The Economic Assimilation of Irish Famine Migrants to the

William J. Collins and Ariell Zimran

February 2019

The repeated failure of 's potato crop in the late 1840s led to a major famine and sparked a surge in migration to the US. We build a new dataset of Irish immigrants and their sons by linking males from 1850 to 1880 US census records. For comparison, we also link German and British immigrants, their sons, and males from US native-headed households. We document a decline in the observable human capital of famine-era Irish migrants compared to pre-famine Irish migrants and to other groups in the 1850 census, as well as worse labor market outcomes. The disparity in labor market outcomes persists into the next generation when immigrants’ and natives’ sons are compared in 1880. Nonetheless, we find strong evidence of intergenerational convergence in that famine-era Irish sons experienced a much smaller gap in occupational status in 1880 than their fathers did in 1850. The disparities are even smaller when the Irish children are compared to those from observationally similar native white households. A descriptive analysis of mobility for the children of the famine Irish indicates that having a more Catholic surname and being born in Ireland were associated with less upward mobility. Our results contribute to literatures on immigrant assimilation, migration, and the Age of Mass Migration.

JEL: F22, J61, J62, N31, O15 Keywords: Migration, , Assimilation, Intergenerational Mobility, Irish Famine

Contact: [email protected]; [email protected]

The authors thank Joseph Ferrie, Tim Hatton, Nick Holtkamp, Joel Mokyr, Cormac Ó Gráda, Marianne Wanamaker; seminar participants at Auburn University, UCLA, the University of Minnesota, Vanderbilt University, and William & Mary; and conference participants at the 2019 ASSA Meeting for helpful suggestions. Claire Whittaker provided excellent research assistance. Collins is the Terence E. Adderley Jr. Professor of Economics at Vanderbilt University and a Research Associate of the NBER. Zimran is an Assistant Professor of Economics at Vanderbilt University and a Faculty Research Fellow of the NBER. 1. Introduction Ireland’s in the late 1840s marked a turning point in the country’s demographic and economic history. In 1841, the population numbered just over 8 million; it is estimated that the famine caused the death of about one million Irish and drove another million to emigrate by the early 1850s (Ó Gráda 1999, chapter 3).1 Most of the Irish emigrants settled in the United States, where virtually open borders gave sanctuary from the horrors of starvation and disease (Ó Gráda 2019). The US ultimately absorbed over 500,000 new arrivals from Ireland between the famine’s onset in 1846 and 1850 (Ferenczi and Wilcox 1929; Barde, Carter, and Sutch 2006).2 This paper picks up the emigrants’ story on American shores and builds new datasets to study their and their children’s labor market outcomes in comparison to those of US natives and immigrants from other countries. Irish migration to the US had been growing since the 1830s as part of a general rise in transatlantic migration (Mokyr and Ó Gráda 1982; Ó Gráda 1983; Cohn 2009); but the sharp increase in arrivals during the famine dwarfed previous arrival cohorts. The unprecedentedly large stream of arrivals induced by the famine marked the start of the “Age of Mass Migration,” and likely comprised the largest group of refugees from a single source that the US has ever absorbed relative to the size of its population.3 This change in the volume of Irish immigrants coincided with an apparent change in their characteristics relative to earlier, more prosperous Irish immigrants (Handlin 1991 [1941] p. 51; Miller 1985 p. 295; Anbinder 1992, p. 7), and exacerbated the view of many Americans at the time that the Irish migrants’ relative poverty, tendency to live near one another, and predominantly Catholic religion were barriers to their assimilation and, therefore, justified restrictions on immigration and immigrants’ rights (Anbinder 1992; Hirota 2017). Such concerns have resurfaced throughout US history in response to the arrival of poor or culturally “different” immigrants. In this case, the nativist response was severe, culminating in the political ascent of the “Know Nothings” (Anbinder 1992; Alsan, Eriksson, and Niemesh 2019). This paper studies the economic status and labor market assimilation of the famine-era Irish immigrants, with a particular focus on the adult labor market outcomes of the immigrants’ children. Although the group’s size and historical prominence makes them particularly interesting to study,

1 Ó Gráda (1999, ch. 3) discusses the dating of the famine and the challenges of quantifying deaths and emigration. 2 Cohn (2009, pp. 26-27) describes difficulties in determining the number of Irish immigrants from official US immigration statistics before 1850. 3 For perspective, refugees and asylees granted permanent resident status under the Displaced Persons Act (1948) averaged about 118,000 per year from 1950-52, at the program’s peak (Barde, Carter, and Sutch 2006, p. 1-632); the Mariel Boatlift entailed approximately 125,000 Cuban migrants in 1980 (Card 1990, p. 245).

1 data constraints have made it difficult to do so. To overcome these constraints, we constructed a new micro-level dataset by linking males born in Ireland, Germany, Britain, and the US from the 1850 to the 1880 complete-count US censuses.4 The linked dataset is large, national in scope, and conservatively constructed to reduce false matches. It includes household heads and their sons; therefore, it allows us to compare labor market outcomes for immigrant and native groups over two generations, and to consider the second generation’s labor market outcomes in light of variation in their early life circumstances. Moreover, the new dataset’s panel structure helps us to avoid biases from cohort quality changes and selective return migration that confound inferences from cross- sectional census data (Lubotsky 2007; Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson 2014). That is, because we follow a fixed set of men over time, there are no changes in sample composition. The inclusion of German and British immigrants, who comprised the next largest groups of immigrants in this period, allows for useful comparisons across arrival cohorts and across immigrant groups, which in turn helps illustrate the distinctiveness of the famine-era Irish. The children’s economic outcomes are especially interesting in the context of concerns about the long-run assimilation of new immigrant groups. Immigrants’ children’s outcomes have garnered considerable attention in the literature on the economics of migration (e.g., Borjas 1992, 1993; Card, DiNardo, and Estes 2000; Card 2005; Caponi 2011; Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson 2014; Alexander and Ward 2018). But to our knowledge, this is the first paper to study the children of the large cohorts of immigrants who arrived in the mid-nineteenth century US, at the start of the Age of Mass Migration. This is also one of a small number of papers that address long-run patterns of economic assimilation by refugee immigrants or their children, whose experiences and outcomes may differ from those of other migrant groups (Edin, Fredriksson, and Åslund 2003; Cortes 2004; Beaman 2012; Evans and Fitzgerald 2017).5 Our focus on the immigrants’ children is also a practical consequence of the historical census data’s limitations. The censuses of this era did not inquire directly about each immigrant’s year of arrival. This poses a major challenge to discerning between those who arrived before or after the Irish famine’s onset and, in general, to any study of immigrant assimilation in this early period.6

4 Linking females from childhood to adulthood is difficult due to name changes at marriage. 5 We use the term “refugee” here because a large number of the Irish migrants were permanently driven from home by a severe ecological disaster and ensuing economic and social dislocation in the late 1840s. The modern literature focuses on refugees that meet a particular legal definition established in the postwar period; see Hatton (2012) for a brief review. 6 One reason much of the recent literature on the Age of Mass Migration focuses on the early twentieth century is that the census microdata report year of immigration starting in 1900. Before 1850, the census did not

2 Nonetheless, in 1850, we can determine the arrival cohort for many household heads by examining their children’s birth year and birth place information.7 This approach definitively categorizes the household head’s arrival cohort (“pre-famine” or “famine-era”) for about two-thirds of the sons of Irish immigrants.8 The relatively high classification rate makes studying the children’s outcomes attractive—we know whether their household head arrived before or during the famine, observe their childhood household characteristics in 1850 in detail, and then see their labor market outcomes as prime-aged adult workers in 1880. In addition, the “classified” set of children is fairly representative of all immigrants’ children circa 1850 in terms of observable characteristics. We use the new dataset to address three main sets of questions. First, in 1850, how different were the households headed by famine-era Irish migrants from those headed by earlier Irish migrants, by concurrent migrants from Germany and Britain, and by US natives? In particular, is there evidence of a differential change in Irish household heads’ human capital (reflecting changing selection) and labor market outcomes (reflecting both selection and labor market conditions for newly arrived migrants) between the pre-famine and famine-era migrants? Given this paper’s motivation, we care about changing migrant selection primarily because it directly influences the average household characteristics and resources of immigrants’ children, though documenting the patterns of migrant selection at the time of the famine is also of independent interest (e.g., Mokyr and Ó Gráda 1982; Cohn 1995). Consistent with the predictions of a simple Roy (1951)-Borjas (1987) model, we find clear evidence of deterioration in the human capital of Irish immigrant household heads with the onset of the famine, as measured by literacy and age heaping in 1850. This is the clearest evidence to date on human capital differences between pre-famine and famine-era arrivals.9 We also document a decline in occupational status between the pre-famine and famine-era Irish, both absolutely and relative to differences over arrival cohorts for other immigrant groups. Thus, by changing both the composition and volume of Irish migration, the Great Famine resulted in a large inquire about place of birth; so, there is limited scope for backward linkage. Extending links to the passenger lists in this early period is difficult due to the sparseness of records and the feasibility of making multiple accurate links across various datasets (see footnote 30). 7 For example, a family with an Irish-born child aged 2 in 1850 immigrated to the US some time in or after 1848, which would make them famine-era migrants. A family with an American-born child aged 7 in 1850 immigrated to the US some time before or during 1843, making them pre-famine migrants. We make the same distinctions for the British and German migrants to form comparison groups of arrival cohorts. 8 In contrast, this approach enables us to classify the arrival cohort of fewer than half of adults in the 1850 census. The method proves to be very accurate in cases where the classification can be verified with outside information (i.e., searching passenger lists). 9 This contribution to the literature on the Irish famine is limited by the fact that our method to classify individuals’ year of arrival requires that they have children; this group may have differed meaningfully from childless immigrants.

3 cohort of relatively poor immigrant children in the US circa 1850. Second, in 1880, how did the adult labor market outcomes of Irish famine migrants’ sons compare to those of other immigrants’ and natives’ sons? Studying these outcomes provides perspective on the potential for long-term assimilation in a setting where a variety of forces— including inauspicious early life conditions, an environment rife with anti-Irish sentiment, and a continuing influx of new immigrants—may have hindered the Irish children’s advancement. We find that, on average, the sons of the famine-era Irish immigrants fared poorly in the labor market as adults in comparison with other groups in 1880. Nonetheless, in comparison to their fathers’ starting point, they greatly narrowed the gap in occupational status relative to natives. The gap is even smaller when considering their adverse childhood environment (i.e., when controlling for 1850 household characteristics); that is, the intergenerational occupational upgrading of the famine Irish was almost the same as that of observationally similar natives. In this sense, fairly strong economic assimilation occurred over generations. The labor market outcomes of Irish immigrants circa 1850 were thus a poor guide to inferring the group’s ability to assimilate over a longer period. Finally, we examine heterogeneity in the upward mobility of the children of famine-era Irish immigrants according to observable characteristics, including measures of their father’s human capital, residence in an Irish enclave, geographic mobility, and social distance (specifically, having a surname that we determine to be predominantly Catholic). The data and setting do not allow clear identification of causal relationships; they do, however, provide novel evidence on factors that may have facilitated or impeded immigrants’ intergenerational gains. In particular, we find that having a more Catholic surname and being born in Ireland were associated with less upward mobility, conditional on other observables. This pattern is consistent with the presence of discrimination against Irish Catholics, lower levels of human capital for Irish Catholics, and long-term negative consequences from exposure to the famine, all of which merit closer examination in future research. This paper contributes to the literature on the economics of immigration in several dimensions. Most directly, the paper advances our knowledge of the Age of Mass Migration generally and of Irish migration during the famine specifically. It is thus complementary to research by Hatton and Williamson (1998), Ferrie (1999), Cohn (2009), and Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (2012, 2014), among others. By studying immigrants’ experiences in the early portion of this period, in contrast to a recent scholarship that has focused on the post-1900 period, the paper brings the first cohorts of the Age of Mass Migration into sharper focus. More broadly, studying the experience of Irish famine-era migrants may yield broader insights into the economics of large-scale

4 migration due to natural or man-made disasters.10 By studying a large wave of migrants and their offspring long before the implementation of restrictive immigration policies, the paper yields insight into the migration process and potential for assimilation in a setting where virtually open borders and lack of labor, housing, or other regulation allowed economic forces to predominate. Finally, our emphasis on economic assimilation in the long run speaks to a core theme of the international migration literature, both historical and contemporary.11 Issues of migrant assimilation have become particularly salient in recent years, as large numbers of refugees have sought residence in the United States and Europe (United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees 2017). This has fueled a debate in which concerns about immigrants’ assimilation have been cited as justification for more restrictive policies (e.g., Kelly 2018), such as proposals that potential entrants be screened to favor those with a greater “likelihood of successful assimilation and contribution to the United States” (US Department of State et al. 2017, p. 8). In the Irish case, we find that despite a notable deterioration in migrant selection and a significant political backlash, the migrants’ children converged strongly, albeit incompletely, on natives’ outcomes by 1880. In this sense, they showed clear evidence of “assimilation and contribution” to the American economy.

