation in popula- birth year fixed effects also control for cohort-specific pressures to migrate tion growth across Mexican states. internally.

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 806 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 5.—MIGRATION DYNAMICS AND NETWORK EFFECTS Interaction Effects Dynamic Effects by Terciles of 1924 Migration All All Top Tercile Bottom Tercile Dependent Variable: Mexican Mexican (Highest Middle (Lowest Decadal change in net migration rate States States All Migration) Tercile Migration) log (MX state cohort size/U.S. high school dropouts) 0.151 0.158 0.205 0.249 0.248 0.270 (13.85)** (13.76)** (11.30)** (7.55)** (7.90)** (7.67)** log (MX state GDP/U.S. GDP) at age 16 Ϫ0.022 Ϫ0.033 Ϫ0.043 Ϫ0.060 Ϫ0.009 Ϫ0.032 (1.48) (2.86)** (3.06)** (2.70)** (0.22) (1.96) 10-year change log (MX state GDP/U.S. GDP) Ϫ0.004 Ϫ0.050 Ϫ0.065 Ϫ0.129 Ϫ0.110 Ϫ0.009 (0.15) (2.27)* (2.63)** (2.88)** (2.35)* (0.33) Log Cohort Size Ratio ϫ 1924 Migration Rate 18.001 (3.19)** Log Cohort Size Ratio ϫ Distance to Train Ϫ0.0001 (4.85)** Log Cohort Size Ratio ϫ Years since 16 0.001 Ϫ0.001 0.003 Ϫ0.001 (1.92) (2.01)* (5.42)** (1.17) Log GDP Ratio (at 16) ϫ Years since 16 0.004 0.005 0.001 0.004 (5.53)** (4.48)** (1.37) (3.27)** Years since 16 (demeaned) 0.012 0.014 0.016 0.012 (4.13)** (3.16)** (3.07)** (2.27)* (Years since 16)2 Ϫ0.0001 Ϫ0.002 Ϫ0.0001 0.00001 (1.24) (2.89)** (0.65) (0.07) Observations 2,258 2,187 2,258 837 642 779 R2 0.21 0.2 0.2 0.09 0.31 0.01 Note: All regressions include Mexico state, census year, gender, and ten-year birth year fixed effects. All regressions are based on instrumental variables, using three-year birth cohorts. See text for discussion of instruments. T-statistics in parentheses: *significant at 5%; **significant at 1%. Regressions in all tables use robust standard errors clustered at the cohort level and are weighted by birth cohort size.

labor supply would raise the decennial emigration rate by 25 strongly to relative cohort size. In unreported results, we found percentage points against a mean emigration rate of 7%.23 no precisely estimated interaction effect between migration networks and initial relative per capita GDP. C. Network Effects and Migration Dynamics The interaction between cohort size and preexisting mi- gration patterns captures intergenerational migration net- So far, we have constrained the estimated elasticities to works. Father and uncles may relay their experiences to be constant across regions of Mexico. Preexisting migration networks could affect the emigration elasticity, ␴*, in equa- sons and nephews (and daughters and nieces), helping to tion (19), by making regions with stronger networks more create regional persistence in migration patterns. Munshi sensitive to changes in labor market conditions. We capture (2003), Orrenius and Zavodny (2005), and McKenzie and the strength of preexisting migration networks by either the Rapoport (2007) also provide evidence that networks (either state emigration rate in 1924 or the distance of a state to the within families or communities) lower the cost of emigrat- railroad that ran down Mexico’s spine in 1910, which U.S. ing from Mexico. labor contractors initially used to locate potential Mexican By their nature, intergenerational networks change slowly workers (Cardoso, 1980).24 over time. Equation (11) allows for intragenerational net- The first two columns of table 5 show results in which we works, which produce a dynamic migration response to interact relative cohort size with preexisting migration net- initial labor market conditions. The shock caused to initial works (all regressions in table 5 are based on IV estimation).25 migration will have effects that are dampened as a cohort In column 1, the interaction term is positive, indicating that ages if labor demand is relatively inelastic (␩ϽϽ 0), such Mexican states with a longer history of emigration are more that ␪Ͻ0, or that are amplified as a cohort ages if network responsive to variation in cohort size. There is a similar result effects from migration are strong (␥ϾϾ 0), in which case in column 2, where the interaction term is negative, implying ␪Ͼ0. The dynamic labor supply elasticity, ␪, can be that states closer to the migration railroad respond more estimated by interacting initial labor market conditions with the number of years since a cohort entered the labor force, 23 To perform this calculation, we express state cohort sizes as deviations assumed to be the current cohort age minus 16. from each state’s mean over the sample period and take the 25th and 75th The third column of table 5 shows these interactions percentiles of the distribution of these within-state deviations. 24 Consistent with a large literature on the subject, we find that distance estimated on the full sample of birth cohorts. For shocks to to the U.S. border is not a good proxy for the strength of migration relative labor supply, the pooled results indicate an interac- networks, whereas distance to the railroad is. 25 As in previous regressions, the high school dropout cohort size ratio tion effect that is in the same direction as the marginal effect is instrumented using the entire U.S. native-born population cohort size but insignificant. The labor demand interaction is in the ratio. Each column in table 5 interacts the high school dropout ratio with opposite direction from the uninteracted effect and strongly an exogenous variable, and in each case, we instrument for this using the interaction of the native population ratio with the same exogenous vari- significant. This suggests that the depression of migration able. caused by a positive GDP shock at age 16 is transitory, and

