Urban Evolutions: the Fast, the Slow, and the Still

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Urban Evolutions: the Fast, the Slow, and the Still University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Real Estate Papers Wharton Faculty Research 3-2007 Urban Evolutions: The Fast, the Slow, and the Still Gilles Duranton University of Pennsylvania Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.upenn.edu/real-estate_papers Part of the Real Estate Commons Recommended Citation Duranton, G. (2007). Urban Evolutions: The Fast, the Slow, and the Still. American Economic Review, 97 (1), 197-221. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.97.1.197 This paper is posted at ScholarlyCommons. https://repository.upenn.edu/real-estate_papers/73 For more information, please contact [email protected]. Urban Evolutions: The Fast, the Slow, and the Still Abstract With the use of French and US data, new and systematic evidence is provided about the rapid location changes of industries across cities (the fast). Cities are also slowly moving up and down the urban hierarchy (the slow), while the size distribution of cities is skewed to the right and very stable (the still). The model proposed here reproduces these three features. Small, innovation-driven shocks lead to the churning of industries across cities. Then, cities slowly grow or decline following net gains or losses of industries. These changes occur within a stable distribution. The quantitative implications of the model are also explored. Disciplines Real Estate This journal article is available at ScholarlyCommons: https://repository.upenn.edu/real-estate_papers/73 Urban Evolutions: The Fast, the Slow, and the Still By GILLES DURANTON* With the use of French and US data, new and systematic evidence is provided about the rapid location changes of industries across cities (the fast). Cities are also slowly moving up and down the urban hierarchy (the slow), while the size distri- bution of cities is skewed to the right and very stable (the still). The model proposed here reproduces these three features. Small, innovation-driven shocks lead to the churning of industries across cities. Then, cities slowly grow or decline following net gains or losses of industries. These changes occur within a stable distribution. The quantitative implications of the model are also explored. (JEL R12, R32) A fundamental but much neglected issue in in the shadow of Eastman Kodak, came up with urban development is the role played by the a new process for making copies without the churning of industries across locations. Jane need for developing. The process, called xerog- Jacobs (1970) provides early anecdotal evi- raphy, made Rochester the new capital of the dence about what the key mechanisms at stake duplication industry in place of New York might be. In the late nineteenth century, New (again), where the previous dominant technol- York City was the capital of the photographic ogy, the varityper, was produced. These two industry, whereas Rochester, New York, was industries came to represent an important part of the leading city for precision instruments. Rochester’s employment. George Eastman, while working at improving Section I presents novel and systematic evi- optical instruments in Rochester, invented an dence that there is indeed considerable indus- emulsion-coating machine that enabled him to trial churning across cities. Industries move and mass-produce photographic dry plates. His cities experience rapid changes in the composi- company soon took over the market for photo- tion of their economic activity. This stylized graphic film. As a consequence, Rochester re- fact, the fast, is closely related to two better- placed New York as the main center for the known features of urban evolutions: the slow, industry. Rochester, 50 years later, was still the where cities move slowly up and down the capital of the US film industry, whereas New distribution of city sizes as they grow or decline York was that of the duplication industry. Then, relative to other cities; and the still, where the Haloid Company, a firm specialized in the man- size distributions of cities tend to be stable over ufacturing of photographic papers and operating time and skewed to the right. The model in Section II provides microeco- nomic foundations for the churning of indus- * Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 Saint George Street, Toronto, Ontario M5S 3G7, Canada tries across cities. Formally, it embeds an (e-mail: [email protected]; Web site: http:// extension of Gene M. Grossman and Elhanan individual.utoronto.ca/gilles/default.html). This is a much Helpman’s (1991) quality ladder model in an revised version of a paper previously circulated as “City urban framework. In each industry, research Size Distributions as a Consequence of the Growth Pro- firms try to invent the next step up the quality cess.” I am grateful to Vernon Henderson, Yannis Ioan- nides, Janet Kohlhase, Tomoya Mori, Henry Overman, John ladder in order to reap monopoly profits. Re- Parr, Diego Puga, Kwok Tong Soo, Dan Trefler, Hyoung search firms may be successful in their own Gun Wang, Fabrizio