On the Fractional Dimension of Partially Ordered Sets

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

On the Fractional Dimension of Partially Ordered Sets On the Fractional Dimension of Partially Ordered Sets STEFAN FELSNER Bel l Communications Research South Street Morristown NJ USA and Technische Uni versitat Berlin Fachbereich Mathematik Strasse des Juni Berlin Germany Email address felsnermathtub erlinde WILLIAM T TROTTER Bel l Communications Research South Street L Morristown NJ USA and Depart ment of Mathematics Arizona State University Tempe AZ USA Email address wttb ellcorecom Date Septemb er Abstract We use a variety of combinatorial techniques to prove several theorems concerning fractional dimension of partially ordered sets In particular we settle a conjecture of Brightwell and Scheinerman by showing that the fractional dimension of a p oset is never more than the maximum degree plus one Furthermore when the maximum degree k is at least two we show that equality holds if and only if one of the comp onents of the p oset is isomorphic to S the standard example of a k dimensional k +1 p oset When w the fractional dimension of a p oset P of width w is less than w unless P contains S If P is a p oset containing an antichain A and at most n other p oints where n we show that the w fractional dimension of P is less than n unless P contains S If P contains an antichain A such that all n antichains disjoint from A have size at most w then the fractional dimension of P is at most w and this b ound is b est p ossible Mathematics Sub ject Classication A C Key words Partially p oset dimension fractional dimension degree Intro duction In this pap er we consider a partial ly ordered set P as a pair X P and refer to X as the ground set and P as the partial order We nd it convenient to use the short form poset for a partially ordered set and we use the term subposet to refer to a p oset induced by a subset of the ground set Let P X P b e a p oset and let F fM M g b e a multiset of linear extensions 1 t of P Brightwell and Scheinerman call F a k fold realizer of P if for each incomparable pair x y there are at least k linear extensions in F which reverse the pair x y ie jfi i t x y in M gj k The fractional dimension of P denoted by fdimP is i then dened in as the least real numb er q for which there exists a k fold realizer F fM M g of P so that k t q it is easily veried that the least upp er b ound 1 t of such real numb ers q is indeed attained Using this terminology the dimension of P denoted by dimP is just the least t for which there exists a fold realizer of P It follows immediately that fdimP dimP for every p oset P In this pap er we will nd it convenient to use the following probabilistic interpretation of this concept Let P X P b e a p oset and let F fM M g b e a multiset of 1 t linear extensions of P We consider the linear extensions of F as outcomes in a uniform sample space For an incomparable pair x y the probability that x is over y in F is FRACTIONAL DIMENSION given by fi i t x y in M g Prob x y i F t The fractional dimension of P is then the least rational numb er q so that there exists a multiset F fM M g of linear extensions of P with Prob x y q for 1 t F every incomparable pair x y For each n the height two p oset containing n minimal elements fx x x g 1 2 n and n maximal elements fy y y g with x y if and only if i j for all i j 1 2 n i j n will b e denoted by S The p oset S is known as the standard example of a n n ndimensional p oset As noted in fdimS dimS n n n This pap er is organized as follows In Section we intro duce some terminology nec essary for our theorems and review facts ab out lexicographic sums In Section we formulate the results relating the fractional dimension of a p oset to its degree In Sec tion we present a key technical lemma involving the algorithmic transformation of linear orders into linear extensions and present the pro of for the main theorem of Section In Section we present the forbidden subp oset characterization of the degree inequality In Sections and we derive two other forbidden subp oset characterizations of inequalities for fractional dimension In b oth cases equality is only p ossible when P contains a full dimensional standard example as a subp oset In Section we present an inequality relating the fractional dimension of a p oset P X P to the width of the subp oset induced by X A where A is an antichain The b ounds obtained in this case are slightly stronger than the corresp onding b ounds for dimension We also prove that our b ounds are b est p ossible In Section we characterize Hiraguchis inequality for fractional dimension Finally in Section we prop ose some new problems for fractional dimension Notation and Terminology Let P X P b e a p oset We denote the set of incomparable pairs of P by incP Now let F fM M M g b e a nonempty multiset of linear orders on X We call F a 1 2 t multirealizer of P if P F ie each M is a linear extension of P and prob x y i F for every x y incP When F is a multirealizer of P we dene the value of F denoted value F as the P least rational numb er q so that prob x y q for every x y incP The F fractional dimension of P is just the least rational q so that P has a multirealizer F of value q Recall that an incomparable pair x y in a p oset P X P is critical if any p oint less than x is less than y and any p oint greater than y is greater than x We denote the set of all critical pairs of P by critP The following elementary prop