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 THE GREAT MEXICAN EMIGRATION 807

TABLE 6.—ALTERNATIVE SPECIFICATIONS AND SAMPLES FOR NET MIGRATION Unit of Aggregation One-Year Cohorts Two- and Three-Year Cohorts Five-Year Cohorts log (MX state cohort size/U.S. high school dropouts) 0.069 0.144 0.202 (9.50)** (12.99)** (11.32)** log (MX state GDP/U.S. GDP) at age 16 Ϫ0.032 Ϫ0.022 0.007 (2.88)** (1.46) (0.38) 10-year change log (MX state GDP/U.S. GDP) Ϫ0.011 Ϫ0.018 Ϫ0.042 (0.55) (0.62) (1.56) Observations 5,545 2,258 1,173 R2 0.18 0.23 0.34 Note: All regressions include Mexico state, census year, gender, and ten-year birth year fixed effects, and are based on instrumental variables, using log (MX state cohort size/U.S. native total) as an instrument for log (MX state cohort size/U.S. high school dropouts). T-statistics in parentheses: *significant at 5%; **significant at 1%. Regressions in all tables use robust standard errors clustered at the cohort level and are weighted by birth cohort size.

over subsequent decades, migrants compensate by leaving sented in column 3 of table 4, using one-year, three-year, or these states in larger numbers. five-year birth cohorts. As we move from less aggregated to Columns 4 to 6 repeat this exercise, dividing the sample more aggregated cohorts, the magnitude of the coefficient according to the strength of preexisting migration networks. on relative cohort size increases, which is exactly the These disaggregated results display intriguing heterogeneity opposite pattern we would expect if measurement error in the dynamic response to labor supply. In states with the were responsible for our results. Also, the precision of the strongest history of migration (the top tercile), the interac- coefficient estimates increases as we move to more aggre- tion effect is negative, suggesting that the dampening re- gated cohorts, despite the fact that the three-year cohort sponse of wages to migration is dominant. States with sample has 60% fewer observations than the one-year sam- intermediate levels of historical migration display a strongly ple and the five-year sample has 80% fewer observations. positive interaction between labor supply and years since The clear implication from this exercise is that rather than turning 16, indicating that migration accelerates over time. measurement error driving our results through spurious In states with nonexistent networks (bottom tercile), the correlation, it may understate the strength of the relation- dynamic interaction is insignificant. Taken together, these ships due to attenuation bias. results suggest that the networks created by labor supply– The use of five-year cohorts in table 6 helps address driven migration are self-reinforcing over time only if those another issue, related to the fact that our specification networks are new; states in which those networks were assumes that possibilities for labor substitution between already extant show a dampening rather than an acceleration younger and older cohorts can be subsumed into state, over time. Where historical migration networks are weakest, census year, and birth year fixed effects. As we expand the the migration networks initiated by labor supply shocks may size of a birth cohort, we allow for more flexible patterns of be too small to create new, self-reinforcing flows. labor substitution, though at the cost of reducing the sample size. Another way to address the issue of labor substitut- D. Robustness Checks ability is to include the size of adjacent cohorts in the Estimates of net migration are noisy, especially for estimation directly. In unreported results, we added as smaller states in the sample. We implement robustness regressors the log size of the previous and following state checks to examine the extent to which measurement error birth cohorts, each expressed relative to the size of the may be affecting the estimation. A particular concern is cohort pertaining to an observation. This addition leaves our raised by the fact that the base cohort size appears in the qualitative results on the impact of relative labor supply on numerator and denominator of the dependent variable as emigration unchanged. well as in log from as an independent variable. It might be Another issue has to do with omitted variables that could the case that we are picking up a spurious correlation arising be related to state population growth. Because changes in from the fact that the base cohort size is observed with error, the timing of the demographic transition are not randomly and a function of this measure error is then regressed on assigned, we may be concerned that some third factor exists itself. Fortunately, we have a simple way to modulate the that is driving both changes in cohort size and the decision degree of measurement error present in the data, which is to to migrate out of Mexico. In this case, the correlations we aggregate over larger or smaller cohorts than the three-year measure between Mexican cohort size and net migration birth year groups used so far in the analysis. As we calculate would be biased. Perhaps the most obvious underlying base cohort sizes and net migration rates on one-year source of heterogeneity in Mexico during this period is (five-year) cohorts, we should increase (decrease) the mea- differences in the timing of industrialization. In 1970, 12% surement error, which allows us to gauge the extent to of Mexican GDP derived from agriculture, but by 2000, this which this matters for our results. number had fallen to 5%. While early industrializing states, In table 6, we recreate the fixed effect regression pre- such as the Federal District and the state of Mexico, saw

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 808 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 7.—FINAL STOCK OF NET EMIGRANTS All Cohorts Men Aged Women Dependent variable: Stock of Net Migration Aged 40–50 40–50 Aged 40–50 log (MX state cohort size/U.S. high school dropouts) 0.372 0.261 0.451 (7.54)** (4.14)** (6.23)** log (MX state GDP/U.S. GDP) at age 16 0.134 0.08568 0.171 (2.10)* (1.00) (1.88) 10-year change log (MX state GDP/U.S. GDP) Ϫ0.021 0.014 Ϫ0.051 (0.35) (0.18) (0.59) Observations 840 413 427 R2 0.43 0.38 0.44 Note: All regressions are based on one-year birth cohorts, including Mexico state, census year, and 10-year birth year fixed effects and are based on instrumental variables, using log (MX state cohort size/U.S. native total) as an instrument for log (MX state cohort size/U.S. high school dropouts). T-statistics in parentheses; *significant at 5%; **significant at 1%. Regressions in all tables use robust standard errors clustered at the cohort level and are weighted by birth cohort size.