2. Background on Ireland’s Great Famine and Migration to the US On the eve of the Great Famine, two-thirds of Irish families were employed primarily in agriculture (Commissioners 1843, p. xviii). Most owned little or no land (Ó Gráda 1999, p. 25) and had few financial resources. Widespread poverty and heavy reliance on the potato left the Irish vulnerable to large and repeated failures of the potato crop, as occurred in 1845 and 1846 due to the spread of a microorganism that causes blight (Phytophthora infestans). By late 1846, Ireland was in the grips of a historic famine. The relatively good yields of 1847 were of little avail as farmers had shifted away from planting potatoes. The famine was then exacerbated by crop failures in 1848 and, less severely, in 1849 and 1850.12 Even before the famine, the migration flow from Ireland to the US was substantial (Mokyr

10 On migration due to environmental disasters or war see recent work by Boustan, Kahn, and Rhode (2012), Hornbeck (2012), Moser, Voena, and Waldinger (2014), Mahajan and Yang (2017), Nakamura, Sigurdsson, and Steinsson (2017), Blum and Rei (2018), and Long and Siu (2018). 11 On immigrant assimilation, both historical and contemporary, see inter alia Ferenczi and Wilcox (1929), Chiswick (1978), Borjas (1992, 1993), Hatton (1997), Hatton and Williamson (1998), Card, DiNardo, and Estes (2000), Minns (2000), Cortes (2004), Card (2005), Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (2014, 2016), and Alexander and Ward (2018). 12 Mokyr (1983) and Ó Gráda (1999) discuss the chronology of agricultural failure and famine in detail. See Solar (1989) on Irish crop failures in historical and international perspective.

5 and Ó Gráda 1982). Historians suggest that pre-famine migrants were likely drawn from above the Irish median in terms of skill and socioeconomic status, but perhaps less so over time as costs of migration declined (Miller 1985, pp. 193-201). Consistent with the impression of positive selection, whereas approximately 40 percent of men (ages 16-45) in Ireland could neither read nor write in 1841 (Commissioners 1843, p. xxxvi), only 15 percent of Irish-born men (ages 25-54) were classified as illiterate in the 1850 US census.13 The bulk of the Irish famine emigrants, including many of those who originally landed in Canada, settled in the US (McInnis 2000; Cohn 2009). Passenger records from US ports of entry suggest that the annual rate of Irish immigration nearly doubled with the famine’s onset.14 By June 1850, when the US population census was taken, there were nearly one million Irish-born residents. To be sure, some of those who migrated during the famine would have left Ireland in any case. But Ó Gráda points out that “… most of the mass emigration of the late 1840s was part of the famine tragedy. It was push migration with a vengeance, and its tragic character has been rightly at the center of historical writings about it” (1999, p. 105). Miller writes of a “mass, indiscriminate rush to leave” Ireland in the wake of the potato blight (1985, p. 292). Many of the migrants were making a leap of faith in a desperate context characterized by widespread death and social collapse. Like modern day refugees, their departure was precipitated by an imminent threat to survival, often undertaken hastily, and generally irreversible.15 A major difference, of course, is that migrants fleeing to the US during the famine did not face the legal restrictions on entry that are prevalent today. In addition to generating a surge in the volume of migration, there are indications that the famine may have led to a change in the composition of Irish migration to the US. Some clues come from fragmentary information on the migrants’ places of origin. It appears that the main sources shifted somewhat from the North and East (Ulster and Leinster) toward the South and the West (Munster and Connacht) (Ó Gráda 1999, p. 113; Anbinder and McCaffrey 2015; Anbinder, Ó Gráda,

13 These are our calculations from 1850 complete count census. We caution that comparing across the censuses this way is somewhat tenuous; it is unclear how comparable literacy measures are. The differences are sufficiently large in this case that we think the information is useful. See Connor (2019) for evidence of negative selection in the early twentieth century. 14 Cohn (2009, pp. 26-27) warns that the time-series data on Irish immigration in the early to mid-nineteenth century allocates a fixed share of UK immigrants to Ireland (0.70) rather than providing a true count. 15 The post-famine transformation of the Irish economy, which included consolidation of small landholdings, ensured that emigration continued once famine conditions passed (Guinnane 1997; Ó Gráda 1999). The parallel between the famine migrants and modern refugees fleeing war and instability has been noted in the Irish press (Delaney 2015).

6 and Wegge 2017). This suggests that the characteristics of migrants may have changed because residents of the South and West were more agricultural and less literate than elsewhere (Commissioners 1843, Geary 1996); they were also more likely to be Catholic and to speak Irish. Passenger lists of ships entering US ports are also potentially informative about changing selection. The lists include self-reported occupation and age, typically recorded at the European port of embarkation. They provide a window on the pre-departure activity of migrants, but the evidence is ambiguous and much caution is necessary (Cohn 2009, ch. 5), which is one factor that motivates our census-based approach.16 Cohn (1995) finds a slight decrease in the fraction of Irish immigrants who were reported as laborers after 1845, whereas Mokyr and Ó Gráda (1982) find an increase in innumeracy as implied by age heaping in passenger lists after 1845. In the US, Irish immigrants were over-represented in urban areas of the Northeast. It is worth emphasizing, however, that most Irish immigrants, including those we identify as famine-era arrivals, did not reside in New York City (13.8 percent of all Irish-born) or Boston (3.5 percent) in 1850.17 Landmarks in the historical literature tend to focus on these cities (Handlin 1991 [1941], Ernst 1949), but a much broader geographic scope is required to describe the experience of the Irish immigrants. Scholars have long understood that Irish immigrants were disproportionately employed in relatively low-skill, low-paying lines of work (Handlin 1991 [1941]; Ernst 1949; Miller 1985). Ferrie (1994, 1995, 1997a, 1999) provides a more dynamic view by drawing a sample of immigrant men from New York City’s passenger lists in the 1840s and linking them to census records in 1850 or 1860. He finds a great deal of mobility between pre-migration occupational categories, coded from passenger lists, and those reported in the 1850 or 1860 US census (1999, Table 5-2). Irish men had lower pre-migration occupational status than the British and Germans based on the passenger lists (i.e., more unskilled laborers), had lower rates of upward mobility from the unskilled category, and accumulated less real estate wealth (1999, Table 6-4). Even so, Anbinder, Ó Gráda, and Wegge (2017) find evidence of upward mobility in the account records of Irish immigrants at the Emigrant Industrial Savings Bank in New York. In addition to their economic struggles, mid-century Irish immigrants were subject to a sharp nativist backlash that was rooted in long-standing anti-Catholic sentiment in the US and heightened

16 The lists are potentially incomplete in coverage, may have deteriorated in quality during the famine, and may have varied in enumeration practices across ports of embarkation. Even within a given list, clerks may or may not have accurately recorded each passenger’s primary past occupation. 17 These are our calculations from the complete count census data (Minnesota Population Center 2017; Ruggles et al. 2015).

7 by the sheer volume of mass migration.18 Hirota (2017, p. 2) writes, “The newcomers’ religion triggered an outburst of anti-Irish nativism in these states [New York and Massachusetts], but so too did the immigrants’ poverty.” Hirota (2017, ch. 2) documents cases of deportation and efforts to prevent destitute Irish passengers from disembarking in Massachusetts. A salient manifestation of this backlash was the success of the “Know Nothing” party in the early 1850s, which advanced the ideas that “Protestantism defined American society” and that “Catholicism was not compatible with the basic values Americans cherished most” (Anbinder 1992, p. 104). Despite much valuable scholarship on Irish immigrants in the US, a number of important gaps remain in our understanding of the famine migrants’ experience. First, there is no clear picture of differences between the Irish who arrived before the famine and those who arrived during the famine. To date, the evidence is somewhat fragmentary and inconclusive. Moreover, although scholars have explored the economic assimilation of first-generation Irish immigrants (e.g., Ferrie 1999), there is no information available on the assimilation experience of the immigrants’ children. This absence stands out relative to studies of modern migrant assimilation (e.g., Borjas 1993; Card 2005), in which children’s outcomes are of fundamental interest. Finally, the economic mobility of the famine Irish has not been closely compared to that of natives, let alone in an intergenerational framework that allows us to tie children’s outcomes to their early life circumstances at an individual level. The mid-nineteenth century was a period of high intergenerational mobility among US natives (Long and Ferrie 2013). It is thus essential to compare immigrants and natives to determine whether immigrants closed the gap in economic status and, in that sense, assimilated over generations. This paper develops new evidence on all of these fronts.

3. Data sources and construction To construct the dataset, we first obtained the complete count US census data for 1850 (Ruggles et al. 2015; Minnesota Population Center 2017). Because this census (and all those prior to 1890) did not inquire about immigrants’ year of arrival in the US, our first task was to develop an alternative approach to distinguish the Irish who arrived during the famine from those who arrived prior to it. We determined the arrival cohort for each Irish-born head of household based on the ages and places of birth of children in the household in the 1850 census.19 Household heads with a child

18 By this time, Irish immigrants were overwhelmingly Catholic. Many German immigrants were also Catholic, but they were better off and less concentrated in cities of the Northeast than the Irish. 19 We use an indicator for relationship to the head of household provided in the original data by Ruggles et al. (2015). Our understanding is that individuals are assumed to be children of the head of household if they are of

8 (son or daughter) born in the US in 1845 or earlier are categorized in the pre-famine group, while those with a child born in Ireland in 1846 or later are in the famine-era group.20 We performed a similar classification for British- and German-born heads of household in 1850.21 We include the Germans and British in this study because, after the Irish, they were the largest groups of immigrants before 1850 (Barde, Carter, and Sutch 2006, p. 1-560), and they provide a useful point of comparison. This classification scheme leads to six categories of immigrant household heads: pre- famine Irish, famine-era Irish, and similar cohorts for the British and Germans. We also include households headed by native-born white men for comparison. We assigned the household heads’ arrival cohort classification and ethnicity to their sons aged 18 or younger. For example, sons of an Irish father who arrived in the US between 1846 and 1850 are referred to as members of the “famine-era Irish.”22 Importantly, not all children in Irish, British, or German-headed households were foreign-born. It follows that not all children classified as being famine-era Irish would have experienced the famine in Ireland (though 40 percent of our benchmark sample of famine Irish sons were born in Ireland during the famine). Given that the paper’s main goal is to characterize long-term assimilation as revealed in the outcomes of immigrants’ children, partitioning the data this way provides simple but new insights. Table 1 divides each immigrant group using the categorization described above, reporting for heads of household in columns (1) to (3) and for sons in columns (4) to (6). The fraction of individuals categorized definitely into the pre-famine or famine-era cohorts was approximately 65 percent for the Irish sons, but only about 44 percent for all Irish heads of household (including those without children).23 The Germans and British exhibit similar patterns. As mentioned earlier, the greater ability to categorize children than heads of households or other adults is part of our motivation for focusing on the children’s long-term outcomes: the children who we can categorize

appropriate age and if they share a surname with the head of household. We must rely on this imputed indicator because the census did not inquire regarding relationship to the head of household until 1880. 20 It is not possible to place all household heads into one of these two categories, and therefore we create two more categories: those with a child born in the United States in 1846 or later and a child born in Ireland between 1841 and 1845 (“probable famine-era”), and all others (“uncategorized”). We do not use these latter two groups in our main analysis. The outcomes of the “probable” group resemble those of the “famine” group, while those of the “uncategorized” group fall between those of the “famine” and “pre-famine” groups. 21 The data obtained from Ruggles et al. (2015) combine England, , and into a single birthplace of Great Britain. We retain this combination. 22 In principle it is possible to determine for a subset of the sample whether individuals arrived in the early period of the famine (when it was somewhat less severe) or later. But pinning down arrival dates this finely would limit the sample to those with children born in quick succession, severely limiting the sample size. 23 The main group that we cannot classify by our approach (and who are not included in Table 1) is boarders, who were 27 percent of all Irish-born adult males in the 1850 US census.