osition rst noted by Rabinovitch and Rival is stated formally to emphasize the fundamentally imp ortant role played by critical pairs in dimension theory PROPOSITION Let P X P be a poset and let F be a multiset of linear exten sions of P Then F is a multirealizer of P if and only if prob x y for every F x y critP We say that a linear order L reverses the critical pair x y if x y in L Similarly we say L reverses the set S crit P if L reverses each pair in S The following remark is noted in S FELSNER AND W T TROTTER PROPOSITION Let P X P be poset and let q be a rational number Then fdimP q if and only if there exists a multiset F of linear extensions of P so that Prob x y q whenever x y critP F Let P X P b e a p oset and let D fY Y Q x X g b e a family of p osets x x x indexed by the p oint set X of P The lexicographic sum of D over P is the p oset S whose p oint set consists of all pairs of the form x y where x X and y Y The partial x x in S if and only if x y order on S is dened by setting x y 2 x 1 x 2 1 x x in P or 1 2 in Q y x x and y x x 1 2 x 1 2 1 Both dimension and fractional dimension are well b ehaved with resp ect to lexicographic sums The statement for dimension is due to Hiraguchi and the statement for frac tional dimension is given in PROPOSITION Let S be the lexicographic sum of D fY x X g over P x X P Then dimS maxfdimP max dimY g xX x fdimS maxffdimP max fdimY g xX x A p oset S is decomposable with resp ect to lexicographic sums if it is isomorphic to a lexicographic sum of a family D fY x X g over a p oset P X P where jX j x and jY j for at least one x X Otherwise we say S is indecomposable x Given a p oint x in a p oset P X P let D x denote the set of all p oints which are P less than x in P and U x the set of p oints which are greater than x in P Whenever P the meaning is clear from the context we will drop the subscripts and just write D x and U x Two p oints x and y are said to b e interchangeable in a p oset P X P if D x D y and U x U y Thus x and y are interchangeable if and only if b oth x y and y x are critical pairs Note that a p oset with an interchangeable pair is decomp osable with resp ect to lexicographic sums unless it is a element antichain Fractional Dimension and Degree For a p oint x in a p oset P X P dene the degree of x denoted deg x as the numb er of p oints comparable but not equal to x in P Then let P denote the maximum degree of P ie P maxfdeg x x X g The following theorem is proved by Brightwell and Scheinerman in THEOREM If P X P is a poset then fdimP P In the next section we prove the following improved b ound which was conjectured in THEOREM If P X P is a poset and is not an antichain then fdimP P As noted in fdimS n S for all n so Theorem is b est p ossible n n In Section we show that when the the maximum degree of a connected p oset P is at least the inequality in Theorem is strict unless P is the standard example of dimension P This result has much the same avor as Bro oks theorem which asserts that the chromatic numb er of a connected graph is at most one more than the maximum degree with equality holding if and only if the graph is a complete graph or an o dd cycle It also provides another instance in which the role played by standard examples FRACTIONAL DIMENSION in dimension theory is analogous to the role played by complete graphs in the theory of graph coloring This parallel is explored in greater detail in the monograph We will in fact prove a result that is slightly stronger than Theorem Given a p oint x in a xed p oset P X P let D x D x fxg Then let deg x jD xj and D dene P maxfdeg x x X g The set U x and the quantities deg x P D U D U are dened dually With this notation we can now state the result we actually prove THEOREM If P X P is a poset then fdimP P D Note that Theorem has Theorem as an immediate corollary Since fractional dimension is dual ie a p oset and its dual have the
Recommended publications
  • The Lorenz Curve
    Charting Income Inequality The Lorenz Curve Resources for policy making Module 000 Charting Income Inequality The Lorenz Curve Resources for policy making Charting Income Inequality The Lorenz Curve by Lorenzo Giovanni Bellù, Agricultural Policy Support Service, Policy Assistance Division, FAO, Rome, Italy Paolo Liberati, University of Urbino, "Carlo Bo", Institute of Economics, Urbino, Italy for the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, FAO About EASYPol The EASYPol home page is available at: www.fao.org/easypol EASYPol is a multilingual repository of freely downloadable resources for policy making in agriculture, rural development and food security. The resources are the results of research and field work by policy experts at FAO. The site is maintained by FAO’s Policy Assistance Support Service, Policy and Programme Development Support Division, FAO. This modules is part of the resource package Analysis and monitoring of socio-economic impacts of policies. The designations employed and the presentation of the material in this information product do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. © FAO November 2005: All rights reserved. Reproduction and dissemination of material contained on FAO's Web site for educational or other non-commercial purposes are authorized without any prior written permission from the copyright holders provided the source is fully acknowledged. Reproduction of material for resale or other commercial purposes is prohibited without the written permission of the copyright holders.
