How Legislative Democracy Creates Political Parties Michael Koß, LMU

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How Legislative Democracy Creates Political Parties Michael Koß, LMU How legislative democracy creates political parties Michael Koß, LMU Munich forthcoming in: Comparative Politics 51/1, 2018 Introduction Standard accounts on the rise of political parties emphasize the role of the electoral arena. Here, the nationalization of politics arguably led to a homogenization of voting behavior and, eventually, the emergence of coherent political parties.1 From this perspective, the legislative arena appears as “chapter 2” of electoral democracy and is largely determined by party system properties.2 The present article challenges this view and provides empirical evidence for Duverger’s claim that political parties can also emerge in the legislative arena. This argument acknowledges that the legislative arena often constitutes chapter one of democracy at large.3 To capture the different dimensions of democracy, this paper introduces the term “legislative democracy” in which all legislation is subject to consent by assemblies. Legislative democracy often precedes electoral democracy as it may exist without universal suffrage, but not vice versa. Despite the temporal precedence of legislative democracy, scholars have primarily focused on the advent of electoral democracy. Previous research examined the choice of electoral systems, the enfranchisement of voters, and the arrival of the secret ballot.4 In contrast, there exist hardly any analyses of the evolution of parties in legislatures apart from work done on the British House of Commons and the Congress of the United States.5 This article aims to fill this gap by exploring the emergence of political parties in the lower chambers of two emerging European democracies, Sweden and France. The analysis focuses on the period between 1866 and 1958, i.e. the first wave of democratization.6 Legislative democracy creates political parties by means of two institutional mechanisms: control over the plenary agenda in the plenary and powerful committees.7 The centralization of agenda control in the hands of governments vertically differentiates the legislature and serves as an incentive for legislators to exert an ex ante impact on legislation by means of voting discipline maintained by political parties. Alternatively, powerful legislative committees horizontally differentiate the legislature and allow legislators to exert an ex post impact on legislation. This renders seats on powerful committees (and in particular committee chairs) legislative mega-seats, i.e. desirable offices which allow for considerable impact on legislation.8 Given that parties serve as the gatekeepers to seats on powerful committees, their establishment can be regarded as the alternative path of legislative democracy creating political parties. These alternative paths pose the question under which circumstances parties emerged as managers of government agenda control or, alternatively, as gatekeepers of access to powerful committees. In order to uncover the causal mechanism which allowed parties to emerge in legislatures, this paper performs a comparative process-tracing analysis primarily based on transcript evidence that has so far been largely overlooked: the committee reports and parliamentary proceedings underlying procedural reforms. More specifically, the process-tracing analysis focuses on the 37 reforms that were debated on the plenary floor after the beginning of competitive elections in 1866 (Sweden) and 1871 (France), respectively. The Swedish and French legislatures are most similar with respect to potential independent variables explaining the distribution of agenda control and committee power, but most different regarding the ultimate outcome of procedural reform. In both legislatures, a multi-party system evolved and coalition and minority governments were prevalent, both of which were arguably conducive to the emergence of both decentralized agenda control and powerful committees. Committees were indeed empowered in both legislatures; however, in 1958, 2 a procedural path change occurred in the French National Assembly during which agenda control was centralized and committees were disempowered. As the evidence presented here suggests, parties emerge as a response to an increasing quest for procedural efficiency in the wake of the Industrial Revolution and the dawn of competitive elections. Individual legislators preferred the creation of powerful committees which provided them with a return for investing emerging party leaderships with the power to select committee members, namely the prospect of mega-seats on committees. Since party membership became the most important selection criterion for committee membership, the empowerment of committees therefore caused the emergence of parties as gatekeepers of committee access. In contrast, individual legislators were only willing to unilaterally surrender their inherited powers to control the plenary agenda to party leaders if anti-system legislators could credibly threaten to obstruct legislation. Unlike their pro-system counterparts, anti-system legislators have no interest in cooperation with others. Rather, “an anti-system opposition abides a belief system that does not share the values of the political order within which it operates” and aims to either break away from the polity it operates in or to abolish democratic rule as such.9 Obstruction is here defined as the exploitation of procedural loopholes in order to delay or derail legislation.10 Obstructive anti- system legislators are willing to accept full-blown legislative deadlock. In this sense, maintaining legislative democracy by means of a centralization of agenda control