9 are fairly representative of the population of immigrants’ children (discussed in more detail below), whereas immigrants with children are not likely to be representative of all adult immigrants. In the next step, we linked all the males who were born in Ireland, Britain, Germany, and the US and observed in the 1850 US census to the full count 1880 US census (Ruggles et al. 2015; Minnesota Population Center 2017). We briefly describe the linking procedure here and provide additional details in Appendix A. We do not constrain the sample for linking to those whose arrival cohort could be determined (described above), as this might result in more false matches. Instead, we attempt to link the 1850 census records to 1880 without regard for whether arrival cohort could be determined; we then use only successful links (described below) whose arrival cohort could be clearly classified as pre-famine or famine-era for the assimilation analyses. At the start of the linkage process, we retained only individuals who were unique in terms of place of birth, age-implied year of birth (plus or minus four years), and first and last name (with allowances for orthographic differences) in 1850. We linked those men to the 1880 census, according to the same identifying characteristics and retained only matches in which both the 1850 and the 1880 record had a unique match in the opposite census. This linkage method is essentially similar to that introduced by Ferrie’s (1996) pioneering effort of mechanical record linkage. Relative to Ferrie’s (1996) approach, our method incorporates recent innovations, such as the replacement of the NYSIIS name standardization algorithm with the use of orthographic distance measures, as in Beach et al. (2016), which reduces the danger of false links and has become common in the literature (Bailey et al. 2017; Abramitzky, Mill, and Pérez 2018). We chose this approach because of its long- standing use and its relatively conservative nature in selecting matches. Table 2 presents rates of successful linkage. Column (1) shows the number of observations with which the linkage process began for each 1850 group. Column (2) shows the fraction of individuals who remained after removing those who were not unique on name, birth place, and age. The fraction of these individuals who were successfully located in 1880 is shown in column (3). Among the Irish children, we linked about 15 percent of the unique famine-era Irish and about 20 percent of the unique pre-famine Irish. Among Germans, the rates of linkage are comparable to the Irish, whereas they are between 23 and 26 percent for the British and Americans. These match rates for the British and Americans are comparable to those of Ferrie (1996, p. 145 and Table 4). The match rates for the Irish and Germans are somewhat lower, and there are reasons to expect this. Besides the lower levels of literacy and education of the Irish, which may tend to reduce match rates, the arrivals of large cohorts of Irish and German immigrants after 1850 would have potentially

10 confounded links even of individuals who were unique in 1850.24 In sum, our benchmark dataset of children consists of males who were aged 0 to 18 in 1850, sons of the household head in 1850 (according to the Ruggles et al. 2015 classification), successfully linked from the 1850 to the 1880 US census, born in the US, Ireland, Britain, or Germany, and with a father born in the US, Ireland, Britain, or Germany. We also require that, if the child’s head of household in 1850 was an immigrant, it was possible to determine whether the head of household was in the famine-era or the pre-famine arrival cohort.

Potential pitfalls in data construction Our data construction process is subject to four main potential pitfalls. First, only a fraction of 1850 individuals are linked to the 1880 census, and selection into linkage is likely to be non- random. In Appendix A, we present linear probability models that relate the probability of being linked to a variety of characteristics in 1850. There are several statistically significant predictors of selection into linkage, such as higher property ownership and literacy; this is typical in studies that link census data (e.g., Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson 2014; Beach et al. 2016). However, most differences are small, as indicated in Figure 1, which compares means of variables for linked children and all children of Irish migrants in 1850. To address selection into linkage, we weight all of the analyses by the inverse of the estimated conditional probability of successful linkage.25 The second issue is that some automated linkage methods may yield a high rate of false positives in matching (Bailey et al. 2017). Our linkage approach mitigates this concern, though it cannot be entirely avoided. We eliminate individuals who are not unique in terms of the linkage characteristics from the sample that we attempt to link; this reduces the probability of a making false match. Moreover, we do not make links on the basis of a name standardization algorithm, a practice that Bailey et al. (2017) highlight as a source of false positives.26 To verify that false positives in linkage are not responsible for our results, we have also examined a sample of exact unique matches

24 For instance, a Patrick Kelly born in 1845 in Ireland may have been unique in the United States in 1850, but other Patrick Kellys born in 1845 in Ireland may have arrived after 1850, preventing the identification of the correct Patrick Kelly in 1880. 25 This probability is computed from separate probit regressions of a linkage indicator on a variety of covariates for each of the seven ethnicity-cohort groups. 26 We use the soundex algorithm to reduce the set of candidate matches, but all of the linking is ultimately based on orthographic distance, which is a score derived from the number and type of spelling changes that would be required to move from one name spelling to another.

11 only.27 This further reduces the probability of false matches and does not qualitatively affect our main results. A third concern is that the roughly two-thirds of children whose father’s arrival cohort is definitively classified might not be representative of the population of children in 1850. To determine whether selection into successful classification is likely to bias our results, we compare the means of 1850 observables of the classified Irish children to those of the whole sample of Irish children in Figure 2.28 Though the classification does appear to favor individuals with better socioeconomic status, such as those whose household heads owned more property in 1850, the differences between the classified group and all children are small.29 Finally, there is concern that the categorization of arrival cohort is confounded by incorrect reporting of children’s ages. We view the danger of age heaping as less severe for children than it would be for adults due to the greater developmental differences by age among children. To provide direct evidence, we randomly selected 50 classified households from our linked data, stratifying to include 25 of each categorization group (famine and pre-famine) and searched carefully for their passenger list records using Ancestry.com. Although we were able to locate only 10 of these households definitively,30 all 10 were correctly categorized by the age- and birthplace-based algorithm.

Additional variables of interest The US census did not collect information on income before 1940; therefore, we rely heavily on occupation to indicate men’s relative economic status. The simplest approach is to define and

27 We define an exact match as one in which there is no more than a one-year difference in age-implied birth year and the first and last names of both records are identical after removing double letters and common first name abbreviations (e.g., changing “Wm” to “William”). These results are available on request. 28 Figure 2 covers the linked sample and is weighted to correct for selection into linkage. Similar results are obtained for the children of British and German immigrants. 29 Results are qualitatively unchanged when we re-weight our sample to correct for selection into both linkage and classification on the basis of observables. However, we prefer not to re-weight to correct for selection into classification in our benchmark results because it is not clear whether differences in observables between the classified and unclassified groups reflect selection into classification (which one would like to reverse) or actual differences in the probability that classified and unclassified individuals arrived during the famine. 30 This also illustrates the difficulties of linkage from the passenger lists to the census. Combined with the number of observations lost in the link from 1850 to 1880, requiring an additional link to the passenger lists would result in a very small sample. Even achieving this low rate of linkage to the passenger lists required using information on individuals’ household composition; in some cases, individuals could be located only when searching for their household members. The use of household information in linkage is generally avoided due to the bias it introduces. The census-based approach to determining the arrival year enables us to avoid these problems of linkage from the passenger lists and to maintain a larger sample.

12 study a categorical variable for “unskilled labor,” which combines “laborers” and other relatively low-skilled occupations, such as “porter” and “miner” (following Ferrie 1995, 1999). In addition, we create a variable that exploits the 1870 census’s information on real and personal wealth. For each occupation-by-region (North/South) cell, we calculate a “wealth score” that equals the average total wealth of men (age 30-65) in the one-percent sample of the 1870 census (Ruggles et al. 2015; Minnesota Population Center 2017).31 This is akin to the occupation score variable based on 1950 income data that is often used in studies of twentieth-century US labor markets.32 We believe the 1870-based occupation score is better suited for studying the mid-nineteenth century because it is, of course, closer in time to our period of study, and it is designed to allow for differences between the North and South. We also use this wealth score to define an occupational rank variable, which represents the percentile of the wealth score in the sample.33 For analysis of heterogeneity in outcomes among the Irish (Section 5), we constructed three additional variables. The Irish immigrants’ predominantly Catholic religion was salient and controversial at the time, but of course there was variation in religious affiliation among the Irish. The US population census has never inquired about individuals’ religious affiliation, and no such information is available from passenger lists. To gain some insight on the association between religion and economic outcomes for the Irish, we construct a measure of “Catholicity” based on surnames.34 In particular, we use full-count micro-level data from Ireland’s 1901 census to calculate the fraction of individuals that were Catholic by surname; then, we merge that surname-based information with our linked dataset from the US census.35 The details of the procedure are provided in Appendix B. This adds a useful dimension to the description of Irish immigrants and within-Irish heterogeneity in labor market outcomes. We also create a variable that measures the fraction of the 100 closest households that were

31 We have also experimented with wealth scores at the source country-occupation-region level. Unfortunately, this cuts the data thinly in many instances, and it is not very well suited to our study of immigrants’ children (many of whom were US-born). The 1850 census did not ascertain personal wealth, and the 1880 census did not inquire about wealth at all. 32 The correlation between our measure in 1880 and the 1950-based occupational income score is only 0.28 in our linked data. However, this is largely due to the changing occupational status of farmers in the intervening period. When farmers are excluded, the correlation is 0.75. 33 In the interest of brevity, we do not report the results for occupational rank in all specifications below. Where it is not shown (and where it is), it is qualitatively similar to the results with the wealth score. 34 The use of information contained in surnames to glean additional information on immigrant origins is increasingly common (e.g., Spitzer 2018; Spitzer and Zimran 2018; Pérez 2019b), including in the study of the origins of the Irish in Ireland and abroad (Ferrie 1997c; Ó Gráda 2016; Connor 2019). 35 Ideally, we would have used data from an earlier Irish census. However, the 1901 census is the earliest with micro data available; the 1841 records were destroyed by fire in the 1920s (National Archives of Ireland n.d.).

13 headed by Irish men in 1850, as a way to gauge residence in Irish immigrant enclaves. In this, we follow Logan and Parman (2017) and rely on the idea that individuals close to one another on census manuscript pages were likely geographically proximate to one another. Finally, we created an indicator for having moved states between 1850 and 1880, which may shed light on whether geographic mobility was associated with upward occupational mobility for the Irish. Geographic mobility is a major theme in American economic development, especially in the nineteenth century, but whether it was a direct conduit for Irish immigrants’ economic gains is an open question.

4. Results describing the selection and economic assimilation of Irish immigrants We first describe the 1850 household characteristics of the children of famine-era immigrants. The 1850 data are informative regarding three aspects of the famine-era migration. First, differences in the human capital characteristics of fathers over arrival cohorts (i.e., in their literacy and numeracy) are informative about changes in migrant selection during the famine.36 Second, fathers’ labor market outcomes are informative about the combination of changing migrant selection and difficult labor market conditions experienced by immigrants arriving during the Great Famine. Finally, and most importantly given our focus on intergenerational assimilation, all of the 1850 variables are informative about the early-life conditions experienced by the children of immigrants. Then, we examine the children’s outcomes in the labor market in 1880. By this time, the children are between 30 and 48 years old, a useful range for observing adult labor market outcomes in an intergenerational framework (Haider and Solon 2006, Long and Ferrie 2013, Feigenbaum 2018). Individual-level information on income or wealth is not available in 1880, and so we study occupational status as defined above. We are particularly interested in whether the famine-era Irish children narrowed gaps in status relative to the children of US natives and other immigrant groups. We are also interested in how they fared in a conditional sense—whether they did as well as observationally similar children from other groups. The ability to connect the children’s adult outcomes to their childhood households is a useful feature of the dataset, and it is rare in studies of US immigrant assimilation.

36 There is a concern that the census data do not reflect migrants’ characteristics at time of arrival. Our focus on human capital mitigates this concern because it is less likely that immigrants’ literacy and numeracy changed after arrival than did other measures, such as occupation.

14 Human capital and occupational status of household heads in 1850 Table 3 summarizes the 1850 variables for our main sample of linked and classified children, reported separately by ethnicity and arrival cohort. The first set of variables describes the individual’s father in 1850.37 We collect literacy directly from the census, and we construct a measure of numeracy, which is an indicator for reporting an age that is not divisible by five.38 We characterize occupational status with the wealth score, as described above, and with broad occupational groups. We also observe directly the household head’s real property ownership in 1850. For the children, we observe whether they attended school in the year prior to the census (ages 5 to 15). We also create indicator variables for whether the child was US-born, and in the case of Irish children, whether the child was in utero during the famine (i.e., Irish-born 1846-1850). Differences between Irish and non-Irish households are immediately apparent from these summary statistics, as are differences between pre-famine and famine-era arrival cohorts of Irish immigrants. Relative to natives and to other immigrant groups, both arrival cohorts of the Irish were more likely to be illiterate, innumerate, and to hold unskilled occupations; as a result of the latter, they also had lower occupational wealth scores and ranks. The Irish also owned less property than other similarly tenured immigrants (or natives). Within the Irish, there was a considerable disadvantage for the famine-era arrivals compared to the pre-famine arrivals along these same dimensions. The famine-era Irish household heads were less literate and numerate, were more likely to hold an unskilled occupation, and had more Catholic surnames than earlier Irish immigrants. They were also more likely to reside in an urban area and in proximity to other Irish than were earlier Irish immigrants. To characterize these differences more precisely, we estimate a regression specification of the form

� = � + � + �� + �, 1 where � is some outcome for individual � from ethnicity � and arrival cohort �. The coefficients of interest are �, which reflect differences in means between each immigrant-cohort group relative to white native-headed households (the excluded category), conditional on �. The controls � in

37 To be included in this analysis, a head of household had to be the father of a son in our linked sample. This does not imply that the father had a son before immigration because daughters’ birthplaces and ages are also used to determine immigration cohort; but the father must have had a son either before or after immigration. 38 This variable does not indicate the numeracy of any individual in the sample, but differences between groups in the share reporting an age that ends in zero or five is informative.

15 the baseline case are simply a quartic in the age of the head of household, or indicators for the individual’s age for the analysis of children’s school attendance.