    [Show full text]
  • Inequality Measurement Development Issues No
    Development Strategy and Policy Analysis Unit w Development Policy and Analysis Division Department of Economic and Social Affairs Inequality Measurement Development Issues No. 2 21 October 2015 Comprehending the impact of policy changes on the distribu- tion of income first requires a good portrayal of that distribution. Summary There are various ways to accomplish this, including graphical and mathematical approaches that range from simplistic to more There are many measures of inequality that, when intricate methods. All of these can be used to provide a complete combined, provide nuance and depth to our understanding picture of the concentration of income, to compare and rank of how income is distributed. Choosing which measure to different income distributions, and to examine the implications use requires understanding the strengths and weaknesses of alternative policy options. of each, and how they can complement each other to An inequality measure is often a function that ascribes a value provide a complete picture. to a specific distribution of income in a way that allows direct and objective comparisons across different distributions. To do this, inequality measures should have certain properties and behave in a certain way given certain events. For example, moving $1 from the ratio of the area between the two curves (Lorenz curve and a richer person to a poorer person should lead to a lower level of 45-degree line) to the area beneath the 45-degree line. In the inequality. No single measure can satisfy all properties though, so figure above, it is equal to A/(A+B). A higher Gini coefficient the choice of one measure over others involves trade-offs.
    [Show full text]
  • SOLVING ONE-VARIABLE INEQUALITIES 9.1.1 and 9.1.2
    SOLVING ONE-VARIABLE INEQUALITIES 9.1.1 and 9.1.2 To solve an inequality in one variable, first change it to an equation (a mathematical sentence with an “=” sign) and then solve. Place the solution, called a “boundary point”, on a number line. This point separates the number line into two regions. The boundary point is included in the solution for situations that involve ≥ or ≤, and excluded from situations that involve strictly > or <. On the number line boundary points that are included in the solutions are shown with a solid filled-in circle and excluded solutions are shown with an open circle. Next, choose a number from within each region separated by the boundary point, and check if the number is true or false in the original inequality. If it is true, then every number in that region is a solution to the inequality. If it is false, then no number in that region is a solution to the inequality. For additional information, see the Math Notes boxes in Lessons 9.1.1 and 9.1.3. Example 1 3x − (x + 2) = 0 3x − x − 2 = 0 Solve: 3x – (x + 2) ≥ 0 Change to an equation and solve. 2x = 2 x = 1 Place the solution (boundary point) on the number line. Because x = 1 is also a x solution to the inequality (≥), we use a filled-in dot. Test x = 0 Test x = 3 Test a number on each side of the boundary 3⋅ 0 − 0 + 2 ≥ 0 3⋅ 3 − 3 + 2 ≥ 0 ( ) ( ) point in the original inequality. Highlight −2 ≥ 0 4 ≥ 0 the region containing numbers that make false true the inequality true.
    [Show full text]
  • The Cauchy-Schwarz Inequality
    The Cauchy-Schwarz Inequality Proofs and applications in various spaces Cauchy-Schwarz olikhet Bevis och tillämpningar i olika rum Thomas Wigren Faculty of Technology and Science Mathematics, Bachelor Degree Project 15.0 ECTS Credits Supervisor: Prof. Mohammad Sal Moslehian Examiner: Niclas Bernhoff October 2015 THE CAUCHY-SCHWARZ INEQUALITY THOMAS WIGREN Abstract. We give some background information about the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality including its history. We then continue by providing a number of proofs for the inequality in its classical form using various proof tech- niques, including proofs without words. Next we build up the theory of inner product spaces from metric and normed spaces and show applications of the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality in each content, including the triangle inequality, Minkowski's inequality and H¨older'sinequality. In the final part we present a few problems with solutions, some proved by the author and some by others. 2010 Mathematics Subject Classification. 26D15. Key words and phrases. Cauchy-Schwarz inequality, mathematical induction, triangle in- equality, Pythagorean theorem, arithmetic-geometric means inequality, inner product space. 1 2 THOMAS WIGREN 1. Table of contents Contents 1. Table of contents2 2. Introduction3 3. Historical perspectives4 4. Some proofs of the C-S inequality5 4.1. C-S inequality for real numbers5 4.2. C-S inequality for complex numbers 14 4.3. Proofs without words 15 5. C-S inequality in various spaces 19 6. Problems involving the C-S inequality 29 References 34 CAUCHY-SCHWARZ INEQUALITY 3 2. Introduction The Cauchy-Schwarz inequality may be regarded as one of the most impor- tant inequalities in mathematics.