little change in their agricultural share, other states saw a estimates from table 4. We use the marginal effect from sharp decline. In unreported results, we examine whether column 3, which gives a decadal coefficient of 0.144 on the movement out of agriculture may have mutually driven the log base cohort size. From here we can calculate the population growth and migration during the period of our aggregate base cohort size for each birth year for the study by including the share of state GDP that comes from country as a whole and multiply the log of this quantity agriculture to the specification in column 3 of table 4. Our times the marginal effect and the number of decades over results on relative labor supply are unchanged, suggesting which they are observed. Of the 37.5 million born they are not being driven by unobserved heterogeneity in between 1960 and 1980, this method suggests that just over the timing of industrialization across Mexican states. 2.2 million emigrated as a result of labor supply growth. Using independent estimates that the stock of Mexican E. The Final Stock of Migration and Possible Future immigrants in the United States increased by 5.2 million Trends between 1977 and 1997 (that is, the years after these cohorts All of our results so far have followed the theoretical model had turned 16), this implies that 42% of total migration can in analyzing the flow of migration over time. We summarize be explained by labor supply growth in these 21 cohorts. our empirical section by presenting results on the impact of This figure is likely to be an underestimate because it uses labor supply and demand shifts on the stock of migrants, only a subset of cohorts to form the numerator of the meaning the total share of a cohort that has migrated out at by fraction and ignores the subsequent network-driven migra- the time they reach age 50. In order to measure these long-term tion caused by these individuals. Hence, labor supply effects, we must observe the cohort prior to migration age and growth in Mexico alone can account for one-third of the then be able to follow them until they reach the end of their total migration from that country to the United States over migration years. We therefore restrict this analysis to cohorts the past quarter-century. aged between 40 and 50, which were first observed in the data Going forward in time, growth in Mexico’s labor supply for those younger than age 15. This group of 843 cohorts gives relative to the United States is likely to slow substantially. us the ability to measure the impact of labor supply shocks on With Mexican fertility rates having fallen from 7 in 1960 to the long-term net stock of migrants. We include as demand 2.5 in 2000, labor supply shocks are likely to become a controls the GDP ratio when these cohorts turned 16, as well as much less significant push factor in Mexican labor outflows. the most recent change in state per capita GDP that they had Given the substantial role of labor supply in Mexican experienced. emigration to date, this is an important development. In this regression (shown in table 7), the coefficient To examine the implications of Mexico’s slowdown in estimate of 0.37 for relative labor supply indicates that for population growth for migration, we use the regression every three “extra” Mexican nationals (relative to the num- results to forecast future emigration rates by birth cohort. ber of U.S. natives) born in a given state, one of them will First, we sum the data by Mexican state and gender to arrive eventually migrate to the United States. Different from the at aggregate labor supply in Mexico (and in the United results on migration flows in table 6, the effects of labor States) for each year, from which we calculate the log labor supply shocks are somewhat larger for women than for men. supply ratio, with Mexico in the numerator. In order to The most likely explanation for this is reverse migration; construct the forecast of this log labor supply ratio, we ran while men have a higher propensity to migrate at younger an Arima model that included a first-order autoregressive ages, they are also more likely to return to Mexico later in and a first-order moving average component, as well as a life, and hence the use of older cohorts enhances the linear and quadratic time trend. Using the Arima model, we apparent sensitivity of women to labor supply shocks. then projected relative labor supply from 2000 through One way of understanding long-term emigration magni- 2020. The net migration rates across age for each cohort tudes is to simulate total out-migration using the parameter were then predicted using the parameter estimates from

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 THE GREAT MEXICAN EMIGRATION 809

FIGURE 4.—FUTURE EMIGRATION AND THE SLOWDOWN IN MEXICAN POPULATION GROWTH PREDICTED NET MIGRATION RATES BY BIRTH YEAR AND AGE:STOCK OF NET MIGRATION RELATIVE TO 1940 BIRTH COHORT .3