We also test the null hypothesis that the difference in � coefficients across Irish arrival cohorts is equal to the difference for the British and Germans.39 This provides a kind of difference- in-differences perspective on the pre- and post-1846 Irish arrivals compared to the pre- and post- 1846 patterns for other groups. The idea is simply to see whether the differences over arrival cohorts are common to all immigrant source countries (e.g., reflecting the duration of time in the US or common trends in transport costs), or if there is something different about the change in Irish outcomes relative to the contemporaneous changes for the British and Germans. We do not interpret such differences as strong evidence of a causal impact of the Irish famine per se, though they would be consistent with such an effect.40

Table 4 presents estimates of � for the 1850 characteristics. Results in columns (1) and (2) indicate that Irish household heads had significantly less human capital than US-native heads of household, who were in turn less likely to be literate but more likely to be numerate than British and German heads. Conditional on age, there is evidence of a large decrease in literacy and numeracy between the pre-famine and famine-era Irish compared to natives (-0.05 to -0.11 for literacy; -0.18 to -0.25 for numeracy), with no similar changes evident among the other nationalities. The difference- in-differences test across ethnicities is statistically significant in both columns, indicating that the worsening observable quality of Irish migrants during the famine was not an artifact of cohort- specific shocks or trends affecting all nationalities. Instead, it is plausible that famine conditions led to a marked deterioration in migrants’ quality, as gauged by literacy and numeracy. This worsening selection is consistent with Mokyr and Ó Gráda’s (1982) findings of increasing age heaping among Irish immigrants in passenger lists after 1845. It is also consistent with the predictions of a canonical Roy (1951)-Borjas (1987) model of migrant selection. As discussed above, positive selection from Ireland is believed to have prevailed before the famine. In this setting, a widespread and persistent negative shock to expected income at home, such as the

39 Formally, this is a joint test of the null hypotheses that � − � = � − � and � − � = � − �, where � represents the indicator for the famine arrival cohort of ethnicity j and � represents the indicator for the pre-famine arrival cohort of ethnicity j. 40 Drawing a strong causal conclusion would require the assumption that Irish immigrants would have followed the same trend over the pre- and post-1846 cohorts as the British and Germans in the absence of the famine shock. We do not view this as a clearly tenable assumption, and we are not making a causal argument. All that we claim is that if the famine Irish fared especially poorly relative to prior Irish immigrants in comparison to arrival cohort patterns within other immigrant groups, then their poor outcome is unlikely to be due solely to their later arrival or a common shock to transatlantic migration.

16 potato blight, would then tend to draw lower-skilled workers into the migrant flow at the margin, leading to a decline in average migrant quality.41 Similar patterns are evident for the heads’ labor market outcomes as shown in columns (3)- (6). Both arrival cohorts of Irish household heads were more likely to hold unskilled occupations and had lower (log) occupational wealth scores and lower occupational ranks than natives and other immigrant groups, conditional on age. They were also less likely than natives to be farmers. We find strong evidence of a deterioration in labor market status between the pre-famine and famine-era Irish, which is unmatched by the other immigrant groups. For example, while pre-famine Irish household heads were about 29 percentage points more likely to hold unskilled occupations than native household heads, the famine Irish household heads were over 56 percentage points more likely. Such large differences are not present in the other ethnicities (i.e., the difference-in- differences F-tests indicate a significantly greater deterioration over arrival cohorts for the Irish than for other groups).42 This suggests that the Irish pattern is unlikely to be solely the result of the famine Irish having been in the US for a shorter time than the pre-famine Irish and thus having had less time to upgrade occupations. Results for property ownership and the school attendance of children are less stark, as shown in columns (7) and (8). We do observe a decline in the value of real property owned between pre- famine and famine-era Irish; this is not surprising given that the famine-era Irish had been in the US for a shorter period. Similar cross-cohort declines are apparent for the Germans and British, and although it is still possible to reject the difference-in-differences null hypothesis, the decline in property holdings over cohorts is actually greatest among the British. There is also a decline in school attendance over arrival cohorts, conditional on children’s age, for each immigrant group. The children of the famine-era Irish were substantially less likely to attend school than similarly aged

41 Richer models of selection that allow migration costs to vary by level of skill (Chiquiar and Hanson 2005, McKenzie and Rapoport 2010) suggest that migration costs may prevent the migration of the poorest workers. Financial constraints on migration were relevant for the Irish (Hatton and Williamson 1994), and the poorest Irish could not afford to migrate to the US during the famine (Ó Gráda 1999, pp. 104-114). Recent work has also emphasized that networks shape migrant selection and migration responses to shocks (Wegge 1998, McKenzie and Rapoport 2010; Mahajan and Yang 2017; Spitzer 2018; Spitzer and Zimran 2018). If Irish migrants were positively selected before the famine, it is possible that relatively well-off families or places had stronger migrant networks to facilitate emigration and more resources to finance the move. In theory, this might skew selection in a more positive direction, but on net we observe selection becoming more negative. 42 It is possible that if the comparison were in the relative difference in the probability of holding an unskilled occupation rather than the absolute difference, that results might differ. However, given that our goal is to describe the childhood household characteristics of the sons of the famine migrants, we are more concerned with the absolute differences, as they reflect the number of children whose head of household was unskilled.

17 children of US natives (by over 14 p.p.), but in this respect, they fared better than German children.43 It is not possible to reject the null hypothesis that the change in schooling across the Irish cohorts was the same as that of the other ethnicities. As with the deterioration in migrant quality, the worsening labor market outcomes of the famine Irish relative to other groups can be rationalized in a cogent theoretical framework. In addition to the deterioration in Irish migrants’ observable human capital, the sheer volume of the immigrants’ arrival cohort may have affected their labor market outcomes. The size of the famine- era arrival cohort may have hindered their economic progress by congesting networks that would ordinarily facilitate their transition. Beaman (2012) shows, in theory and in a dataset of recent refugees to the US, that pre-existing stocks of immigrants can facilitate labor market assimilation for newly arrived countrymen by providing information about job opportunities. Relatively large cohorts of new immigrants, however, exacerbate competition for information in the network and may lead to worse labor market outcomes than would otherwise occur, at least in the short term. This mechanism is potentially applicable to the case of the famine-era Irish migrants, who, upon arriving in the US, would have entered labor markets that were populated by many previous Irish migrants, but also glutted with a large cohort of new arrivals. Moreover, there may have been some mismatch of the new arrivals and the pre-existing network, as the sources of emigration within Ireland shifted during the famine. In sum, the new dataset of linked census records reveals that the famine-era Irish household heads were notably less educated and attained low occupational status compared to other contemporaneous immigrant groups, earlier immigrants from Ireland, and US natives. There was nothing about the famine refugees that would favorably impress policymakers concerned primarily with immigrant “quality.”44 Thus, their children began life at a severe disadvantage in terms of economic resources relative to others in the US during an era with minimal public assistance and ongoing mass immigration from Europe. Under these circumstances, how far, if at all, were the children of the famine-era Irish able to narrow the gap in economic status relative to their peers as they moved into adulthood?

43 The greater school attendance of the famine Irish relative to the famine Germans is largely explained by differences in the geographic distribution of the two groups. That is, controlling for state fixed effects reduces the gap between the two groups from 9.5 to 1.4 percentage points. This likely reflects a greater tendency for Germans to live in the Midwest, where schooling would have been less readily available. 44 As unfortunate as the famine-Irish household heads appear in 1850, it is quite possible that they were better off on average than those in the same arrival cohort without children; we cannot know for sure because we cannot identify the arrival cohort of those without children.

18 Assimilation by immigrants’ children We now shift the focus to the adult labor market outcomes in 1880 of individuals first observed as children in 1850. Table 5 presents summary statistics for various occupational measures. As with the 1850 data, clear differences are evident between the Irish and the non-Irish, as well as between the famine-era and pre-famine Irish immigrants, all in similar directions as observed for the household heads in 1850. Table 6 presents regressions of the form of equation (1) for the children’s adult labor market outcomes in 1880; again, the only baseline control variable is a quartic in the individual’s age.45 The children of famine-era Irish immigrants were 24 percentage points more likely to hold an unskilled occupation than children of natives, translating into a 48 log point or 11 percentile rank disadvantage in terms of occupational score. For all immigrant groups, occupational outcomes were worse for the children of later (famine-era) arrivals than for children of earlier arrivals. However, whereas these differences were small for the British and Germans, the famine-era Irish children fared much worse than the children of the pre-famine Irish (e.g., 16 percentage points more likely to have an unskilled occupation). The difference-in-differences tests reveal that the famine-era Irish disadvantage relative to earlier Irish arrivals is significantly different from the pattern observed in other immigrant groups; it does not merely reflect worse outcomes for the children of later arriving immigrants. Thus, it is clear that the distinct disadvantage of the famine-era Irish arrivals persisted to the adult outcomes of the children, 30 years after the famine. The results of Tables 5 and 6 taken in isolation paint a fairly negative picture of the economic assimilation of the famine-era Irish. However, when considered in comparison to Tables 3 and 4, the results indicate that considerable assimilation occurred from one generation to the next. Figure 3 directly compares the coefficients from the estimation of equation (1) for the heads’ outcomes in 1850 to those for the (adult) children’s outcomes in 1880. For both the probability of holding an unskilled occupation in Figure 3(a) and the occupational status score in Figure 3(b), the famine-era Irish disadvantage relative to natives in 1880 is much smaller than the gap observed for their fathers in 1850. In this sense, there is strong evidence of convergence in labor market outcomes between immigrants and natives, even for the most impoverished and desperate group of mid-nineteenth century immigrants.

45 These controls are desirable because the famine-era children were on average younger than the pre-famine children (35.6 years as opposed to 37.4 years in 1880), and might thus have had worse labor market outcomes solely because of their age. Controlling for age addresses this concern.

19 Outcomes conditional on 1850 characteristics Given their relatively poor starting point, it is unsurprising that Irish immigrants’ children had worse labor market outcomes than the average child of natives. A different perspective on assimilation is afforded by controlling for the adverse childhood conditions faced by the famine-era Irish children. In studying intergenerational mobility for immigrants, scholars often rely on comparisons of cross-sectional data observed roughly a generation apart; that is, they compare foreign-born workers’ outcomes in one census to outcomes for US-born workers who report having foreign-born parents in a later census (see Borjas 1993; Card 2005; Abramitzky, Boustan, Eriksson 2014). An advantage of the linked census dataset studied here is that we observe at the individual- level both the childhood household characteristics and the adult outcomes. That is, we can study the immigrants’ children’s outcomes conditional on a rich set of early life circumstances. To compare the immigrants’ children to observationally similar natives’ children, we repeat the estimation of equation (1) but expand the vector of control variables in � to include quartic polynomials in the log of the occupational wealth score of the head of household (in 1850), the head’s real property holdings, and the head’s age; indicators for head’s literacy and numeracy; indicators for head’s broad occupational category; and indicators for urban residence, school attendance, and state of residence.

The ethnicity-cohort indicators (�) can thus be interpreted as the difference in intergenerational mobility between natives and observationally similar immigrants. Each panel in Figure 4 presents the coefficient estimates for the ethnicity-cohort indicators

(�) for three specifications. The first set of estimates, labeled “Baseline,” are the coefficients obtained when controlling only for the quartic in age (i.e., they are the same as in Table 6). The second, labeled “Controls,” are the coefficient estimates obtained when controlling for the 1850 household characteristics listed above. The last set, labeled “Controls plus nativity,” are the estimates obtained with all the controls mentioned above and an indicator for US birth.46 US birth might be advantageous to later life outcomes, as it implies no exposure to a long trans-Atlantic voyage and full exposure to American educational institutions, language, and society (Hatton 1997; Alexander and Ward 2018). The famine-era Irish children’s disadvantage in occupational status relative to other groups is greatly diminished, but still visible, when the regression includes background controls. In the baseline results, recall that the sons of the famine-era Irish were 24 percentage points more likely than the sons of natives to have an unskilled occupation, and their occupations scored 48 log points

46 The coefficients of the regressions with the expanded sets of controls are presented in Appendix Table C.1.

20 lower than natives’ sons on average. Once the background control variables are added to the specification, the gaps decline to 14 percentage points and 27 log points for unskilled occupations and occupation scores, respectively. Additionally controlling for native birth further reduces the gaps to just 8 percentage points and 12 log points. Separately, it is notable that the “controls plus nativity” results for the English and Germans are small and indicate slightly better performance for the immigrants’ children than for observationally similar natives. A Gelbach decomposition indicates that the native birth variable and the measures of the father’s occupational status in 1850 (the indicators for occupational category and the quartic in the occupational wealth score) are responsible for the greatest portion of the decline in the magnitude of the famine Irish coefficient relative to the more parsimonious baseline (Gelbach 2016).47 In this sense, the relatively poor early life economic circumstances of the children of the famine-era Irish immigrants were quantitatively important to their subsequent outcomes. Interpreting the residual gap for the famine-era Irish is, of course, difficult in this kind of analysis. It is consistent with both unobservably worse background conditions for the Irish children—circumstances that are not fully captured in �—and discrimination that affects labor market outcomes. The main point here is simply that the children of famine-era Irish fared only slightly worse than children of natives with observationally similar backgrounds, despite facing obstacles that might have been particularly relevant to the children of Irish immigrants. In addition to hindrances associated with relatively low human capital parents, they might also have experienced more overcrowding of schools, housing, and public goods; a nativist backlash against immigrants, especially Irish Catholics; intense labor market competition from new waves of immigrants; and, for some, the physical and psychological trauma of the famine itself.