    [Show full text]
  • The FKG Inequality for Partially Ordered Algebras
    J Theor Probab (2008) 21: 449–458 DOI 10.1007/s10959-007-0117-7 The FKG Inequality for Partially Ordered Algebras Siddhartha Sahi Received: 20 December 2006 / Revised: 14 June 2007 / Published online: 24 August 2007 © Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2007 Abstract The FKG inequality asserts that for a distributive lattice with log- supermodular probability measure, any two increasing functions are positively corre- lated. In this paper we extend this result to functions with values in partially ordered algebras, such as algebras of matrices and polynomials. Keywords FKG inequality · Distributive lattice · Ahlswede-Daykin inequality · Correlation inequality · Partially ordered algebras 1 Introduction Let 2S be the lattice of all subsets of a finite set S, partially ordered by set inclusion. A function f : 2S → R is said to be increasing if f(α)− f(β) is positive for all β ⊆ α. (Here and elsewhere by a positive number we mean one which is ≥0.) Given a probability measure μ on 2S we define the expectation and covariance of functions by Eμ(f ) := μ(α)f (α), α∈2S Cμ(f, g) := Eμ(fg) − Eμ(f )Eμ(g). The FKG inequality [8]assertsiff,g are increasing, and μ satisfies μ(α ∪ β)μ(α ∩ β) ≥ μ(α)μ(β) for all α, β ⊆ S. (1) then one has Cμ(f, g) ≥ 0. This research was supported by an NSF grant. S. Sahi () Department of Mathematics, Rutgers University, New Brunswick, NJ 08903, USA e-mail: [email protected] 450 J Theor Probab (2008) 21: 449–458 A special case of this inequality was previously discovered by Harris [11] and used by him to establish lower bounds for the critical probability for percolation.
    [Show full text]
  • Inequality and Armed Conflict: Evidence and Data
    Inequality and Armed Conflict: Evidence and Data AUTHORS: KARIM BAHGAT GRAY BARRETT KENDRA DUPUY SCOTT GATES SOLVEIG HILLESUND HÅVARD MOKLEIV NYGÅRD (PROJECT LEADER) SIRI AAS RUSTAD HÅVARD STRAND HENRIK URDAL GUDRUN ØSTBY April 12, 2017 Background report for the UN and World Bank Flagship study on development and conflict prevention Table of Contents 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY IV 2 INEQUALITY AND CONFLICT: THE STATE OF THE ART 1 VERTICAL INEQUALITY AND CONFLICT: INCONSISTENT EMPIRICAL FINDINGS 2 2.1.1 EARLY ROOTS OF THE INEQUALITY-CONFLICT DEBATE: CLASS AND REGIME TYPE 3 2.1.2 LAND INEQUALITY AS A CAUSE OF CONFLICT 3 2.1.3 ECONOMIC CHANGE AS A SALVE OR TRIGGER FOR CONFLICT 4 2.1.4 MIXED AND INCONCLUSIVE FINDINGS ON VERTICAL INEQUALITY AND CONFLICT 4 2.1.5 THE GREED-GRIEVANCE DEBATE 6 2.1.6 FROM VERTICAL TO HORIZONTAL INEQUALITY 9 HORIZONTAL INEQUALITIES AND CONFLICT 10 2.1.7 DEFINITIONS AND OVERVIEW OF THE HORIZONTAL INEQUALITY ARGUMENT 11 2.1.8 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY BETWEEN ETHNIC GROUPS 14 2.1.9 SOCIAL INEQUALITY BETWEEN ETHNIC GROUPS 18 2.1.10 POLITICAL INEQUALITY BETWEEN ETHNIC GROUPS 19 2.1.11 OTHER GROUP-IDENTIFIERS 21 2.1.12 SPATIAL INEQUALITY 22 CONTEXTUAL FACTORS 23 WITHIN-GROUP INEQUALITY 26 THE CHALLENGE OF CAUSALITY 27 CONCLUSION 32 3 FROM OBJECTIVE TO PERCEIVED HORIZONTAL INEQUALITIES: WHAT DO WE KNOW? 35 INTRODUCTION 35 LITERATURE REVIEW 35 3.1.1 DO PERCEIVED INEQUALITIES INCREASE THE RISK OF CONFLICT? MEASUREMENT AND FINDINGS 37 3.1.2 DO OBJECTIVE AND PERCEIVED INEQUALITIES OVERLAP? MISPERCEPTIONS AND MANIPULATION 41 3.1.3 DO PERCEPTIONS
    [Show full text]