1980

.2 1970 1990 2000

2010 .1

0 2020 Additional fraction migrated

-.1 1960 16 26 36 46 Age Birth cohort sizes for 2000-2020 are forecast

column 3 of table 5, which gives us the dynamic effects of intragenerational migration networks, it does not control for cohort size estimated using the entire Mexican population. dynamic changes in intergenerational networks, which fall Figure 4 plots the resulting net emigration rates by decade outside our framework. from 1960 to 2020, expressed relative to the 1940 cohort (that is, subtracting values for 1940 from each cohort). This V. Discussion exercise is equivalent to forecasting changes in emigration due to labor supply, holding labor demand, enforcement The surge in labor flows from Mexico to the United policies, and other factors constant. By expressing emigra- States over the past 25 years has made international migra- tion relative to a base cohort, we isolate changes in past and tion the subject of intense policy debate in the two countries. future emigration that the empirical results suggest are Mexico accounts for fully one-third of U.S. immigration associated with changes in relative labor supply. since 1980, and the United States is now the country of In figure 4, labor supply–induced emigration falls for residence for nearly one-fifth of young working-age Mexi- cohorts born between 1940 and 1960, owing to the large can males. Despite the magnitude of these labor move- increase in U.S. population associated with the baby boom. ments, little academic research attempts to account for the From 1960 to 1980, relative labor supply growth in Mexico scale of Mexican emigration. leads to a dramatic surge in emigration. But this surge peaks Our approach is to examine the contribution of labor supply for the 1980 birth cohort, which would have begun to enter shocks to the labor exodus from Mexico by exploiting varia- the labor market in the late 1990s. Emigration rates fall for tion across Mexican states in the evolution of population all subsequent cohorts as population growth in Mexico growth. Larger birth cohorts in Mexico have higher rates of begins to decline to U.S. levels. By the time the 2020 birth emigration, consistent with positive labor supply shocks con- cohort comes of age, emigration rates would have returned tributing to out-migration. Differential growth in labor supply to levels equal to those of the 1940 birth cohort. Holding between Mexico and the United States over 1960 to 1984 can labor demand and enforcement policies constant, it would account for one-third of observed Mexican migration to the appear that emigration from Mexico is peaking today and United States over 1977 to 2000. that labor supply–driven pressures for labor outflows will Population growth in Mexico has decreased dramatically. weaken in subsequent decades. Of course, shocks to labor Indeed, the decline in fertility in Mexico between 1970 and demand or U.S. immigration policy could produce much 2000 is one of the fastest ever recorded. Will slowing larger or much smaller emigration rates, depending on their population growth contribute to slower increases in emigra- realizations. Also, while the forecast in figure 4 controls for tion rates in the future? Absent network effects (and holding

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021 810 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