Discussion The results described thus far answer simple but fundamental questions about immigrants and their children in the early Age of Mass Migration. The answers are made possible by advances in data resources and techniques that allow us to create linked census records at large scale. Our interpretation emphasizes that the famine-era Irish were more negatively selected than prior Irish immigrants and arrived in a large wave on the northeastern seaboard. Their poverty and relative lack

47 Gelbach (2016) provides a method to decompose the change in a coefficient (in our case, the coefficient for the famine Irish indicator) that results from the addition of a vector of controls � into the separate contribution of each component of that vector. Unlike approaches that address coefficient stability with the sequential addition of controls, this decomposition does not depend on the order in which controls are added.

21 of human capital square with historical accounts, but the new dataset offers much more detail and precision than previously available. It can be no surprise that the Irish children did not completely close the gap in average economic status relative to natives’ children by 1880. Yet under the circumstances, the strong evidence of convergence is notable. They may have benefited from arriving at a time when whites’ intergenerational mobility was at a historically high level compared to later periods (Long and Ferrie 2013). Movement toward the mean from the bottom of the occupational distribution was fairly common for low-status whites, but such strong convergence is neither mechanical nor to be taken for granted, as evidenced by the history of black men’s intergenerational mobility later in the nineteenth century (Collins and Wanamaker 2017). Our finding of substantial but incomplete intergenerational convergence by the famine Irish is consistent with important studies of mid- to late-twentieth century immigrants, which typically rely on cross-sectional data sources (as described above). For instance, our finding that the children of famine-era Irish migrants fared worse than other groups is consistent with Borjas (1993, pp. 122- 128), which finds evidence of substantial but incomplete income convergence by the children of relatively poor immigrant groups. Our convergence results are also roughly consistent with Card (2005), which finds that second-generation immigrants tend to converge on or even overtake the educational attainment of US natives (pp. F318-F319). Second-generation Mexican immigrants, for instance, eliminated about 80 percent of the education gap faced by first-generation fathers (Card 2005, p. F319).48 For an earlier period, White and Mullen (2016) describe intergenerational gains in occupational status using IPUMS microdata samples, and Hatton and Williamson (1998, pp. 128- 129) do so based on the reports of the US Immigration Commission (1911). Our findings also complement evidence provided in Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (2014, pp. 498-500), who study immigrant assimilation in the early to mid-twentieth century. Their paper is primarily focused on describing assimilation within a generation using linked data, but it also provides some insight regarding the second generation’s outcomes using cross-sectional data. They find persistence in outcomes across generations, such that groups that were initially disadvantaged (or advantaged) relative to natives in terms of occupational status tended to maintain that position in the second generation. Our results for the Irish are consistent with this finding. Our results for the pre-famine cohorts of British and German immigrants (Table 6) are somewhat different, as their children appear to have surpassed those of natives by 1880, but only slightly.

48 Educational attainment cannot be studied with the US census in the nineteenth century. Even the literacy variable is unavailable for the 1880 complete count data.

22 Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (2014, p. 499) also find that the second generation fared better than the first (relative to US natives) for about half of the 16 sending countries in their dataset, with second-generation German, English, Scottish, and Welsh men faring worse, and second-generation Irish men faring better. These mixed results contrast with the fairly consistent patterns of improvement in the relative status of the immigrant groups that we document in Figure 3, albeit for a small number of groups. There are several possible reasons for differences between our findings and those of Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (2014). The most obvious is that we study different cohorts and periods of time, with our focus being on the earliest cohorts of the Age of Mass Migration and their focus being on the later cohorts. The later cohorts were drawn from a wider range of sending countries, faced lower transport costs, and arrived in an economy that had been transformed by rapid industrialization and . It is possible that features of the mid-nineteenth century US economy facilitated the occupational advancement of poor immigrants relative to later periods. For instance, the frontier remained open (a factor cited by Pérez 2019a), and both native-born workers and immigrants moved westward in large numbers, possibly in response to continuing immigrant inflows (Ferrie 1995). Although we cannot observe whether the men in our sample participated in the US Civil War, it is possible that the tumult of the period provided opportunities for economic mobility. Finally, return migration was far less common in the period that we study than in the later years of the Age of Mass Migration, which may have had implications for immigrants’ investment in US-specific human capital (Cortes 2004).

5. Correlates of economic mobility among the famine Irish In this section, we investigate heterogeneity in economic mobility among the famine-era Irish immigrants, offering the first such analysis of this group. The analysis aims to highlight characteristics that were strongly associated with differences in economic mobility for the sons of famine-era immigrants. We begin with a focus on variables that from the child’s perspective were pre-determined, such as the father’s literacy, whether the son was born in the US or born in Ireland, whether an Irish-born child was born during or before the famine, the share of neighbors who were Irish, and the “Catholicity” of his surname. These correspond to prominent themes in the literature on immigrant assimilation regarding human capital, enclave residence, and social distance. Variation in these characteristics is not quasi-random, and our interpretations are therefore descriptive not causal; even so, the results provide novel insights into the group’s pattern of economic mobility. We estimate an equation of the form

23 � = �� + �� + � � , � + � where � is an occupational outcome for the child in 1880 (an indicator for unskilled occupation or the log of the occupational wealth score), � is the same occupational outcome variable for the child’s father in 1850, � is the vector of regressors of interest, and �(� , � ) represents quartic polynomials in the age of the head of household in 1850 and the age of the child in 1880. The � coefficients measure the conditional correlation of the sons’ economic status with elements of �, taking account of differences in fathers’ occupational status, age variables, and other covariates. The sample is restricted to sons of the famine-era Irish immigrants. Table 7 reports the results.49 Native (US) birth was associated with greater upward mobility relative to children born in Ireland before the famine (the implicit comparison group). This is consistent with findings regarding age at arrival and assimilation later in the Age of Mass Migration (Hatton 1997, Alexander and Ward 2018). In this context, native birth implies no exposure to famine conditions in Ireland or a long trans-Atlantic voyage, and full exposure to US educational and other institutions. These children would have acquired US-specific human capital from the start. Those born in Ireland during the famine did not have statistically different outcomes from those born earlier in Ireland, who would still have been young at the famine’s onset.50 They did, however, fare worse than similarly aged US-born children of famine-era immigrants (i.e., comparing to the coefficient on native-born). This difference is particularly interesting since both groups spent nearly their entire lives in the US, but of course the Irish-born children experienced the famine directly. In other settings, research has shown that immigrants tend to negatively select into enclaves, but that conditional on this sorting, immigrant enclaves may be beneficial (Cutler, Glaeser, and Vigdor 2008; Damm 2009; Edin, Fredriksson, and Åslund 2003) or detrimental (Battisti, Peri, Romiti 2018; Eriksson 2018) for employment outcomes. Table 7 shows that residing in a home with a high

49 The number of observations in this table is reduced relative to the number of famine Irish described in Tables 3 and 5. The difference is accounted for by individuals whose surnames were not sufficiently common in the 1901 Irish census to determine their Catholicity measure (we require at least 200 individuals with similar names in the 1901 Irish census). Columns (1) and (3) include controls for the 1850 head of household’s occupational category. Columns (2) and (4) control for the log of the 1850 head of household’s occupational wealth score. The coefficient on this variable, which is the intergenerational elasticity of the occupational wealth score, is 0.087 (se=0.038) in both columns. As the occupational wealth measure is novel to this paper, there is no reason to expect that this elasticity would resemble intergenerational elasticities estimated in other contexts. 50 We recognize that there are individuals who would have been born in the US but who would have been in utero in Ireland during the famine. Unfortunately, the fact that we do not observe the actual year of arrival (only a range) prevents us from identifying these individuals. We thus consider the coefficient on Famine In Utero to be an understatement of the correlation in question.

24 share of Irish neighbors was associated with worse outcomes for children, but the estimates are very imprecise. Thus, there is no clear evidence that links residence in an Irish enclave to worse (or better) outcomes, conditional on 1850 observables. The predominantly Catholic character of the famine immigrants was highly controversial at the time. Their religion was seen as a barrier to assimilation in a predominantly Protestant society, and some US natives were openly hostile (Anbinder 1992; Hirota 2017). As described above, we used full-count micro-level data from Ireland’s 1901 census to calculate the fraction of individuals who were Catholic by surname; we then merged that information with the linked dataset. Having a “more Catholic” surname is strongly negatively correlated with sons’ labor market outcomes, even after conditioning on fathers’ economic status and literacy and the Irishness of the child’s neighborhood. We caution that this result is difficult to interpret. It is plausible that it reflects poor treatment of Irish Catholics in labor markets; it is also plausible that it reflects unobserved differences in background characteristics and human capital accumulation that are not sufficiently controlled for in the regression. That said, this statistical association is strong. A typical “Catholic” surname had a Catholicity of 0.95 whereas a typical “Protestant” surname had a Catholicity of 0.18.51 This difference translates to Catholics being about 11 percentage points more likely to hold an unskilled occupation (relative to a group mean of 42 percent) and having a roughly 20 percent lower occupational wealth score. Finally, in a separate specification we add an indicator variable for interstate migrants. The connection between economic and geographic mobility is salient to mid-nineteenth century economic history; in the US context, the prominent “safety valve” theory argues that geographic mobility was an important channel for economic mobility by the urban poor (e.g., Ferrie 1997b; Stewart 2006). In recent work, Pérez (2018) has shown that geographic mobility may have been an important contributor to economic mobility in nineteenth century Argentina, another major destination for European migrants. It is interesting, and perhaps surprising, that the results in Table 7 show that there is no evidence that geographic mobility, as measured by moving states, was an important avenue for occupational advance among the famine-era Irish children. Most of the famine-era migrants’ children did relocate between 1850 and 1880 (Table 5), but their relocation was not associated with occupational upgrades relative to their father. It remains possible, however, that the Irish benefited as a group from the geographic mobility of others, or that negative selection into internal migration may have obscured gains (Ferrie 1997b; Stewart 2006).

51 That is, plotting the density of the Catholicity variable reveals local modes at 0.95 and at 0.18.

25 6. Conclusions This paper builds a large dataset of linked US census records to shed new light on the assimilation of a large group of desperate, poor, and culturally distinct immigrants—the Irish fleeing the Great Famine. The complete count census-based approach to linking and studying the Irish and other immigrants provides several advantages relative to the existing literature. The linked dataset includes immigrants regardless of their port of arrival (including arrivals via Canada), is nationally representative, distinguishes clearly between those arriving before and during the Irish famine, and relies on measures of human capital and occupation that are consistently enumerated across groups. The linked data ensure that we study a fixed group of individuals over time, which avoids spurious results driven by changes in sample composition, as discussed by Lubotsky (2007) and Abramitzky, Boustan, and Eriksson (2014). The new dataset forms the basis for a more definitive picture of migrant selection during the Irish famine and immigrant assimilation patterns in the early Age of Mass Migration. We find evidence of a decline in human capital among the famine-era Irish immigrants relative to previous Irish migrants and relative to other immigrant and native groups. As a result of this deteriorating selection, the migrants’ poor labor market outcomes, and the backlash against Irish immigrants, the children of the famine Irish faced long odds. But as adults they significantly narrowed the gap in occupational status relative to natives in comparison to their fathers’ starting point, and they nearly kept pace with sons of US natives whose fathers were similarly situated in 1850. In this sense, there is strong evidence of economic assimilation by the famine Irish. This is the paper’s main finding. Among the children of the famine-era Irish immigrants, conditional on observables in 1850, we find differences in occupational outcomes depending on the Catholicity of their surname; we also find that children born in Ireland, even those who spent nearly their entire life in the US, fared worse that those born in the US, potentially reflecting exposure to famine conditions. The paper’s findings advance the literature on the economics of migration in several ways. First and most directly, they add to our knowledge of the early decades of the Age of Mass Migration (Hatton and Williamson 1998, Cohn 2009), especially Irish migration to the US during the Great Famine (Mokyr and Ó Gráda 1982; Miller 1985; Ó Gráda and O’Rourke 1997; Ferrie 1999). Prior research on this period has been hampered by data limitations that are inherent to mid-nineteenth century records. The census did not inquire about the year of immigration in this period, and passenger lists from ships are incomplete in their coverage and difficult to link. Consequently, much of the recent surge in research on the Age of Mass Migration has focused on the early twentieth century, by which time the US economy had passed through a remarkable period of economic growth

26 and transformation. The complete count census files allow us to form relatively large, conservatively linked samples and to classify arrival cohorts for many households in 1850 using the age and birthplace of children. We can trace labor market assimilation at the micro level by connecting fathers and sons over a period of 30 years. This distinguishes our work from that of Ferrie (1999), as do our detailed comparisons of the famine-era arrivals to those who arrived earlier. The paper also contributes to the extensive economics literature on immigrants’ labor market assimilation. The influx of immigrants circa 1850 was very large relative to the size of the US population; it is, therefore, a particularly important event in the annals of mass migration, albeit understudied for reasons discussed above. Apart from its sheer magnitude, this historical setting is appealing because it allows scholars to study assimilation in the absence of federal policy barriers to entry, legal curbs on discrimination, or a robust social safety net. The observed assimilation patterns are primarily the product of the economic and social forces, rather than of screening or support policy. Moreover, unlike much of the literature on immigrant children’s outcomes that relies on cross-sectional data sources, the linked dataset built in this paper allows a direct, micro-level connection to be made between childhood circumstances and adult labor market outcomes. The paper’s final contribution is to the economics of migration in cases of natural or man- made disasters. In addition to research on the quantity of migration in response to large negative shocks, the selection of refugees into migration and their subsequent labor market assimilation are important concerns for receiving countries. This paper speaks to both selection and assimilation questions from the perspective of perhaps the largest wave of disaster refugees that the US has ever absorbed. Despite the desperate conditions in which many famine-era migrants arrived and their relatively low levels of human capital, their children showed strong evidence of “assimilation and contribution” in the labor market. Thus, the paper provides useful historical perspective at a time when refugees are once again viewed by many with skepticism and scorn.