Zilibotti, conference and seminar par- industry or may develop a new leading quality ticipants, and four referees for helpful comments, sugges- in another industry. Local spillovers induce re- tions, and encouragement. I am also grateful to Pierre- Philippe Combes for sharing his data and helping me with search firms in an industry to co-locate with them. Funding from the Leverhulme Trust is gratefully production in the same industry and in most acknowledged. industries, successful innovators need to start 197 198 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2007 producing where they did their research. This economies and crowding (Stuart S. Rosenthal implies that own-industry innovations lead to a and William C. Strange 2004), it is possible to change of monopoly but to no change of loca- replicate the US and French urban systems very tion for an industry. By contrast, cross-industry closely. innovations imply not only a change of monop- There is a large urban growth literature that oly but also, typically, a change of location, builds on the trade-off between agglomeration since the old and new monopolies are not gener- economies and crowding (see Marcus Berliant ally located in the same city. Hence, innovation- and Ping Wang 2004, or J. Vernon Henderson driven shocks provide the basis for the growth and 2006, for surveys). Like this paper, this litera- decline of cities so that urban evolutions result ture often views purposeful innovative activity from the aggregation of small industry-level as a key engine of urban growth. Its main em- shocks. phasis, however, is on how the growth process The results derived in Section III show that, depends on urban agglomeration, and vice over a specific time period, a city typically versa, an issue that is intentionally left aside experiences employment gains in some sectors here. On the other hand, the spatial churning of and losses in others. Since gains and losses industries, the slow mobility of cities in the partially offset each other, net employment urban hierarchy, and their heterogeneity in pop- changes in cities are smaller than gross employ- ulation size are usually neglected in this ment flows, and cities move slowly up and literature.2 down the size distribution. Furthermore, these A second important strand of literature, changes occur within an approximately stable which dates back to Herbert Simon (1955), has right-skewed distribution of city sizes. Hence sought to generate distributions of city sizes that the model can replicate the three stylized facts would obey Zipf’s law. This literature, recently above. revived by the work of Xavier Gabaix (1999), is The quantitative predictions of the model are successful at generating realistic and stable dis- explored in Section IV using simulations. The tributions of city sizes with some mobility model is calibrated to replicate French and US within them. It has two main limitations. First, it city-size distributions. The simulations approx- ignores the churning of industries across cities, imate the US distribution well. The model does the main focus of this paper. Second, and more better than Zipf’s law according to a natural subtly, urban evolutions in this literature are efficiency criterion.1 For France, the perfor- driven by ad hoc exogenous shocks: amenity mance is also good. Interestingly, the model can shocks in Gabaix (1999), preference shocks in replicate the nonregular features of the French Juan-Carlos Co´rdoba (2003), and productivity and US Zipf’s curves like their concavity, al- shocks in Jan Eeckhout (2004) and Esteban though it exaggerates them. Rossi-Hansberg and Mark L. J. Wright (forth- These systematic deviations can be reduced coming). By contrast, the model presented here or eliminated altogether by considering a natu- offers detailed microeconomic foundations for ral extension of the model. In Section V, the technology shocks.3 Such microeconomic foun- returns to innovative activities in cities are af- dations are important because these shocks are fected by their size: positively, through (reduced- form) dynamic agglomeration economies, and 2 A possible exception is Duranton and Diego Puga negatively, through crowding. When agglomer- (2001), who examine the movements of firms from diver- ation economies dominate crowding, the prob- sified to specialized cities in steady state. Their focus is ability of innovating in a city increases more nonetheless different, since churning occurs across cities than proportionately to its size. This reduces the that keep the same population and sectoral structure. 3 Zipf’s coefficient in the upper tail and increases In a companion paper (Duranton 2006), a Zipf’s law model with detailed microeconomic foundations is pro- it in the lower tail. Under empirically plausible posed. This companion paper builds on the product prolif- values for the trade-off between agglomeration eration model of endogenous growth (Paul M. Romer 1990) instead of its quality ladder version. This companion model is unable to deal with the churning of industries—a crucial focus of the present paper—since existing industries never 1 Zipf’s law refers to the well-known empirical claim move.
