Capital in Disequilibrium

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Capital in Disequilibrium Capital in Disequilibrium Capital in Disequilibrium The Role of Capital in a Changing World Second Edition P L Ludwig von Mie Intitute AUBURN,ALABAMA Copyright © 2011 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute Published under the Creative Commons Aribution License 3.0. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/ Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 Ph: (334) 844-2500 Fax: (334) 844-2583 mises.org 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 ISBN: 978-1-61016-239-5 Contents Acknowledgments . vii Preface to the Second Edition . xi 1. Introduction and Outline. 1 Part I. Baground: Equilibrium and Change 2. What Does Equilibrium Mean? A Discussion in the Context of Modern Austrian Ideas . 15 3. Equilibrium and Expectations Re-Examined: A Different Perspective . 31 Part II. Capital, Interest, and Profits 4. Capital in Historical Perspective . 51 5. Modern Capital eory . 79 6. e Hicksian Marriage of Capital and Time . 93 7. e Nature of Interest and Profits . 109 Part III. Capital in a Dynamic World 8. Modern Mengerian Capital eory . 125 9. Capital and Business Organizations . 147 10. Organizations, Money, and Calculation . 177 11. Human Capital . 193 12. Human Capital, the Nature of Knowledge, and the Value of Knowledge . 225 Conclusion . 237 Bibliography . 243 Index . 259 v Acknowledgments I owe a large intellectual debt to two remarkable and very different teachers. e spark of interest, of which this book is the culmination, was ignited when, as an undergraduate (in 1968), I took a course in capital theory from my teacher Ludwig Lachmann, at the University of the Witwatersrand in Johannesburg, South Africa. Lachmann’s ideas have influenced the writing of almost every page of this work. From him I learned at a young and impressionable age to think critically about the implications of time for human action. From him I inherited an enduring fascination with the questions posed by capital theory, a fas- cination enhanced by the very complexity of the subject. I suspect that it would not have troubled him in the least that his student presumed to differ from him in some ways and to extend his approach into novel areas; on the contrary, I imagine he would have been quite pleased. In particular, Lachmann’s influence as an economist was limited by the absence of concrete or practical implications of his work. Yet, as I have tried to show, his general insights have specific applications in the areas of the theory of the firm, in human capital, and many other areas. Professor Lachmann, in addition to providing a crucial component of my education, helped me in other ways at the beginning of my professional career. He was always considerate and respectful of his students and his memory inspires and sustains me. I am indebted in a less personal, but nevertheless important, way to Gary Becker. Professor Becker was my PhD thesis commiee chair- man and my teacher for a number of graduate courses. e opportu- nity to study with him was of inestimable value to me in my training as an economist and, more particularly, in gaining an appreciation of the importance of human capital (and related subject areas, like the economics of the family). His influence will be particularly apparent in the chapters that deal with human capital. vii viii CAPITAL IN DISEQUILIBRIUM is work, then, has been in the pipeline for many years, dur- ing which time I have benefited from talking to many individuals. I cannot hope to recall them all, at least not without engaging in an inappropriate exercise of intellectual autobiography. However, they include Karl Miermaier, Landis Gabel, Sam Weston, Bob Formaini, Roger Garrison, Richard Ebeling, Don Lavoie, and Karen Vaughn. I have benefited from comments on presentations at the Colloquium on Austrian economics at New York University, most notably from com- ments by Mario Rizzo, Israel Kirzner, Peter Boeke, Joe Salerno, Bill Butos, Roger Koppl, David Harper, Don Boudreaux, Frederic Sautet, and Sanford Ikeda. I also benefited from comments received at pre- sentations at the Southern Economic Association and the History of Economics Association meetings. Larry White provided very useful comments. I am very grateful to Steven Horwitz who read the entire manu- script of an early version and provided numerous stylistic and substan- tive corrections. is book would not have been wrien without the efforts and encouragement of Mario Rizzo. It was he who first suggested it and provided important directional indicators. In addition, his work in Austrian economics has been an important source of inspiration for me and has helped me to gain greater insight into and appreciation of many of the themes that appear in the pages that follow. In the years since the first edition of this book I have benefited from too many individuals to name. My coauthor Howard Baetjer cannot go unmentioned however. His work on capital and knowledge is crucial to my current understanding of the subject. For editorial assistance at the Mises Institute I thank Jeffrey Tucker and Paul Foley. I need hardly add that none of the individuals mentioned above is to be implicated in any of the errors that may be found in this work, especially where they are the result of my stubborn refusal to follow their advice. In addition to colleagues and teachers, I have been fortunate to have had the support of friends and family, without which I could not have found the time and resolve to complete this work. My parents, Merle and Herman Lewin, have been a constant source of support and have stood by me in my obstinate determination to follow the calling ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ix of academe. To my father-in-law Felix Shapiro, also my constant friend and admirer, I owe more than I can say. And finally and mostly, my family, my children Dan, Andy, Shiralee and Gabbi, each in their own way has helped me in this “strange” project (as they must see it); and my wife Beverley, my partner in life, who has struggled valiantly to identify with her husband’s determination to complete this weird time- and energy-consuming project. Preface to the Second Edition It has been twelve years since the original publication of this book in 1999. Much has happened in the intervening years to affect its relevance. In the world of economic policy, the relevance of (Austrian type) capital theory has increased dramatically. e appeal of what Ludwig Lachmann referred to as “neoclassical formalism” has not diminished. Policy-makers, following the counsel of their economic advisors, who are ruled by a belief in the significance of economic aggregates, have persistently ignored, indeed precipitated, capital structure distortions; the results of which have been two major domestic economic crises (the dot-com bust and the