  • Solving Linear Inequalities
    Solving Linear Inequalities Farah Dawood Some Application of Inequalities Inequalities are used more often in real life than equalities: ❖ Businesses use inequalities to control inventory, plan production lines, produce pricing models, and for shipping. ❖ Linear programming is a branch of mathematics that uses systems of lin e a r in e q u a litie s to solve re a l-world problems. ❖ Financial occupations often require the use of linear inequalities such as accountants, auditors, budget analysts and insurance underwriters to determine pricing and set budgets. Inequality Symbols What is a linear Inequality ? ● Linear inequality is an inequality which involves a linear function (with first power). ● Linear inequality contains one of the symbols of inequality ● The solution of a linear inequality in two variable like Ax+By>C is an ordered pair (x,y) that make an inequality true. Solving Linear Inequalities For One Variable ` ● Solve the inequality as you would an equation which means that "whatever you do to one side, you must do to the other side". ● If you multiply or divide by a negative number, REVERSE the inequality symbol. ● We can write the answer in interval notation. Steps for Graphing Solution on Number Line ● Use an open circle on the graph if your inequality symbol is greater than or less than. ● Use a closed circle on the graph if your inequality symbol is greater than or equal to OR less than or equal to. ● Arrow will point to the left if the inequality symbol is less than. ● Arrow will point to the right if the inequality symbol is greater than.
    [Show full text]
  • Inequalities in the European Union—A Partial Order Analysis of the Main Indicators
    sustainability Article Inequalities in the European Union—A Partial Order Analysis of the Main Indicators Lars Carlsen 1,* and Rainer Bruggemann 2 1 Awareness Center, Linkøpingvej 35, Trekroner, DK-4000 Roskilde, Denmark 2 Department of Ecohydrology, Leibniz-Institute of Freshwater Ecology and Inland Fisheries, Oskar—Kösters-Str. 11, D-92421 Schwandorf, Germany; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Abstract: The inequality within the 27 European member states has been studied. Six indicators proclaimed by Eurostat to be the main indicators charactere the countries: (i) the relative median at-risk-of-poverty gap, (ii) the income distribution, (iii) the income share of the bottom 40% of the population, (iv) the purchasing power adjusted GDP per capita, (v) the adjusted gross disposable income of households per capita and (vi) the asylum applications by state of procedure. The resulting multi-indicator system was analyzed applying partial ordering methodology, i.e., including all indicators simultaneously without any pretreatment. The degree of inequality was studied for the years 2010, 2015 and 2019. The EU member states were partially ordered and ranked. For all three years Luxembourg, The Netherlands, Austria, and Finland are found to be highly ranked, i.e., having rather low inequality. Bulgaria and Romania are, on the other hand, for all three years ranked low, with the highest degree of inequality. Excluding the asylum indicator, the risk-poverty-gap and the adjusted gross disposable income were found as the most important indicators. If, however, the asylum application is included, this indicator turns out as the most important for the mutual Citation: Carlsen, L.; Bruggemann, R.