not only helps democratic parties to thrive and survive, but also democracy at large. Legislative organization and political parties Scholarship on the advent of political parties mostly focuses on the electoral arena. Here, only coherent political parties were able to fulfil voters’ demand for identifiable and coherent policy 3 platforms. In turn, candidates were increasingly elected on party tickets rather than individual merits which allowed parties to impose discipline upon formerly autonomous legislators.11 In this respect, party organization and party system properties such as fragmentation, patterns of government alternation, or government formation are regarded as crucial for the evolution of legislative organization.12 This article aims to show that this is not the whole story. Parties also emerge in the legislative arena independent of and prior to electoral democracy. Representative institutions were originally neither devised to foster democracy nor the emergence of political parties.13 Historically, individual legislators dominated parliamentary procedure. This is why the “legislative state of nature” is characterized by equal rights of all legislators.14 Two departures from the legislative state of nature allow for the emergence of political parties in the legislative arena: vertical differentiation, i.e. the centralization of agenda control and horizontal differentiation, i.e. the establishment of powerful committees. Agenda control refers to the ability to introduce, amend, and discuss legislation.15 These features correspond to three dimensions of agenda control: timetable, positive, and negative control. Timetable control refers to decisions about which proposals are debated. If governments or majorities control the legislative timetable, they possess gatekeeping power. Positive agenda control encompasses the power to amend legislation or prevent amendments, which is accomplished through restrictive rules (which exclude certain kinds of amendments) or closed rules (which forbid all amendments) as well as the power to make last amendments.16 Negative agenda control comprises measures affecting the length of legislative debates such as closure procedures, which terminate such debates. 4 Agenda control can be defined as centralized if governments or majorities enjoy privileges in two of the three dimensions (timetable, positive, and negative agenda control). The centralization of agenda control is an institutional prerequisite for the dominance of political parties in the legislative arena because serves as an incentive for the cohesion of governing parties and opposition parties alike.17 This cohesion ensures that governments include the policy preferences of their legislators in an ex ante fashion: Since governments cannot rely on compromises with disciplined opposition parties, they have to ensure their proposals reflect the views of rank-and- file legislators to get passed. The second institutional mechanism allowing parties to dominate legislative organization are powerful committees. Committees provide coalition partners without control of executive departments with the expertise necessary to control the actions of the respective minister and to either alter or stop proposals which deviate from their preferences.18 In order to enable legislators to do so, three features of committees are essential: First, committees need to be able to rewrite bill proposals, which not only allows them to change government proposals but also ensures that it is the amended committee version of the proposal which becomes the basis of the plenary debate. Second, permanence, which allows committee members to acquire the expertise which distinguishes them from their ordinary peers not sitting on committees. Third, committees need to be congruent with executive departments which makes it more likely that committees are able to oversee the activities of particular ministers. Committees are powerful
Recommended publications
  • Managing Meritocracy in Clientelistic Democracies∗
    Managing Meritocracy in Clientelistic Democracies∗ Sarah Brierleyy Washington University in St Louis May 8, 2018 Abstract Competitive recruitment for certain public-sector positions can co-exist with partisan hiring for others. Menial positions are valuable for sustaining party machines. Manipulating profes- sional positions, on the other hand, can undermine the functioning of the state. Accordingly, politicians will interfere in hiring partisans to menial position but select professional bureau- crats on meritocratic criteria. I test my argument using novel bureaucrat-level data from Ghana (N=18,778) and leverage an exogenous change in the governing party to investigate hiring pat- terns. The results suggest that partisan bias is confined to menial jobs. The findings shed light on the mixed findings regarding the effect of electoral competition on patronage; competition may dissuade politicians from interfering in hiring to top-rank positions while encouraging them to recruit partisans to lower-ranked positions [123 words]. ∗I thank Brian Crisp, Stefano Fiorin, Barbara Geddes, Mai Hassan, George Ofosu, Dan Posner, Margit Tavits, Mike Thies and Daniel Triesman, as well as participants at the African Studies Association Annual Conference (2017) for their comments. I also thank Gangyi Sun for excellent research assistance. yAssistant Professor, Department of Political Science, Washington University in St. Louis. Email: [email protected]. 1 Whether civil servants are hired by merit or on partisan criteria has broad implications for state capacity and the overall health of democracy (O’Dwyer, 2006; Grzymala-Busse, 2007; Geddes, 1994). When politicians exchange jobs with partisans, then these jobs may not be essential to the running of the state.