labor demand constant), the answer would appear to be yes. Chiquiar, Daniel, and Gordon Hanson, “International Migration, Self- The direct effects of differential labor supply growth should Selection, and the Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the U.S.,” Journal of Political Economy 113 (2005), 239–281. already be dwindling. The sharp increase that started in Durand, Jorge, Douglas S. Massey, and Rene M. Zenteno, “Mexican 1960 came to an end in 1980, and so cohorts coming of Immigration in the U.S.,” Latin American Research Review 36:1 migration age today are not experiencing the shocks that (2001), 107–127. Fernandez-Huertas, Jesus, “New Evidence on Emigrant Selection,” Co- those only a decade ago faced. The mechanical migration lumbia University mimeograph (2008). pressures caused by population growth are now pressing on Gathmann, Christina, “The Effects of Enforcement on Illegal Markets: Mexico’s southern border, because neighboring Central Evidence from Migrant Smuggling on the Southwestern Border,” IZA discussion paper no. 1004 (2004). American countries have not undergone the rapid demo- Grogger, Jeffrey, and Stephen J. Trejo, Falling Behind or Moving Up? The graphic transition seen in Mexico. Intergenerational Progress of (San Francisco: However, emigration from Mexico shows evidence of Public Policy Institute of California, 2002). Hanson, Gordon H., “Illegal Migration from Mexico to the U.S.,” Journal network effects. Emigration is more responsive to Mexico- of Economic Literature 44 (2006), 869–924. U.S. differences in labor supply in states that have stronger Hanson, Gordon H., and Antonio Spilimbergo, “Illegal Immigration, historical migration networks, and the response of emigra- Border Enforcement and Relative Wages: Evidence from Appre- hensions at the U.S.-Mexico Border,” American Economic Review tion to initial labor supply differences appears to accelerate 89 (1999), 1337–1357. over time in a manner consistent with early migrants’ Hatton, Timothy J., and Jeffrey G. Williamson, “Demographic and Eco- encouraging later migrants to move abroad. Network effects nomic Pressure on Emigration out of Africa,” Scandinavian Jour- nal of Economics 105 (2003), 465–486. could make the impact of differential Mexico-U.S. labor- “What Fundamentals Drive World Migration?” (pp. 15–38), in supply growth over the 1960 to 1980 period long lived, as George J. Borjas and Jeff Crisp (Eds.), Poverty, International the current generation of migrants eases migration for later Migration, and Asylum (New York: Macmillan, 2005). Ibarraran, Pablo, and Darren Lubotsky, “Mexican Immigration and Self- generations. In this event, emigration from Mexico may Selection: New Evidence from the 2000 Mexican Census” (pp. continue to accelerate for some time, even as population 159–192), in George J. Borjas (Ed.), Mexican Immigration to the growth in the two countries continues to converge. United States (Chicago: University of Chicago and National Bu- reau of Economic Research, 2007). Martinez, Jose, and Christopher Woodruff, “Selectivity of Migrants from REFERENCES Mexico: What Does Net Migration Tell Us?” University of Cali- Aydemir, Abdurrahman, and George J. Borjas, “A Comparative Analysis fornia, San Diego mimeograph (2007). of the Labor Market Impact of International Migration: , Massey, Douglas S., and Kristin E. Espinosa, “What’s Driving Mexico- Mexico, and the