27 References

Abramitzky, Ran, Leah Platt Boustan, and Katherine Eriksson (2012). “Europe’s Tired, Poor, Huddled Masses: Self-Selection and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass Migration.” American Economic Review 102:5, pp. 1832-1856.

Abramitzky, Ran, Leah Platt Boustan, and Katherine Eriksson (2014). “A Nation of Immigrants: Assimilation and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass Migration.” Journal of Political Economy 122:3, pp. 467–506.

Abramitzky, Ran, Leah Platt Boustan, and Katherine Eriksson (2016). “Cultural Assimilation During the Age of Mass Migration.” NBER Working Paper 22381.

Abramitzky, Ran, Roy Mill, and Santiago Pérez (2018). “Linking Individuals Across Historical Sources: A Fully Automated Approach.” Historical Methods Forthcoming.

Alexander, Rohan and Zachary Ward (2018). “Age at Arrival and Assimilation during the Age of Mass Migration.” Journal of Economic History 78:3, pp. 904-937.

Alsan, Marcella, Katherine Eriksson, and Gregory Niemesh (2019). “The Rise and Fall of the Know- Nothing Party.” Mimeo., Miami University.

Anbinder, Tyler (1992). Nativism and Slavery: The Northern Know Nothings and the Politics of the 1850s. New York: Oxford University Press.

Anbinder, Tyler and Hope McCaffrey (2015). “Which Irish Men and Women Immigrated to the United States during the Great Famine Migration of 1846–54?” Irish Historical Studies 39:156, pp. 620–642.

Anbinder, Tyler, Cormac Ó Gráda and Simone A. Wegge (2017). “Networks of Opportunity: How Emigrants from the Great Irish Famine Survived, and Eventually Thrived, in New York and Beyond.” Mimeo., University College, Dublin.

Bailey, Martha, Connor Cole, Morgan Henderson, and Catherine Massey (2017). “How Well Do Automated Methods Perform in Historical Samples? Evidence from New Ground Truth.” NBER Working Paper 24019.

Barde, Robert, Susan B. Carter, and Richard Sutch (2006). “Table Ad106-120: Immigrants, by country of last residence—Europe, 1820-1997.” In Historical Statistics of the United States. Susan B. Carter, Scott Sigmund Gardner, Michael R. Haines, Alan L. Olmstead, Richard Sutch, and Gavin Wright (ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1.560-1.563.

Battisti, Michele, Giovanni Peri, and Agnese Romiti (2018). “Dynamic Effects of Co-Ethnic Networks on Immigrants’ Economic Success.” NBER Working Paper 22389.

Beach, Brian, Joseph P. Ferrie, Martin Saavedra, and Werner Troesken (2016). “Typhoid Fever, Water Quality, and Human Capital Formation.” Journal of Economic History 76:1, pp. 41-75.

28 Beaman, Lori A. (2012). “Social Networks and the Dynamics of Labour Market Outcomes: Evidence from Refugees Resettled in the US.” Review of Economic Studies 79:1, pp. 128–161.

Blum, Matthias and Claudia Rei (2018). “Escaping Europe: Health and Human Capital of Holocaust Refugees.” European Review of Economic History 22:1, pp. 1-27.

Borjas, George J. (1987). “Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants.” American Economic Review 77:4, pp. 531–553.

Borjas, George J. (1992). “Ethnic Capital and Intergenerational Mobility.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:1, pp. 123-150.

Borjas, George J. (1993). “The Intergenerational Mobility of Immigrants.” Journal of Labor Economics 11:1, pp. 113-135.

Boustan, Leah Platt, Matthew E. Kahn, and Paul W. Rhode (2012). “Moving to Higher Ground: Migration Response to Natural Disasters in the Early Twentieth Century.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 102:3, pp. 238–244.

Caponi, Vincenzo (2011). “Intergenerational Transmission of Abilities and Self-Selection of Mexican Immigrants.” International Economic Review 52:2, pp. 523-547.

Card, David (1990). “The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the Miami Labor Market.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 43:2, pp. 245-257.

Card, David (2005). “Is the New Immigration Really So Bad?” Economic Journal 115, pp. F300- F323.

Card, David, John DiNardo, and Eugena Estes (2000). “The More Things Change: Immigrants and the Children of Immigrants in the 1940s, the 1970s, and the 1990s.” In Issues in the Economics of Immigration. George J. Borjas (ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 227-270.

Chiquiar, Daniel and Gordon H. Hanson (2005). “International Migration, Self-Selection, and the Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the United States.” Journal of Political Economy 113:2, pp. 239-281.

Chiswick, Barry R. (1978). “The Effect of Americanization on the Earnings of Foreign-Born Men.” Journal of Political Economy 86:5, pp. 897-921.

Cohn, Raymond L. (1995). “Occupational Evidence on the Causes of Immigration to the United States, 1836-1853.” Explorations in Economic History 32, pp. 383-408.

Cohn, Raymond L. (2009). Mass Migration Under Sail: European Immigration to the Antebellum United States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Collins, William J. and Marianne H. Wanamaker (2017). “Up from Slavery? African American Intergenerational Mobility since 1880.” NBER Working Paper 23395.

29 Commissioners Appointed to Take the Census of Ireland (1843). Report of the Commissioners Appointed to Take the Census of Ireland for the Year 1841. Dublin: Alexander Thom.

Connor, Dylan S. (2019). “The Cream of the Crop? Geography, Networks, and Irish Migrant Selection in the Age of Mass Migration.” Journal of Economic History Forthcoming.

Cortes, Kalena E. (2004). “Are Refugees Different from Economic Immigrants? Some Empirical Evidence on the Heterogeneity of Immigrant Groups in the United States.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86:2, pp. 465-480.

Cutler, David M., Edward L. Glaeser, and Jacob L. Vigdor (2008). “When Are Ghettos Bad? Lessons from Immigrant Segregation in the United States.” Journal of Urban Economics 63, pp. 759-774.

Damm, Anna Piil (2009). “Ethnic Enclaves and Immigrant Labor Market Outcomes: Quasi- Experimental Evidence.” Journal of Labor Economics 27:2, pp. 281-314.

Delaney, Enda (2015). “Refugee Crisis Has Chilling Parallels with the Famine Years.” Irish Times.

Edin, Per-Anders, Peter Fredriksson, and Olof Åslund (2003). “Ethnic Enclaves and the Economic Success of Immigrants—Evidence from a Natural Experiment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118:1, pp. 329-357.

Eriksson, Katherine (2018). “Ethnic Enclaves and Immigrant Outcomes: Norwegian Immigrants during the Age of Mass Migration.” NBER Working Paper 24763.

Ernst, Robert (1949). Immigrant Life in New York City, 1825-1863. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press.

Evans, William N. and Daniel Fitzgerald (2017). “The Economic and Social Outcomes of Refugees: Evidence from the ACS.” NBER Working Paper 23498.

Feigenbaum, James J. (2018). “Multiple Measures of Historical Intergenerational Mobility: Iowa 1915 to 1940.” Economic Journal 128, pp. F446-F481.

Ferenczi, Imre and Walter F. Wilcox (1929). International Migrations. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Ferrie, Joseph P. (1994). “The Wealth Accumulation of Antebellum European Immigrants to the US, 1840–60.” Journal of Economic History 54:1, pp. 1–33.

Ferrie, Joseph P. (1995). “Up and Out or Down and Out? Immigrant Mobility in the Antebellum United States.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 26:1, pp. 33–55.

Ferrie, Joseph P. (1996). “A New Sample of Males Linked from the Public Use Microdata Sample of the 1850 US Federal Census of Population to the 1860 US Federal Census Manuscript Schedules.” Historical Methods 29:4, pp. 141-156.

Ferrie, Joseph P. (1997a). “The Entry into the US Labor Market of Antebellum European Immigrants, 1840–1860.” Explorations in Economic History 34, pp. 295–330.

30

Ferrie, Joseph P. (1997b). “Migration to the Frontier in Mid-Nineteenth Century America: A Re- Examination of Turner’s ‘Safety Valve.’” Mimeo., Northwestern University.

Ferrie, Joseph P. (1997c). “A New View of the Irish in America: Economic Performance and the Impact of Place of Origin, 1850-1920.” Mimeo., Northwestern University.

Ferrie, Joseph P. (1999). Yankeys Now: Immigrants in the Antebellum United States, 1840–1860. New York: Oxford University Press.

Geary, Frank (1996). “Regional Industrial Structure and Labour Force Decline in Ireland between 1841 and 1851.” Irish Historical Studies 30:118, pp. 167-194.

Gelbach, Jonah B. (2016). “When Do Covariates Matter? And Which Ones, and How Much?” Journal of Labor Economics 34:2, pp. 509-543.

Guinnane, Timothy W. (1997). The Vanishing Irish: Households, Migration, and the Rural Economy in Ireland, 1850-1914. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Haider, Steven and Gary Solon (2006). “Life-Cycle Variation in the Association between Current and Lifetime Earnings.” American Economic Review 96:4, pp. 1308-1320.

Handlin, Oscar (1991 [1941]). Boston’s Immigrants, 1790-1880: A Study of Acculturation, Revised and Enlarged Edition. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.

Hatton, Timothy J. (1997). “The Immigrant Assimilation Puzzle in Late Nineteenth-Century America.” Journal of Economic History 57:1, pp. 34-62.

Hatton, Timothy J. (2012). “Refugee and Asylum Migration to the OECD: A Short Overview.” IZA Discussion Paper 7004.

Hatton, Timothy J. and Jeffrey G. Williamson (1994). “What Drove the Mass Migrations from Europe in the Late Nineteenth Century?” Population and Development Review 20, 3, pp. 533-559.

Hatton, Timothy J. and Jeffrey G. Williamson (1998). The Age of Mass Migration: Causes and Economic Impact. New York: Oxford University Press.

Hirota, Hidetaka (2017). Expelling the Poor: Atlantic Seaboard States and the Nineteenth-Century Origins of American Immigration Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.

Hornbeck, Richard (2012). “The Enduring Impact of the American Dust Bowl: Short- and Long-Run Adjustments to Environmental Catastrophe.” American Economic Review 102:4, pp. 1477–1507.

Kelly, John (2018). “Transcript: White House Chief of Staff John Kelly’s Interview with NPR.” NPR.org.

Logan, Trevon D. and John M. Parman (2017). “The National Rise in Residential Segregation.” Journal of Economic History 77:1, pp. 127-170.

31 Long, Jason and Joseph P. Ferrie (2013). “Intergenerational Occupational Mobility in Great Britain and the United States since 1850.” American Economic Review 103:4, pp. 1109-1137.

Long, Jason and Henry E. Siu (2018). “Refugees from Dust and Shrinking Land: Tracking the Dust Bowl Migrants.” Journal of Economic History 78:4, pp. 1001-1033.

Lubotsky, Darren (2007). “Chutes or Ladders? A Longitudinal Analysis of Immigrant Earnings.” Journal of Political Economy 115: 5, pp. 820-867.

Mahajan, Parag and Dean Yang (2017). “Taken By Storm: Hurricanes, Migrant Networks, and US Immigration.” NBER Working Paper 23756.

McInnis, Marvin (2000). “The Population of Canada in the Nineteenth Century.” In A Population History of North America. Michael R. Haines and Richard H. Steckel (eds.) Cambridge University Press. Chapter 12, pp. 529-599.

McKenzie, David and Hillel Rapoport (2010). “Self-Selection Patterns in Mexico-US Migration: The Role of Migration Networks.” Review of Economics and Statistics 92:4, pp. 811-821.

Miller, Kirby A. (1985). Emigrants and Exiles: Ireland and the Irish Exodus to North America. New York: Oxford University Press.

Minnesota Population Center (2017). North Atlantic Population Project: Complete Count Microdata: Version 2.3 [Machine-readable dataset]. , MN: University of Minnesota.