    [Show full text]
  • Mapping Recent Inequality Trends in Developing Countries
    Mapping recent inequality trends in developing countries Rebecca Simson Working paper 24 May 2018 III Working paper 24 Rebecca Simson LSE International Inequalities Institute The International Inequalities Institute (III) based at the London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE) aims to be the world’s leading centre for interdisciplinary research on inequalities and create real impact through policy solutions that tackle the issue. The Institute provides a genuinely interdisciplinary forum unlike any other, bringing together expertise from across the School and drawing on the thinking of experts from every continent across the globe to produce high quality research and innovation in the field of inequalities. In addition to our working papers series all these publications are available to download free from our website: www.lse.ac.uk/III For further information on the work of the Institute, please contact the Institute Manager, Liza Ryan at [email protected] International Inequalities Institute The London School of Economics and Political Science Houghton Street London WC2A 2AE Email: [email protected] Web site: www.lse.ac.uk/III @LSEInequalities © Rebecca Simson. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including ã notice, is given to the source. 2 III Working paper 24 Rebecca Simson Editorial note and acknowledgements This paper was written with the engagement and input of the project research committee: Mike Savage, Beverley Skeggs, Rana Zincir-Celal, Duncan Green, Paul Segal and Pedro Mendes Loureiro. Students from the LSE M.Sc. course, ‘Social Scientific Analysis of Inequalities’, also provided a wealth of useful inputs to this study.
    [Show full text]
  • Week 4 – Complex Numbers
    Week 4 – Complex Numbers Richard Earl∗ Mathematical Institute, Oxford, OX1 2LB, November 2003 Abstract Cartesian and polar form of a complex number. The Argand diagram. Roots of unity. The relation- ship between exponential and trigonometric functions. The geometry of the Argand diagram. 1 The Need For Complex Numbers All of you will know that the two roots of the quadratic equation ax2 + bx + c =0 are b √b2 4ac x = − ± − (1) 2a and solving quadratic equations is something that mathematicians have been able to do since the time of the Babylonians. When b2 4ac > 0 then these two roots are real and distinct; graphically they are where the curve y = ax2 + bx−+ c cuts the x-axis. When b2 4ac =0then we have one real root and the curve just touches the x-axis here. But what happens when− b2 4ac < 0? Then there are no real solutions to the equation as no real squares to give the negative b2 − 4ac. From the graphical point of view the curve y = ax2 + bx + c lies entirely above or below the x-axis.− 3 4 4 3.5 2 3 3 2.5 1 2 2 1.5 1 1 -1 1 2 3 0.5 -1 -1 1 2 3 -1 1 2 3 Distinct real roots Repeated real root Complex roots It is only comparatively recently that mathematicians have been comfortable with these roots when b2 4ac < 0. During the Renaissance the quadratic would have been considered unsolvable or its roots would− have been called imaginary. (The term ‘imaginary’ was first used by the French Mathematician René Descartes (1596-1650).
    [Show full text]
  • Inequalities and Their Measurement
    IZA DP No. 1219 Inequalities and Their Measurement Almas Heshmati DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER July 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Inequalities and Their Measurement Almas Heshmati MTT Economic Research and IZA Bonn Discussion Paper No. 1219 July 2004 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 Email: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of the institute. Research disseminated by IZA may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit company supported by Deutsche Post World Net. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its research networks, research support, and visitors and doctoral programs. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available on the IZA website (www.iza.org) or directly from the author. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1219 July 2004 ABSTRACT Inequalities and Their Measurement This paper is a review of the recent advances in the measurement of inequality.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 11: Economic and Social Inequality
    Principles of Economics in Context, Second Edition – Sample Chapter for Early Release Principles of Economics in Context, Second Edition CHAPTER 11: ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL INEQUALITY As the United States economy began recovering from the Great Recession of 2007– 2009, economic data indicated that the vast majority of all income growth was going to the richest Americans. From 2009–2012, over 90 percent of new income accrued to just the top 1 percent of income earners. As the economy recovered further, new income distribution was less lopsided, but still uneven. The top 1 percent captured over half of all income growth in the United States over the period 2009–2015.1 The trend toward higher economic inequality is not limited to the United States. Over the last few decades, inequality has been increasing in most industrialized nations, as well as most of Asia, including China and India. And while inequality has generally been decreasing in Latin American and sub-Saharan African countries, these regions still have the highest overall levels of inequality.2 Analysis of inequality, like most economic issues, involves both positive and normative questions. Positive analysis can help us measure inequality, determine whether it is increasing or decreasing, and explore the causes and consequences of inequality. But whether current levels of inequality are acceptable, and what policies, if any, should be implemented to counter inequality are normative questions. While our discussion of inequality in this chapter focuses mainly on positive analysis, we will also consider the ethical and policy debates that are often driven by strongly held values. 1.
    [Show full text]