    [Show full text]
  • 7972-1 Comparative Political Institutions (Clark)
    COMPARATIVE POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS Political Science 7972 Prof Wm A Clark Thursdays 9:00-12:00 213 Stubbs Hall 210 Stubbs Hall [email protected] Fall 2013 COURSE DESCRIPTION This course is dedicated to the comparative analysis of political institutions, which in comparative politics are viewed as either formal rules or organizations. The primary orientation of the course material lies in state governmental institutions, although some social institutions will also be examined. The course focuses on what has come to be called the "new institutionalism," which adopts a more decidedly structural or state-centric approach to politics. It emphasizes the relative autonomy of political institutions, and thus seeks to present a counterweight to the predominant view of politics as merely a reflection of the aggregation of individual preferences and behaviors. If it can be argued that individuals and institutions impact each other, the new institutionalism focuses primary attention on how relatively autonomous political institutions (i.e., rules and organizations) affect individual political behavior. COURSE REQUIREMENTS Each student’s semester grade will be determined on the basis of four tasks, detailed below. [1] Research paper: weighted at 35% of the course grade. This paper is to be modeled on a typical conference paper. The paper should focus on the downstream consequence(s) of a national or sub-national institutional variable; that is, it should adopt an institutional factor (or factors) as the independent variable(s). It should focus on any country other than the USA, and may adopt any traditional form of institutional analysis. It must be fully cited and written to professional standards.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Science 2 Introduction to Comparative Politics 3 Units; 3
    Political Science 2 Introduction to Comparative Politics 3 units; 3 hours lecture Recommended Preparation: Political Science 1 and eligibility for English 1A Credit, degree applicable Transfer CSU, UC In this course students will analyze political systems of different countries in a comparative context. Emphasis will be placed on studying the differences and similarities of governmental systems found in developed democratic nation-states. Developing countries, regional systems, and new democracies will also be analyzed to illustrate the complex nature of creating and maintaining a functioning nation-state system. Course Objectives: 1. Identify and assess the basic theory of comparative political analysis and the commonly applied methodology. 2. Identify and evaluate the structures and functions common to all political systems. 3. Analyze the geopolitical, cultural, and historical antecedents of nation-states for comparative analysis. 4. Evaluate cultural-political systems in developing non-democratic nation-states. 5. Assess procedures used in democratic political systems in the determination of policy and legislation. 6. Evaluate and examine the major institutions that contribute to the political process. 7. Describe and analyze the European Union as a model of regional integration. 8. Identify and evaluate current government systems. 9. Assess the ways in which political parties, interest groups, and public opinion effect the political process. Student Learning Outcomes: SLO#1 Political Systems- In a written essay, the students will discuss and critically analyze both differences and similarities found among different political systems as they pertain to the functions that their institutions perform. SLO#2 Institutional Choices- In a written essay, students will demonstrate knowledge and analyze the difference between presidential and parliamentary system and the impact they have one the policymaking process.
    [Show full text]
  • SIS 802 Comparative Politics
    Ph.D. Seminar in Comparative Politics SIS 802, Fall 2016 School of International Service American University COURSE INFORMATION Professor: Matthew M. Taylor Email: [email protected] Classes will be held on Tuesdays, 2:35-5:15pm Office hours: Wednesdays (11:30pm-3:30pm) and by appointment. In the case of appointments, please email me at least two days in advance to schedule. Office: SIS 350 COURSE DESCRIPTION Comparative political science is one of the four traditional subfields of political science. It differs from international relations in its focus on individual countries and regions, and its comparison across units – national, subnational, actors, and substantive themes. Yet it is vital to scholars of international relations, not least because of its ability to explain differences in the basic postures of national and subnational actors, as well as in its focus on key variables of interest to international relations, such as democratization, the organization of state decision-making, and state capacity. Both subfields have benefited historically from considerable methodological and theoretical cross-fertilization which has shaped the study of international affairs significantly. The first section of the course focuses on the epistemology of comparative political science, seeking to understand how we know what we know, the accumulation of knowledge, and the objectivity of the social sciences. The remainder of the course addresses substantive debates in the field, although students are encouraged to critically address the theoretical and methodological approaches that are used to explore these substantive issues. COURSE OBJECTIVES This course will introduce students to the field, analyzing many of the essential components of comparative political science: themes, debates, and concepts, as well as different theoretical and methodological approaches.