Minns, Chris (2000). “Income, Cohort Effects, and Occupational Mobility: A New Look at Immigration to the United States at the Turn of the Twentieth Century.” Explorations in Economic History 37:4, pp. 326-50.

Mokyr, Joel (1983). Why Ireland Starved: An Analytical and Quantitative Study of Irish Poverty, 1800–1851. Boston: George Allen and Unwin.

Mokyr, Joel and Cormac Ó Gráda (1982). “Emigration and Poverty in Prefamine Ireland.” Explorations in Economic History 19, pp. 360-384.

Moser, Petra, Alessandra Voena, and Fabian Waldinger (2014). “German Jewish Émigrés and US Invention.” American Economic Review 104:10, pp. 3222-3255.

Nakamura, Emi, Jósef Sigurdsson, and Jón Steinsson (2017). The Gift of Moving: Intergenerational Consequences of a Mobility Shock.” NBER Working Paper 22392.

National Archives of Ireland. n.d. History of Irish Census Records. http://www.census.nationalarchives.ie/help/history.html. Accessed July 20, 2018.

Ó Gráda, Cormac (1983). “Across the Briny Ocean: Some Thoughts on Irish Emigration to America 1800–1850.” In Ireland and Scotland, 1600–1850: Parallels and Contrasts in Economic and Social Development. T. M. Devine and David Dickson (ed.). John Donald. Chap. 9, pp. 118–130.

32 Ó Gráda, Cormac (1999). Black ’47 and Beyond: The Great Irish Famine in History, Economy, and Memory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Ó Gráda, Cormac (2016). “What’s in an Irish Surname? Connollys and Others a Century Ago.” UCD Centre for Economic Research Working Paper WP 2016/05.

Ó Gráda, Cormac (2019). “The Next World and the New World: Relief, Migration, and the Great Irish Famine.” Journal of Economic History Forthcoming.

Ó Gráda, Cormac and Kevin H. O’Rourke (1997). “Migration as Disaster Relief: Lessons from the Great Irish Famine.” European Review of Economic History 1, pp. 3–25.

Pérez, Santiago (2018). “Railroads and the Rural to Urban Transition: Evidence from 19th Century Argentina.” Mimeo., UC Davis.

Pérez, Santiago (2019a). “Intergenerational Occupational Mobility Across Three Continents.” Journal of Economic History Forthcoming.

Pérez, Santiago (2019b). “Southern (American) Hospitality: Italians in Argentina and the United States during the Age of Mass Migration.” Mimeo., UC Davis.

Roy, A. D. (1951). “Some Thoughts on the Distribution of Earnings.” Oxford Economic Papers 3:2, pp. 135–146.

Ruggles, Steven, Katie Genadek, Ronald Goeken, Josiah Grover, and Matthew Sobek (2015). Integrated Public Use Microdata Series: Version 6.0 [Machine-readable database]. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota.

Solar, Peter M. 1989. “The Great Famine Was No Ordinary Subsistence Crisis.” In E.M. Crawford (ed.), Famine: The Irish Experience, 900-1900, Edinburgh: John Donald, pp. 112-131.

Spitzer, Yannay (2018). “Pogroms, Networks, and Migration: The Jewish Migration from the Russian Empire to the United States 1881–1914.” Mimeo. Hebrew University of Jerusalem.

Spitzer, Yannay and Ariell Zimran (2018). “Migrant Self-Selection: Anthropometric Evidence from the Mass Migration of Italians to the United States, 1907–1925.” Journal of Development Economics 134, pp. 226-247.

Stewart, James I. (2006). “Migration to the Agricultural Frontier and Wealth Accumulation, 1860- 1870.” Explorations in Economic History 43, pp. 547-577.

United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (2017). Global Trends: Forced Displacement in 2017. United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees.

US Department of State, US Department of Homeland Security, and US Department of Health and Human Services (2017). Proposed Refugee Admissions for Fiscal Year 2018.

US Immigration Commission (1911). Reports, 61st Congress, 1st Session. Washington, DC: GPO.

33 Wegge, Simone A. (1998). “Chain Migration and Information Networks: Evidence from Nineteenth- Century Hesse-Cassel.” Journal of Economic History 58:4, pp. 957-986.

White, Michael J. and Erica Jade Mullen (2016). “Socioeconomic Attainment in the Ellis Island Era.” Social Science History 40:1, pp. 147-181.

34 Figures Figure 1: Selection into linkage

1

.8

.6

.4

.2

0 Age Farm Native School Urban Craft head Farmer head Occ. wealth Famine status Head's literacyHead's propertyHousehold size Unskilled head Head's occ. score Name Catholicness White collar head

All Linked

Note: Sample covers sons of 1850 Irish heads of household. The “Linked” group contains 1850 sons who were successfully linked to 1880. The “All” group includes these individuals as well as those whose could not be linked. Values are divided by the smallest multiple of 10 needed to generate a mean below 1.

35 Figure 2: Selection into classification

1

.8

.6

.4

.2

0 Age Farm Native School Urban Craft head Farmer head Occ. wealth Head's literacyHead's propertyHousehold size Unskilled head Head's occ. score Name Catholicness White collar head

All Classified

Note: Sample covers sons of 1850 Irish heads of household and is limited to those who could be linked from 1850 to 1880. Observations weighted to correct for selection into linkage. The “Classified” group contains 1850 sons who were linked to 1880 and whose head of household’s arrival cohort could be determined. The “All” group includes these individuals as well as those whose head of household’s arrival cohort could not be determined. Values are divided by the smallest multiple of 10 needed to generate a mean below 1.

36 Figure 3: Comparison of adults’ and children’s outcomes Figure 3(a): Unskilled Occupation

.6

.4

.2

0

Famine Irish Famine British Pre-Famine Irish Famine Germans Pre-Famine British Pre-Famine Germans

Heads (1850) Sons (1880)

Figure 3(b): Occupational Wealth Score

0

-.5

-1

-1.5

Famine Irish Famine British Pre-Famine Irish Famine Germans Pre-Famine British Pre-Famine Germans

Heads (1850) Sons (1880)

Note: Bars in panel 3(a) for 1850 heads of household are coefficients from column (3) of Table 4. Bars in panel 3(a) for 1880 sons are coefficients from column (1) of Table 6. Bars in panel 3(b) for 1850 heads of household are coefficients from column (5) of Table 4. Bars in panel 3(b) for 1880 sons are coefficients from column (2) of Table 6.

37 Figure 4: Unconditional and conditional coefficients for 1880 characteristics Figure 4(a): Unskilled Occupation

.3

.2

.1

0

-.1

Famine Irish Famine British Pre-Famine Irish Famine Germans Pre-Famine British Pre-Famine Germans

Baseline Controls Controls and Nativity

Figure 4(b): Occupational Wealth Score

.2

0

-.2

-.4

-.6

Famine Irish Famine British Pre-Famine Irish Famine Germans Pre-Famine British Pre-Famine Germans

Baseline Controls Controls and Nativity

Note: Coefficients portrayed by the “Raw” bars are reached by conditioning only on a quartic in individual’s age; they are from columns (1) and (2) of Table 6. Coefficients portrayed by the “Controls” bars come from regressions that control for the 1850 household characteristics, as described in text. They are presented in columns (1) and (2) of Table C.1. Coefficients portrayed by the “Native” bars come from regressions including all 1850 controls and indicators for native birth of sons. They are presented in columns (3) and (4) of Table C.1.

38 Tables

Table 1: Sample divisions

Household Heads Sons (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Famine Status Irish British Germans Irish British Germans Not Famine 77,238 47,594 49,638 139,968 84,036 93,063 (0.371) (0.435) (0.307) (0.561) (0.640) (0.524) Famine 15,009 7,422 11,237 23,116 12,127 17,229 (0.072) (0.068) (0.069) (0.093) (0.092) (0.097) Maybe Famine 6,268 2,833 7,452 11,508 5,787 14,472 (0.030) (0.026) (0.046) (0.046) (0.044) (0.081) Unknown 109,846 51,511 93,517 55,865 23,591 46,014 (0.527) (0.471) (0.578) (0.224) (0.180) (0.259) Total 208,361 109,360 161,844 249,583 131,304 177,739 Notes: This Table enumerates individuals observed in 1850 who were either heads of household over 18 years old, or who were aged 0 to 18 years and were sons of men born in Ireland, Britain, or Germany. Famine status is determined as described in text. Divisions in columns (4)–(6) are according to the place of birth of the head of household. Numbers in parentheses are fractions of the column total.

39

1 Table 2: Linkage rates for the seven categories

(1) (2) (3) Famine Status Start Searched Linked Panel A: Irish Pre-Famine 139,968 52,189 10,338 (0.373) (0.198) Famine 23,116 9,665 1,473 (0.418) (0.152) Panel B: British Pre-Famine 84,036 35,051 9,182 (0.417) (0.262) Famine 12,127 7,066 1,589 (0.583) (0.225) Panel C: Germans Pre-Famine 93,063 57,398 10,071 (0.617) (0.175) Famine 17,229 13,194 1,834 (0.766) (0.139) Panel D: Americans All 3,725,019 1,686,500 424,500 (0.453) (0.252) Notes: Panel headers refer to ethnicities (i.e., fathers’ birthplaces). Column (1) enumerates all males in 1850 who were aged between 0 and 18 years and who were the children of a head of household born in the United States, Ireland, Britain, or Germany who was either na- tive or whose household composition enabled the determination of arrival cohort. Column (2) enumerates those individuals from col- umn (1) for whom an attempt was made to link to 1880. Column (3) enumerates those individuals from column (2) who were successfully linked to the 1880 census. Numbers in parentheses indicate the frac- tion of observations from the previous column that were advanced to the next column.

40

1 Table 3: Summary statistics for linked children, 1850

Irish British Germans Americans (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Variable Pre-Famine Famine Pre-Famine Famine Pre-Famine Famine All Head’s human capital Literacy 0.858 0.790 0.961 0.946 0.972 0.975 0.903 (0.349) (0.407) (0.195) (0.227) (0.165) (0.157) (0.296) Numeracy 0.560 0.494 0.695 0.723 0.716 0.688 0.738 (0.496) (0.500) (0.460) (0.448) (0.451) (0.463) (0.439) Head’s labor market characteristics ln(Occ. Wealth) 7.395 6.719 7.843 7.403 7.810 7.498 7.939 (1.101) (0.955) (0.898) (0.915) (0.980) (1.024) (0.804) Occ. Rank 29.974 15.238 39.532 27.878 39.442 31.214 40.486 (27.872) (22.131) (26.577) (24.204) (26.715) (24.836) (22.235) White collar 0.095 0.050 0.137 0.077 0.133 0.080 0.079 (0.293) (0.217) (0.344) (0.266) (0.340) (0.271) (0.270) Craft 0.227 0.178 0.352 0.419 0.299 0.302 0.185 (0.419) (0.383) (0.477) (0.494) (0.458) (0.459) (0.388) Farmer 0.296 0.104 0.371 0.208 0.402 0.340 0.640 (0.456) (0.306) (0.483) (0.406) (0.490) (0.474) (0.480) Unskilled 0.382 0.668 0.140 0.297 0.165 0.279 0.096 (0.486) (0.471) (0.347) (0.457) (0.371) (0.449) (0.295) Real property (1,000) 0.946 0.158 1.315 0.214 0.991 0.312 1.523 (4.130) (2.148) (4.382) (0.715) (4.423) (1.076) (7.102) Son’s characteristics School (ages 5-15) 0.714 0.518 0.742 0.577 0.647 0.427 0.675 (0.452) (0.500) (0.438) (0.494) (0.478) (0.495) (0.468) Native 0.930 0.123 0.915 0.110 0.906 0.126 (0.256) (0.329) (0.278) (0.313) (0.292) (0.331) Irish name Catholicness 0.687 0.754 (0.308) (0.272) Famine in utero 0.403 (0.491) Place of residence characteristics Urban 0.451 0.546 0.311 0.373 0.362 0.422 0.106 (0.498) (0.498) (0.463) (0.484) (0.480) (0.494) (0.308) Fraction Irish in 100 0.254 0.297 0.117 0.163 0.079 0.094 0.034 (0.225) (0.229) (0.139) (0.171) (0.111) (0.119) (0.068) Observations 9,977 1,388 8,939 1,536 9,791 1,742 376,905 Notes: Table includes sons who were under 18 years old in 1850 who could be linked to 1880 and whose head of household’s arrival cohort could be determined. Observations grouped by head’s nativity and arrival cohort. All figures weighted to correct for selection into linkage on observables. Standard deviations in parentheses. Sample sizes are the minimum with data for all variables other than School, Name Catholicness, Famine in utero, and Fraction Irish in 100.