U.S.,” Journal of the European Economic Asso- U.S. Migration? A Theoretical, Empirical, and Policy Analysis,” ciation 5 (2007), 663–708. American Journal of Sociology 102 (1997), 939–999. Blanchard, Oliver, and Lawrence Katz, “Regional Evolutions,” Brookings Massey, Douglas S., and Rene Zenteno, “The Dynamics of Mass Migra- Papers on Economic Activity (1992), 1–75. tion,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 96 (1999), Blau, Francine D., and Lawrence M. Kahn, “Gender and Assimilation among 5328–5335. Mexican Americans” (pp. 57–106), in George J. Borjas (Ed.), Mexican McKenzie, David, and Hillel Rapoport, “Network Effects and the Dynam- Immigration to the United States (Chicago: University of Chicago and ics of Migration and Inequality: Theory and Evidence from Mex- National Bureau of Economic Research, 2007). ico,” Journal of Development Economics 84 (2007), 1–24. Borjas, George J., “The Earnings of Mexican Immigrants in the U.S.,” Mishra, Prachi, “Emigration and Wages in Source Countries: Evidence Journal of Development Economics 51 (1996), 69–98. from Mexico,” Journal of Development Economics 31 (2006), “Native Internal Migration and the Labor Market Impact of 177–183. Immigration,” Journal of Human Resources 41 (2006), 221–258. Munshi, Kaivan, “Networks in the Modern Economy: Mexican Migrants Borjas, George J., Jeffrey Grogger, and Gordon H. Hanson, “Imperfect in the US Labor Market,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 Substitution between Immigrants and Natives: A Reappraisal,” (2003), 549–597. NBER working paper no. 13821 (2008). Orrenius, Pia M., and Madeline Zavodny, “Self-Selection among Undoc- Borjas, George J., and Lawrence F. Katz, “The Evolution of the Mexican- umented Immigrants from Mexico,” Journal of Development Eco- Born Workforce in the United States,” (pp. 13–56) in George J. nomics 78 (2005), 215–240. Borjas (Ed.), Mexican Immigration to the United States (Chicago: Ottaviono, Gianmarco, and Giovanni Peri, “Rethinking the Effects of University of Chicago Press and National Bureau of Economic Immigration on Wages,” University of California, Davis, mimeo- Research, 2007). graph (2006). Buck, Steve, Celine Ferre, Nakagawe Hideyuki, Lourdes Rodriguez- Smith, James P., “Assimilation across the Latino Generations,” American Chamussy, and Elisabeth Sadoulet, “Rural Out-Migration in Mex- Economic Review 93 (2003), 315–319. ico and Brazil,” background paper for the World Development Taylor, J. Edward, “Undocumented Mexico-U.S. Migration and the Re- Report, 2008 (2007). turns to Households in Rural Mexico,” American Journal of Agri- Cardoso, Lawrence, Mexican Emigration to the U.S., 1897–1931 Tucson: cultural Economics 69 (1987), 626–638. University of Arizona Press, 1980. Tuiran, R., V. Partida, O. Mojarro, and E. Zuniga, “Fertility in Mexico; Carrington, William J., Enrica Detragiache, and Tara Viswanath, “Migra- Trends and Forecast” (New York: United Nations Population Di- tion with Endogenous Moving Costs,” American Economic Review vision, 2002). 86 (1996), 909–930. Woodruff, Christopher, and Rene Zenteno, “Migration Networks and Chiquiar, Daniel, “Why Mexico’s Regional Income Convergence Broke Microenterprises in Mexico,” University of California, San Diego Down,” Journal of Development Economics 77 (2005), 257–275. (2006).

Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/REST_a_00031 by guest on 28 September 2021