    [Show full text]
  • Elector System Design and Ethnic Separatism: a Rationalist Approach to Ethnic Politics in Eastern Europe
    Illinois Wesleyan University Digital Commons @ IWU Honors Projects Political Science Department Spring 2000 Elector System Design and Ethnic Separatism: A Rationalist Approach to Ethnic Politics in Eastern Europe Eric Wesselkamper '00 Illinois Wesleyan University Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/polisci_honproj Part of the Political Science Commons Recommended Citation Wesselkamper '00, Eric, "Elector System Design and Ethnic Separatism: A Rationalist Approach to Ethnic Politics in Eastern Europe" (2000). Honors Projects. 7. https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/polisci_honproj/7 This Article is protected by copyright and/or related rights. It has been brought to you by Digital Commons @ IWU with permission from the rights-holder(s). You are free to use this material in any way that is permitted by the copyright and related rights legislation that applies to your use. For other uses you need to obtain permission from the rights-holder(s) directly, unless additional rights are indicated by a Creative Commons license in the record and/ or on the work itself. This material has been accepted for inclusion by faculty at Illinois Wesleyan University. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ©Copyright is owned by the author of this document. • Electoral System Design and Ethnic Separatism A Rationalist Approach to Ethnic Politics in Eastern Europe Eric Wesselkamper Spring 2000 The resurgence ofnationalism taking place throughout Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union raises important questions with respect to ethnic political mobilization, particularly with respect to the potentialfor ethnic separatism. Moreover, the region provides scholars an excellent setting in which to study the political effects ofconstitutional choices.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Best Practices: a Model Annual State of the Parliament Report*
    GLOBAL BEST PRACTICES: A MODEL ANNUAL STATE OF THE PARLIAMENT REPORT* A Strategic Monitoring and Reporting Tool for Promoting Democratic Parliaments Worldwide (2005) • Contact: Professor Keith Henderson, [email protected]; [email protected] or [email protected] A number of experts from other regions made significant contributions to developing this framework, including Sandra Elena from Argentina, Violaine Autheman from France and Rosie Zigormo from Zimbabwe, as well as the Canadian Parliamentary Centre. IFES Parliamentary Tool Kit Model State of Parliament Report: Framework TABLE OF CONTENTS IFES Parliamentary Toolkit: Multiple Uses of the Annual State of Parliament Report 3 IFES Parliamentary Toolkit: Parliamentary Transparency and Accountability Standards 4 Abstract 5 1. Overview: Country Context and Methodology 6 a. The Functions of Parliament in the Country Context 6 b. Scope of the State of Parliament Report: the IFES Parliamentary Transparency and Accountability Standards, PTAS 8 c. Multifaceted Methodology 9 2. Relevant International and Domestic Legal and Institutional Framework 11 a. International and Regional Obligations 11 b. Constitutional Standards 12 c. Country Legal Framework 12 d. Country Institutional Framework 12 3. Assessment of the Level of Compliance with the PTAS 13 PTAS.1: Independence of Parliament 13 PTAS.2: Free and Fair Parliamentary Elections 14 PTAS.3: Transparent, Adequate Political Financing and Compensation 14 PTAS.4: Representative Parliament 16 PTAS.5: Security of Tenure 16 PTAS.6:
    [Show full text]
  • Downloads of Previous Issue Since Publication (25Th of January 2011–10Th of August 2011): 946
    Volume 4, Number 2, July 2011 CompaJ O U R N A Lr Oa F tive Politics ISSN 1338-1385 GG NON-DETERMINANTSGOFGCORRUPTION:G AGSCEPTICALGVIEWGFROMGEASTERNGEUROPE Anris ZIMELIS GG COSMOPOLITISMGASGTHEGENDGOFGPATRIOTISMG AMONGGSLOVENIANGYOUTH Lea NAHTIGAL and Vladimir PREBILIČ GG THEGEUROPEANGFUTURESGANDGCOHESIVEGEUROPE:GG EU2020GSTRATEGYGANDGCOHESIONGPOLICYGWITHGFLEXIBLEG INTEGRATION Attila ÁGH GG BOSNIAGANDGHERZEGOVINAGBETWEENGDAYTONGANDG BRUSSELS Rudi KOCJANČIČ GG DELIBERATIONGANDGONLINEGPARTICIPATION:G THEGCASEGOFGTHEGSLOVENIANGPORTALG“IGPROPOSEGTOGTHEG GOVERNMENT” Tanja OBLAK-ČRNIČ, Jernej PRODNIK and Nika TRBIŽAN GG NETWORKEDGCITIES’GRESPONSESGTOGGLOBALG PROBLEMS:GG