Recommended publications
  • The Concept of Cittaslow As a Marketing Tool for Destination Development: the Case of Mugla, Turkey
    American International Journal of Social Science Vol. 4, No. 3; June 2015 The Concept of Cittaslow as a Marketing Tool for Destination Development: The Case of Mugla, Turkey Aydan Bekar Nisan Yozukmaz Çağrı Sürücü Ahmet Metehan Gövce Faculty of Tourism Mugla SitkiKocman University Mugla, Turkey Abstract Akyaka town situated in the southern coast of Aegean Sea in Turkey has gained a different status from other touristic destinations due to its participation in the Cittaslow network in 2011. The process of Akyaka’s participation in this network; the effects of this participation on tourism and its usage as a marketing tool in destination development are the issues dealt in this study. The sample is Akyaka town in Mugla province of Turkey. Interview and observation techniques which are qualitative data collection methods are applied. As a result, it is determined that Cittaslow title has not been used for destination marketing on purpose; but rather it is considered as a factor of sustainability and as a factor increasing life quality and standards of locals. It is found that the priority of local administration is to protect natural environment and the sustainability of natural resources instead of increasing the tourist number. Keywords: Cittaslow; destination development; destination marketing; local administration; Akyaka 1. Introduction One of the most important tools that destination managements use for obtaining competitive advantage by differentiating themselves from others and for attracting more visitors and investors is destination branding (Govers& Go, 2009:5). Having a strong destination brand gives the destination an advantage in the struggle of product differentiation, substitutability and competitiveness regardless of the size or population of the destination (Morgan, Pritchard & Pride, 2011:5).
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Development and Poverty Alleviation
    14 OCTOBER 2019 Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2019 UNDERSTANDING DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel THE ROYAL SWEDISH ACADEMY OF SCIENCES, founded in 1739, is an independent organisation whose overall objective is to promote the sciences and strengthen their influence in society. The Academy takes special responsibility for the natural sciences and mathematics, but endeavours to promote the exchange of ideas between various disciplines. BOX 50005 (LILLA FRESCATIVÄGEN 4 A), SE-104 05 STOCKHOLM, SWEDEN TEL +46 8 673 95 00, [email protected] WWW.KVA.SE Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2019 Understanding Development and Poverty Alleviation The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel October 14, 2019 Despite massive progress in the past few decades, global poverty — in all its different dimensions — remains a broad and entrenched problem. For example, today, more than 700 million people subsist on extremely low incomes. Every year, five million children under five die of diseases that often could have been prevented or treated by a handful of proven interventions. Today, a large majority of children in low- and middle-income countries attend primary school, but many of them leave school lacking proficiency in reading, writing and mathematics. How to effectively reduce global poverty remains one of humankind’s most pressing questions. It is also one of the biggest questions facing the discipline of economics since its very inception.
    [Show full text]
  • Philippe Aghion
    CURRICULUM VITAE (last updated March 2018) Name: Philippe Aghion Address: College de France 3 rue d Ulm 75005 Paris France Email: [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Date of Birth: August 17, 1956 Place of Birth: Paris, France Education: 1976-80 Ecole Normale Supérieure de Cachan, Mathematics Section 1981 Diplome d’Etudes Approfondies d’Economie Mathématique, Université de Paris I 1983 Doctorat de 3éme cycle d’Economie Mathématique, Université de Paris I- Pantheon-Sorbonne 1987 Ph.D. Harvard University (Economics) Professional Experience: 1986-87 Sloan Foundation Dissertation Fellowship 1987-89 Assistant Professor, Massachusetts Institute of Technology 1989- Chargé de Recherches au Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique 1990-1992 Deputy Chief Economist, EBRD (London) 1992-96 Official Fellow, Nuffield College (Oxford) 1992-2000 Research Co-ordinator, EBRD (London) 1996-2002 Professor of Economics, University College London (UCL) 2000-2002 Professor of Economics, Harvard University 2002- 2015 Robert C. Waggoner Professor of Economics, Harvard University 2015- Professor at College de France, Chair entitled “Institutions, Innovation, et Croissance” 2009-2015 Invited Professor, Institute of International Economic Studies, Stockholm 2015- Centennial Professor of Economics, London School of Economics 2018-2020 Visiting Professor, Department of Economics, Harvard University Other Professional Positions or Appointments: 1991-97 Associate Editor, Review of Economic Studies 1992- Managing Editor,
    [Show full text]
  • Escaping the Climate Trap? Values, Technologies, and Politics∗