1 41 Table 4: Regressions of 1850 characteristics

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Variables Literacy Numeracy Unskill Farmer Occ. Wealth Occ. Rank Property School Pre-Famine Irish 0.048a 0.177a 0.289a 0.345a 0.555a 10.798a 0.627a 0.043a (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.012) (0.306) (0.058) (0.007) Famine Irish 0.113a 0.248a 0.565a 0.511a 1.191a 24.568a 1.127a 0.141a (0.012) (0.014) (0.013) (0.008) (0.026) (0.588) (0.037) (0.023) Pre-Famine British 0.054a 0.041a 0.048a 0.274a 0.113a 1.390a 0.307a 0.067a (0.002) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005) (0.010) (0.305) (0.049) (0.007) Famine British 0.044a 0.021c 0.190a 0.400a 0.495a 11.639a 0.985a 0.089a (0.007) (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) (0.024) (0.631) (0.027) (0.021) Pre-Famine Germans 0.065a 0.021a 0.071a 0.237a 0.141a 1.351a 0.582a 0.022a (0.002) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005) (0.011) (0.279) (0.062) (0.007) Famine Germans 0.070a 0.052a 0.178a 0.281a 0.424a 8.899a 1.054a 0.237a (0.004) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011) (0.025) (0.592) (0.033) (0.019) Observations 410,278 410,278 410,278 410,278 410,278 410,278 410,278 202,139 R-squared 0.007 0.008 0.055 0.054 0.039 0.024 0.008 0.025 F-Test 14.145a 10.828a 45.845a 31.561a 42.866a 22.584a 3.898b 1.871

Significance levels: a p<0.01, b p<0.05, c p<0.1 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. All specifications include a quartic in age and are weighted by inverse linkage probability. F-tests are of the joint null that the difference between the famine Irish and pre-famine Irish coefficients is equal to the difference between the famine and pre-famine coefficients for the other two ethnicities. Excluded group in all specifications is members of native-headed households.

1

42 Table 5: Summary statistics for linked children, 1880

Irish British Germans Americans (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Variable Pre-Famine Famine Pre-Famine Famine Pre-Famine Famine All Labor market characteristics ln(Occ. Wealth) 7.628 7.281 7.877 7.726 7.830 7.667 7.803 (1.045) (1.090) (0.992) (0.943) (1.022) (1.062) (0.993) Occ. Rank 39.434 31.758 45.876 40.955 44.622 40.481 43.776 (27.446) (26.849) (27.118) (25.884) (27.098) (27.734) (24.953) White collar 0.195 0.145 0.224 0.171 0.207 0.196 0.152 (0.396) (0.352) (0.417) (0.376) (0.405) (0.397) (0.359) Craft 0.304 0.289 0.264 0.341 0.266 0.330 0.168 (0.460) (0.454) (0.441) (0.474) (0.442) (0.470) (0.374) Farmer 0.226 0.137 0.323 0.257 0.330 0.229 0.487 (0.418) (0.344) (0.468) (0.437) (0.470) (0.420) (0.500) Unskilled 0.244 0.415 0.162 0.211 0.170 0.227 0.165 (0.430) (0.493) (0.369) (0.408) (0.376) (0.419) (0.371) Place of residence Moved state 0.364 0.690 0.379 0.634 0.327 0.699 0.339 (0.481) (0.462) (0.485) (0.482) (0.469) (0.459) (0.474) Observations 9,654 1,366 8,683 1,505 9,529 1,710 366,144 Notes: Table includes sons who were under 18 years old in 1850 who could be linked to 1880 and whose head of household’s arrival cohort could be determined. Observations grouped by head’s nativity and arrival cohort. All figures weighted to correct for selection into linkage on observables. Standard deviations in parentheses. Sample sizes are the minimum with data for all variables.

1 43 Table 6: Regressions of 1880 characteristics

(1) (2) (3) Variables Unskill Occ. Wealth Occ. Rank Pre-Famine Irish 0.078a 0.170a 4.239a (0.005) (0.012) (0.307) Famine Irish 0.237a 0.478a 11.075a (0.014) (0.031) (0.756) Pre-Famine British 0.000 0.065a 1.891a (0.004) (0.011) (0.309) Famine British 0.033a 0.035 1.893a (0.011) (0.025) (0.689) Pre-Famine Germans 0.003 0.036a 1.022a (0.004) (0.011) (0.287) Famine Germans 0.049a 0.093a 2.356a (0.010) (0.026) (0.685) Observations 410,278 398,591 398,591 R-squared 0.013 0.017 0.014 F-Test 26.015a 13.252a 5.729a

Significance levels: a p<0.01, b p<0.05, c p<0.1 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. All specifications include a quartic in age and are weighted by inverse linkage probability. F-tests are of the joint null that the difference between the famine Irish and pre-famine Irish coefficients is equal to the difference between the famine and pre-famine coefficients for the other two ethnicities. Excluded group in all specifications is members of native- headed households.

1

44 Table 7: Correlates of upward mobility among the famine Irish

(1) (2) (3) (4) Variables Unskill Occ. Wealth Unskill Occ. Wealth Head Literacy (1850) 0.074 0.064 0.072 0.064 (0.045) (0.098) (0.045) (0.098) Native 0.075 0.327b 0.058 0.326b (0.063) (0.135) (0.064) (0.135) Famine in utero 0.063 0.000 0.052 0.001 (0.049) (0.113) (0.049) (0.114) Irish Name Catholicness 0.166a 0.294b 0.163a 0.294b (0.051) (0.117) (0.051) (0.117) Fraction Irish in 100 0.045 0.128 0.048 0.128 (0.074) (0.167) (0.074) (0.168) Moved State 0.065c 0.003 (0.036) (0.080) Observations 968 951 968 951 R-squared 0.046 0.032 0.049 0.032

Significance levels: a p<0.01, b p<0.05, c p<0.1 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. Sample limited to famine Irish children. All specifi- cations include a quartic in age of the individual and the 1850 household head and are weighted by inverse linkage probability. Columns with an indicator for holding an unskilled occuptation as the dependent variable condition on indicators of the father’s occupational status. Columns with the log of the occupational wealth score as the outcomes condition on the log of the father’s occupational wealth score.

1

45 Data Appendix (not for publication)

Appendix A: Census linkage

The linkage procedure was the following. 1. Men with non-empty first and last names were extracted from the 1850 census, and punctuation was removed. 2. The listed first name was divided into a given name and middle initial, when one was present. 3. Standard first name abbreviations were replaced (e.g., “Wm” was replaced with “William”). 4. Any remaining spaces were removed from the names. 5. The list of cleaned men's names generated by steps 1-4 was linked to itself on the following characteristics: a. Birthplace matches b. Absolute difference in birth years less than or equal to 4 c. First three characters of last name soundex match, and either of the following two conditions are true:52 i. The last name soundexes are identical and the SAS spelling distance is less than or equal to 20.53 ii. The last name soundexes are non-identical, and the SAS spelling distance is less than or equal to 17. d. First letter of first name matches, and spelling distance between first names is less than or equal to 20. 6. Any individual with a match in step 5 (other than himself) was removed from the sample. 7. The remaining men from 1850 and all those from 1880 were cleaned according to steps 1, 2, and 4 above (no standardization of name abbreviations was made). 8. Men in 1850 were linked to 1880 according to the criteria listed in step 5, as well as the

52 This is not a soundex match; the soundex is used to limit the set of candidate matches, which are then evaluated based on spelling distance. 53 The SAS spelling distance is not a symmetric measure. Whenever I use spelling distance, I make a match when min spedis,, spedis, ≤ �, where c is the linkage cutoff.

46 following additional characteristic: a. Where both records report a middle initial, the middle initials must match for a match to occur. 9. Of the candidate matches created in step 8, any match in which more than one 1880 individual matched to an 1850 individual, or in which more than one 1850 individual matched to the same 1880 individual, was removed.

Table A.1 presents the rates of successful linkage by the individual’s place of birth (so that native-born sons of immigrants are in column 4). This Table is not restricted to sons; it also includes others, such as heads of household and boarders. Tables A.2 presents the results of a linear probability model relating the probability of being successfully linked between 1850 and 1880 to a variety of characteristics observed in 1850. This Table divides the sample by the ethnicity of the head of household in 1850.

Table A.1: Linkage rates by place of birth

Birth Place (1) (2) (3) (4) Stage Irish British German American Start 998,625 391,615 602,955 17,667,555 Males 520,096 224,874 345,581 8,963,889 Searched 164,710 108,399 222,648 4,286,869 Linked 18,378 18,684 24,822 892,443 Notes: All observations enumerated are from the 1850 census. Table is not limited to individuals who were sons in 1850. Observations are divided by birth place and not ethnicity. Individuals enumerated in the row labeled Searched are those for whom an atempt was made to make a match to the 1880 census. Individuals enumerated in the row labeled Linked are those for whom a unique match could be made in the 1880 census.

47

1 Table A.2: Selection into linkage, children

(1) (2) (3) (4) Variables Irish British Germans Americans HH Size 0.002a 0.002a 0.003a 0.001a (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Age 0.001a 0.002a 0.001a 0.001a (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Urban 0.006a 0.004 0.005b 0.017a (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) Farm 0.019b 0.008 0.010 0.014a (0.007) (0.008) (0.010) (0.001) School 0.000 0.004c 0.008a 0.005a (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.000) Head’s Literacy 0.006a 0.013a 0.004 0.007a (0.001) (0.004) (0.004) (0.001) Head’s Occ Wealth 0.001 0.002 0.008a 0.003a (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) Head’s Property 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000a (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Native 0.007a 0.023a 0.004b (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) Head WC 0.008 0.008 0.022b 0.004a (0.008) (0.009) (0.010) (0.001) Head Unskill 0.003 0.014 0.017 0.006a (0.008) (0.009) (0.011) (0.002) Head Craft 0.004 0.005 0.020b 0.001 (0.008) (0.009) (0.010) (0.001) Observations 214,935 118,624 163,421 3,382,996 R-squared 0.010 0.010 0.003 0.011

Significance levels: a p<0.01, b p<0.05, c p<0.1 Notes: These are regressions of an indicator for successful linkage on a variety of 1850 characteristics. Sample includes all males who were under age 18 in 1850 and were sons of a head of household, including those who were omitted for not having unique names. Columns are divided by place of birth of the head of household. All specifications include state FE. Robust standard errors in parentheses.

48

1 Appendix B: Surname-Based Catholicity Imputation Algorithm The algorithm to determine the probability of being Catholic based on surname proceeds as follows. It is based on Spitzer and Zimran’s (2018) algorithm to determine the province of origin of Italian migrants to the United States by their surnames. 1. We obtained the complete 1901 Census of Ireland. Religions listed in this source were manually classified as Catholic, Protestant, or other. Using this source, a list was created of all distinct surnames, along with the number of these individuals who were and were not Catholic. For example, there were 12,238 individuals in 1901 with the surname Collins who were Catholic, and 1,076 individuals in 1901 with the surname Collins who were not Catholic. 2. A list was created of all distinct surnames of individuals in the 1850 US Census who were either born in Ireland or lived in a household headed by an Irish-born individual. 3. These two lists were matched to one another if the first letter matched, and on the following criteria. a. If the soundexes of the entry in the two sources were the same, a match was made if the minimum SPEDIS value between them was less than or equal to 20. b. If the soundexes of the entries in the two sources were not the same, a match was made if the minimum SPEDIS value between them was less than or equal to 17. This approach created, for each surname in the 1850 census, a count of Catholic and non- Catholic individuals to whom the individual was matched in the 1901 Irish census. 4. The surname “Catholicity” was calculated as � ∈ ∈ �

where N is the set of 1901 surnames to which an 1850 individual’s surname was matched, �

is the number of Catholic individuals with surname n in 1901 Ireland, and � is the number of

non-Catholic individuals with the surname n in 1901 Ireland. In cases where � + � < 200, no categorization was made.

49 Appendix C: Additional results Table C.1: Coefficients underlying Figure 4

(1) (2) (3) (4) Variables Unskill Occ. Wealth Unskill Occ. Wealth Pre-Famine Irish 0.024a 0.095a 0.020a 0.084a (0.005) (0.012) (0.005) (0.012) Famine Irish 0.137a 0.273a 0.078a 0.122a (0.014) (0.031) (0.016) (0.036) Pre-Famine British 0.012a 0.022b 0.017a 0.036a (0.004) (0.011) (0.004) (0.011) Famine British 0.010 0.008 0.070a 0.161a (0.011) (0.025) (0.014) (0.032) Pre-Famine Germans 0.010b 0.007 0.017a 0.023b (0.004) (0.011) (0.004) (0.011) Famine Germans 0.020c 0.084a 0.039a 0.066b (0.010) (0.027) (0.013) (0.033) Native 0.068a 0.173a (0.009) (0.022) Observations 410,278 398,591 410,278 398,591 R-squared 0.047 0.091 0.048 0.092 F-Test 18.549a 7.389a 18.469a 7.388a

Significance levels: a p<0.01, b p<0.05, c p<0.1 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. All specifications include a quartic in age and the controls described in text, and are weighted by inverse linkage probability. F-tests are of the joint null that the difference between the famine Irish and the pre-famine Irish coefficients is equal to the difference between the famine and pre-famine coefficients for the other two ethnicities. Excluded group in all specifications is members of native-headed households.

1

50