AGTYPOLOGY Nikita CHIU Journal of Comparative Politics 2 Editorial Team General Editor General Editor Miro Haček Peter Csányi Department of Political Science Pan European University Faculty of Social Sciences Institute of Political Science University of Ljubljana Tomášikova 20, 821 02 Kardeljeva ploščad 5, Ljubljana, Slovenia Bratislava, Slovakia [email protected] [email protected] Assistant Editor Irena Bačlija Department of Political Science Faculty of Social Sciences University of Ljubljana Kardeljeva ploščad 5, Ljubljana, Slovenia [email protected] JCP uses two-sided peer review process before publication. Those wishing to sub- mit papers should send their e-version to either of the General Editors at one of the addresses above in compliance with the Submission Guidelines. The views ex- pressed are neither those of either of co-publishers. Authors
    [Show full text]
  • Altered States: a Comparison of Separation of Powers in the United States and in the United Kingdom
    Cleveland State University EngagedScholarship@CSU Law Faculty Articles and Essays Faculty Scholarship 1990 Altered States: A Comparison of Separation of Powers in the United States and in the United Kingdom James G. Wilson Cleveland State University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/fac_articles Part of the Comparative and Foreign Law Commons, and the Comparative Politics Commons How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! Original Citation James G. Wilson, Altered States: A Comparison of Separation of Powers in the United States and in the United Kingdom, 18 Hastings Constitutional Law Quarterly 125 (1990) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at EngagedScholarship@CSU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law Faculty Articles and Essays by an authorized administrator of EngagedScholarship@CSU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. +(,121/,1( Citation: 18 Hastings Const. L.Q. 125 1990-1991 Content downloaded/printed from HeinOnline (http://heinonline.org) Wed Sep 12 11:33:36 2012 -- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License -- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text. -- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your HeinOnline license, please use: https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do? &operation=go&searchType=0 &lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=0094-5617 Altered States: A Comparison of Separation of Powers in the United States and in the United Kingdom By JAMES G.
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Legislatures Thursdays: 2:00 – 4:50Pm Location: 210 Stubbs
    POLI 7971: Comparative Legislatures Thursdays: 2:00 – 4:50pm Location: 210 Stubbs Professor: Dr. Yann Kerevel Office Hours: Wednesdays 1-3pm or by appt. Office: 230 Stubbs Email: [email protected] Overview The study of legislative institutions has been dominated by research on the U.S. Congress. Despite this singular focus, the design of legislatures, their organization, their relations with other branches of government, the methods by which legislative representatives reach office, and the way in which representatives serve their constituents vary widely across countries. This course is designed to introduce students to research on legislatures across the globe. Required Readings Most readings are peer-reviewed journal articles easily found through the LSU library system or Google Scholar. Any book chapters will be provided in PDF format on Moodle. Evaluation Weekly writing assignments and discussion questions: 20% Each week in which there are assigned readings, I expect students to write a 2- 3 page critical review of the week’s readings. In your review, you should address at least some of the questions listed below. In addition to writing the 2-page review, I also expect students to submit at least 3 questions related to the readings for discussion. The writing assignment and the 3 questions are due by 12pm on the day of class and should be submitted electronically by email. To receive full credit for these assignments, they must all be turned in on time, they must meet the basic requirements, and it must be clear to me you have read all of the week’s material. I will not be providing weekly, individual feedback on these assignments but I will reach out to individual students early in the semester with comments.