    Escaping the Climate Trap? Values, Technologies, and Politics Tim Besleyyand Torsten Perssonz November 2020 Abstract It is widely acknowledged that reducing the emissions of green- house gases is almost impossible without radical changes in consump- tion and production patterns. This paper examines the interdependent roles of changing environmental values, changing technologies, and the politics of environmental policy, in creating sustainable societal change. Complementarities that emerge naturally in our framework may generate a “climate trap,”where society does not transit towards lifestyles and technologies that are more friendly to the environment. We discuss a variety of forces that make the climate trap more or less avoidable, including lobbying by firms, private politics, motivated scientists, and (endogenous) subsidies to green innovation. We are grateful for perceptive comments by Philippe Aghion, David Baron, Xavier Jaravel, Bård Harstad, Elhanan Helpman, Gilat Levy, Linus Mattauch, and Jean Tirole, as well as participants in a Tsinghua University seminar, and LSE and Hong Kong University webinars. We also thank Azhar Hussain for research assistance. Financial support from the ERC and the Swedish Research Council is gratefully acknowledged. yLSE, [email protected]. zIIES, Stockholm University, [email protected] 1 1 Introduction What will it take to bring about the fourth industrial revolution that may be needed to save the planet? Such a revolution would require major structural changes in production as well as consumption patterns. Firms would have to invest on a large scale in technologies that generate lower greenhouse gas emissions, and households would have to consume goods that produce lower emissions. Already these observations suggest that the required transformation can be reinforced by a key complementarity, akin to the one associated with so- called platform technologies (Rochet and Tirole 2003).
    [Show full text]
  • A Netnographic Study on the Slow Fashion Online Community
    Content with less: A netnographic study on the Slow Fashion online community Bárbara Cardoso 152118121 Dissertation written under the supervision of Pedro Oliveira Dissertation submitted in partial fulfilment of requirements for the MSc in Management with specialization in Strategic Marketing, at the Universidade Católica Portuguesa, January 2020. 1 Title: Content with less: A netnographic study on the Slow Fashion online community Author: Bárbara Cardoso Abstract The slow fashion movement is gaining prominence as consumers have become alerted to the fashion industry’s practices. In a fast-fashion dominated industry, slow fashion proposes a holistic outlook on fashion, considering garment’s movement throughout the supply chain. It advocates an ethically conscious and environmentally aware fashion, ensuring transparent production systems. The present dissertation aims to study the slow fashion online community resorting to netnography. Deviating from previous academic research focused on slow fashion definition, the present research uncovers slow fashion’s meaning to its advocates and common practices. Results demonstrate how slow fashion’s adoption is consensually perceived as a journey and identified its drivers and barriers. The slow movement weights circular fashion and anti-consumerism principles aiming for self-contentment with less. It contributes to current academic discussion on fashion brand’s trust, unveiling skeptical and defrauded consumers that resort to alternative means to evaluate corporations’ credibility. Mistrust in brands is aggravated by the inexistence of an organization nor government body which regulates fashion industry guidelines. Transparency was appointed to lessen the perceived deception greenwashing exerts on brand attitude and perceived company performance. Implications suggest a strategy focused on transparent communication and consumer education, namely on how to increase garments durability.
    [Show full text]
  • Endogenous Preferences: the Political Consequences of Economic Institutions
    Endogenous Preferences: The Political Consequences of Economic Institutions Jan-Emmanuel De Neve∗y November 5, 2009 Abstract This paper attempts to explain cross-national voting behavior in 18 West- ern democracies over 1960-2003. A new data set for the median voter is intro- duced that corrects for stochastic error in the statistics from the Comparative Manifesto Project. Next, the paper finds that electoral behavior is closely re- lated to the salience of particular economic institutions. Labour organization, skill specificity, and public sector employment are found to influence individual voting behavior. At the country level, this paper suggests that coordinated market economies move the median voter to the left, whereas liberal market economies move the median voter to the right. The empirical analysis employs cross-sectional and panel data that are instrumented with the level of eco- nomic structure circa 1900 to estimate the net effect of economic institutions on the median voter. Significant results show that revealed voter preferences are endogenous to the economic institutions of the political economy. This paper places political economy at the heart of voting behavior and implies the existence of institutional advantages to partisan politics. Keywords: Comparative Political Economy, Median Voter, Voting Behav- ior, Panel Data, Instrumental Variables JEL Classification Numbers: C23, D72, H5, J24, J51, O57, P51 . ∗London School of Economics and Political Science, Department of Government, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, United Kingdom (email: [email protected]). yFor their time and generous data sharing, the author would like to thank Simon Hix, Jonathan Hopkin, Peter Hall, Torben Iversen, Lane Kenworthy, Duane Swank, Daniel Gingerich, Pepper Culpepper, Piero Stanig, Slava Mikhaylov, Johannes Spinnewijn, and Richard Fording.
    [Show full text]
  • Employee Representation and Corporate Governance: a Missing Link
    EMPLOYEE REPRESENTATION AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: A MISSING LINK Sanford M. Jacobyt The publication of Freeman and Rogers' What Workers Want' is a major contribution to the debate over employee representation in America. The authors have answered the basic question of what workers and manag- ers want. Now we must reconsider how public policy can be designed to help these preferences be realized. Although Freeman and Rogers have on other occasions contributed ideas for closing the representation gap,2 the present study maintains a curious silence on solutions. Most of the recent policy proposals on employee representation at- tempt to tweak the National Labor Relations Act to permit greater experi- mentation with nonunion employee participation plans. For example, the so-called Dunlop Commission of the mid-1990s outlined the following four principal policy options, all of which focused on labor law: (1) to retain the law in its present form; (2) to revise section 8(a)(2) to permit employers to create employee involvement plans and even company unions, so long as they do not bargain collectively with the employer (the approach contained in the so-called TEAM Act); (3) to modify the TEAM approach to permit employers to establish employee involvement plans but require that they meet certain standards for employee selection, access to information, and protection against reprisals; and (4) to legally require the establishment of employee participation committees,3 as in the plan put forth in 1990 by Professor Paul Weiler to require every company above a certain size to es- tablish elected committees to address the firm's human resource policies t Professor of Management, Policy Studies and History, UCLA; A.B.
    [Show full text]
  • October 2004
    ROBIN BURGESS CONTACT INFORMATION LSE Department of Economics Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK Tel: (020) 7955 6676, Fax: (020) 7955 6951 [email protected] http://econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/rburgess/index_own.html PERSONAL Marital Status: Married to Bronwen Burgess Children: Isla Macbeth Burgess (d.o.b. August 03, 2005) Citizenship: UK PROFESSIONAL EXPERIENCE POSITIONS 2007 – present Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, LSE 2004 – 2007 Reader in Economics, Department of Economics, LSE 1999 – present Co-Director, Economic Organization and Public Policy Programme, STICERD, LSE 2005 Visiting Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, Fall Semester 2003 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Harvard University and National Bureau for Economic Research, Fall Semester 2002 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University College London, Fall Semester 2001 Visiting Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, MIT, Fall Semester 2000 – 2004 Lecturer in Economics, Department of Economics, LSE 1998 – 1999 Lecturer in Development Economics, Development Studies Institute and Department of Economics, LSE 1991 – 1995 Consultant Economist, Chief Economists Office, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development 1989 – 1991 Consultant Economist, World Development Report and Research Department, World Bank AFFILIATIONS 2006 – present Program Director, CEPR Development Economics Program (with Esther Duflo) 2005 – present Senior Fellow, Bureau for Research in the Economic
    [Show full text]
  • Slow Adventure: from Natural Concept to Consumer Desire
    ETOUR Rapport 2020:2 Slow adventure: from natural concept to consumer desire Peter J. Varley, Edward H. Huijbens, Steve Taylor, Daniel Laven Slow adventure: from natural concept to consumer desire © Authors, 2020-04-21 Photo: Rupert Shanks – Wilderness Scotland Printed by Mid Sweden University, Sundsvall ISBN: 978-91-88947-58-1 Faculty of Human Sciences Mid Sweden University, Kunskapens väg 8 Phone: +46 (0)10 142 80 00 Report series ETOUR Report 2020:2 Table of contents Abstract ................................................................................................................................... vii Biographical notes .................................................................................................................. ix Preface ..................................................................................................................................... xi 1 Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 1 2 Adventure tourism ................................................................................................................ 3 2.1 Slow adventure: selling ‘nothing’? ........................................................................................ 3 2.2 Contrasting ‘fast’ adventure .................................................................................................. 4 3 Methods .................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARTIFICIAL INTELLIGENCE AND ECONOMIC GROWTH Philippe Aghion Benjamin F. Jones Charles I. Jones Working Paper 23928 http://www.nber.org/papers/w23928 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2017 We are grateful to Ajay Agrawal, Mohammad Ahmadpoor, Adrien Auclert, Sebastian Di Tella, Patrick Francois, Joshua Gans, Avi Goldfarb, Pete Klenow, Hannes Mahlmberg, Pascual Restrepo, Chris Tonetti, Michael Webb, and participants at the NBER Conference on Artificial Intelligence for helpful discussion and comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2017 by Philippe Aghion, Benjamin F. Jones, and Charles I. Jones. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth Philippe Aghion, Benjamin F. Jones, and Charles I. Jones NBER Working Paper No. 23928 October 2017 JEL No. O3,O4 ABSTRACT This paper examines the potential impact of artificial intelligence (A.I.) on economic growth. We model A.I. as the latest form of automation, a broader process dating back more than 200 years. Electricity, internal combustion engines, and semiconductors facilitated automation in the last century, but A.I. now seems poised to automate many tasks once thought to be out of reach, from driving cars to making medical recommendations and beyond.