    [Show full text]
  • The Historical Development of Comparative Federal Studies
    THE HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENT OF • in the allocation of taxing powers and COMPARATIVE FEDERAL STUDIES resources; in the character of federal government representative institutions and Professor Ronald L. Watts in the degree of regional input to federal policy-making; in the procedures for INTRODUCTION resolving internal conflicts between Political events in various parts of the world governments; during the past two decades have attracted • in the processes established to facilitate increasing attention to comparative federal collaboration between interdependent studies. But the comparative scholarly literature governments; attempting to assess the nature of federalism and to understand such issues as the theory and • and in the procedures for formal and practice of federalism, the strengths and informal adaptation and change. weaknesses of federal political solutions, the Clearly then, there is no single pure model design and operation of various federal systems of federation that is applicable everywhere. and the processes of political integration and Even where similar institutions are adopted, disintegration has a long history. This paper will different circumstances have often made them trace that history and the development of the operate differently. A classic illustration of this comparative study of federalism, federal is the operation of the similar formal constitution political systems and federations as a amendment procedures in Switzerland and background for the following chapters which Australia requiring ratification by double examine federal theories and the methodologies majorities in a referendum. In a century this that have been employed in these studies. procedure produced over 110 constitutional Much of the scholarly study of federalism amendments in Switzerland and only eight in has taken the form of examining individual Australia (Watts, 1999: 2).
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Politics of Federalism
    Political Science Entry ID: 9780199756223-xxxx Version Date: uploaddate Citation Style: Humanities Comparative Politics of Federalism Jenna Bednar University of Michigan Srinivas Parinandi University of Michigan Introduction General Overviews Datasets Country Reports and Qualitative Data Journals Definitions of Federalism Federalism’s Purpose and Performance Economic Growth Economic Efficiency Deficit Reduction Corruption Redistribution and Unified Policy-Making Policy Innovation & Diffusion Peace-Preserving Federalism Secession Participation Effect on the Party System Understanding Variation in Federal Performance Why Safeguards are Necessary Institutional Safeguards of Federalism Dynamics in Federal-State Power INTRODUCTION Federalism is a system of government that sits uneasily between a unitary government with administrative decentralization and a confederacy comprised of independent states that choose to coordinate their activity in some realms, such as defense or trade. The comparative study of federations is broad, ranging from internal fiscal arrangements to economic performance to political representation and identity. Uniting these diverse fields is a common interest in federalism as a system of government, adopted for a purpose, and failing or meeting aspirations. Federal systems vary widely in construction, in purpose, and in practice. The system effects are complex and often unexpected. Hence adopting the federal form is an important constitutional decision with significant---and sometimes surprising---consequences. In this overview, we concentrate on two aspects of the comparative federalism literature: the postulated benefits of federalism and theories to explain its inconsistent performance. GENERAL OVERVIEWS As a field, political science has been working on (and arguing about) an understanding of what federalism might achieve and under what conditions it might be successful since Alexander Hamilton, John Jay, and especially James Madison wrote as **Publius** (1787).
    [Show full text]
  • Party Politics and Presidentialism
    From Perils to Pearls? Presidentialism as an Answer to the Challenge to Party Government Dennis-Jonathan Mann Draft version—please do not cite Introduction This paper seeks to link recent arguments about a decline of—or, at least, a challenge to—party government to another body of literature that distinguishes two systems of government, a presi- dential from a parliamentary one. The point of departure is that, especially with regard to presi- dentialism, the nature of the party system is regarded as crucial factor in explaining the success or failure of presidential democracy. While the academic debate about the presidential system of government has been shaped by Juan Linz’s (1990a) influential essay “The Perils of Presidentialism” and, accordingly, has been focusing on the Spanish and Latin American cases of developing democracies, here, I am trying to relate this debate to the literature on political parties in Western Europe. Therefore, some of the specific arguments made in the presidentialism literature—especially how to sustain de- mocracy in a process of transition from an autocracy—will not be applicable. Here, the puzzle is rather how to adapt to a changing role of political parties in consolidated democracies. The paper is divided into three parts; the first part will summarize the main arguments cur- rently advanced in the party government literature. The second part of the paper with then re- visit the main findings of the system of government literature with regard to the role of political parties and/or the party system. Building upon this discussion, the last part of the paper then seeks to establish a theoretical relationship between recent changes in party government and the logics of a presidential system of government.
    [Show full text]