    [Show full text]
  • The Flotilla Effect Europe’S Small Economies Through the Eye of the Storm
    The Flotilla Effect Europe’s small economies through the eye of the storm A Report for Jill Evans MEP by Adam Price with Ben Levinger The Flotilla Effect Europe’s small economies through the eye of the storm Adam Price with Ben Levinger Page 2 Today, Europe consists solely of small countries. The only relevant distinction that remains is that some countries understand this, while others still refuse to acknowledge it. Paul-Henri Spaak Page 3 Acknowledgements The authors would like to acknowledge the following for their help and support: Professor Michael Landesmann, Dr Eurfyl ap Gwilym and Dr. Rhys ap Gwilym for their comments and suggestions and David Linden, Iain Wallace and Daniel Wylie for their extremely valuable research input. Lastly we would like to put on record our heartfelt thanks to Jill Evans MEP (Plaid Cymru) and Alyn Smith MEP (Scottish National Party) for their financial support without which this research project would not have been possible. The views expressed and any inadequacies, inaccuracies or omissions are exclusively our own. Page 4 Biographies Adam Price was the Plaid Cymru Member of Parliament for Carmarthen East and Dinefwr between 2001 and 2010. He has published widely on politics, history and economic development, and is the former Managing Director of an economics consultancy. He is currently a Research Fellow at the Center for International Development at Harvard‟s John F. Kennedy School of Government. He can be contacted via email on [email protected]. Benjamin Levinger is currently conducting research at the Brookings Institution and studying for a Master in Public Policy at the Kennedy School.
    [Show full text]
  • The Origin of Slow Media: Early Diffusion of a Cultural Innovation Through Popular and Press Discourse, 2002-2010 by Jennifer Rauch
    TRANSFORMATIONS Journal of Media & Culture http://www.transformationsjournal.org/issues/20/article_0... ISSN 1444-3775 2011 Issue No. 20 — Slow Media The Origin of Slow Media: Early Diffusion of a Cultural Innovation through Popular and Press Discourse, 2002-2010 By Jennifer Rauch Since the turn of the 21st century, people from diverse walks of life have begun to form a sub-cultural movement whose members reduce their overall time spent with media and/or their use of specific communication technologies in order to constrain the influence of digital devices and networks on their personal, professional, and family lives. For example, some people have adopted the Sabbath Manifesto ritual of unplugging as a modern way of observing a weekly day of rest, some participate in Adbusters’ long-running Digital Detox Week campaign to disrupt corporate-commercial culture, and some reduce their use of fast, digital media in favor of slow, analog activities. The perspective of such groups and individuals who espouse these innovative cultural practices are typically not “Luddite” or “against technology”; rather, they recognize the various benefits and limitations of new forms of media and want to use it in a more deliberate way. Recent attention to the concept of “Slow Media,” in particular, suggests that we are observing a moment of transformation in the way that many people around the world think about and engage with mediated communication. With the term “slow” now established as familiar shorthand for leading a more balanced life (see Honoré, In Praise of Slowness), Slow Media can be understood as both a philosophy and a practice: First, it represents an appreciation or re-appraisal of “heirloom” forms of media, such as print or analog, and questions popular desire for ever-more information and ever-faster communication.
    [Show full text]