housing-bubble meltdown), a global credit crisis, a chronic fiscal deficit and an exploding debt burden that threat- ens to destroy the very fabric of the economy’s value-creating poten- tial. is book is designed for those who wish to understand, in a thorough and fundamental way, the nature and significance of capital. What makes an economy “capitalist”? How does value get created over time? If we get this wrong we may end up paying a high price indeed. e erroneous ideas upon which disastrous economic policy has been based have come down from the intellectual forebears of the current generation of economic advisors. A full appreciation of this entails understanding the nature of bales fought long ago over the nature and significance of capital and capital theory. Accordingly, the focus of this book on this particular aspect of the history of economic thought remains very relevant. In the world of economic theory, though the majority of the eco- nomics profession remains oblivious of, and contemptuous of, any- thing outside of its narrow quantitative orientation, and, indeed, has become even more finely specialized and technically esoteric, so that its members know more and more about less and less over time, on the growing fringes of the profession a number of “heterodox” approaches xi xii CAPITAL IN DISEQUILIBRIUM have prospered and are growing. One of these heterodox approaches is that of Austrian economics, which has continued to gain adherents, including from young, energetic graduates who are beginning to make their marks. I hope that the re-publication of this book in a more accessible form will serve to encourage this development and provide a firm foundation for the diverse applications of capital theory that are now becoming evident. One area in which such applications have been growing apace is that of management and business studies, particularly in the areas of strategic-management, organization studies and entrepreneurship. e Austrian ideas most relevant to this line of research concern the na- ture of resources and how they can be organized in productive combi- nations to produce value. e “capital-nature” of productive resources has pointed in the direction of the Austrians. ough long interested in Schumpeter, scholars in this area have recently enthusiastically em- braced the ideas of Hayek, Kirzner, and, most recently, Lachmann. In particular, understanding resources as capital has led to an apprecia- tion of the importance of time and knowledge in productive processes, and of social institutions—connected themes examined below, espe- cially in Chapter 9. is literature stream has grown rapidly since 1999. An indication of some of this work and its connection to the work below can be found in Lewin and Baetjer (2011). is book is about capital in a disequilibrium world, a dynamic world. In the years since its first publication the world in which we live has become even more dynamic. e pace of change has accelerated.
Recommended publications
  • Hayek's the Constitution of Liberty
    Hayek’s The Constitution of Liberty Hayek’s The Constitution of Liberty An Account of Its Argument EUGENE F. MILLER The Institute of Economic Affairs contenTs The author 11 First published in Great Britain in 2010 by Foreword by Steven D. Ealy 12 The Institute of Economic Affairs 2 Lord North Street Summary 17 Westminster Editorial note 22 London sw1p 3lb Author’s preface 23 in association with Profile Books Ltd The mission of the Institute of Economic Affairs is to improve public 1 Hayek’s Introduction 29 understanding of the fundamental institutions of a free society, by analysing Civilisation 31 and expounding the role of markets in solving economic and social problems. Political philosophy 32 Copyright © The Institute of Economic Affairs 2010 The ideal 34 The moral right of the author has been asserted. All rights reserved. Without limiting the rights under copyright reserved above, no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored or introduced into a PART I: THE VALUE OF FREEDOM 37 retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means (electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise), without the prior written permission of both the copyright owner and the publisher of this book. 2 Individual freedom, coercion and progress A CIP catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. (Chapters 1–5 and 9) 39 isbn 978 0 255 36637 3 Individual freedom and responsibility 39 The individual and society 42 Many IEA publications are translated into languages other than English or are reprinted. Permission to translate or to reprint should be sought from the Limiting state coercion 44 Director General at the address above.
    [Show full text]
  • Human Action Vs
    Kiel Institute for the World Economy | Kiel, 19 July 2016 Paradigm Debate: “Human Action vs. Phishing for Phools – Two Perspectives of Socio-Economics” Human Action Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics Stefan Kooths Forecasting Center KOOTHS | Human Action – Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics 1 Crisis of mainstream economic thinking Reconstruction or revolution of economics? KOOTHS | Human Action – Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics 2 Reconstruction of economics Coordinationist paradigm of economics inspired by „Austrian Economics“ (Entrepreneurial Economics) methodological backbone Praxeology: Science of Human Action Catallactics: Science of human inter-action via (market) exchange KOOTHS | Human Action – Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics 3 Fundamental axiom Man acts. KOOTHS | Human Action – Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics 4 Implications of “human action” (1/2) . Purposeful conduct: Aiming at reducing uneasiness » The human actor “wants to substitute a state of affairs that suits him better for one that suits him less”. (Mises) » Human beings as universal entrepreneurs (explorers, not decision automata) » Action: decision making + search for means . Individuals act … » … but not in isolation (society formed by voluntary interaction) » … groups/aggregates do not (anti-collectivist approach) . Preferences as ranks only » Chosen ends are strictly subjective » Making choices on means (no discussion of ends) » No room for interpersonal comparison of utility (no social planner) KOOTHS | Human Action – Towards a Coordinationist Paradigm of Economics 5 Implications of “human action” (2/2) . Diminishing marginal utility » Follows from praxeological approach (outcome, not an assumption) » Not a psychological/physiological phenomenon . Action in time » Dynamic disequilibrium approach » Evenly rotating economy as a state of non-action (thought experiment only) .
    [Show full text]
  • CATALLACTICS: Hayek's 'Evolutionary' Theory of Economics, Applied to Public Policy and Education Through Competition and Market Forces
    DEV99089 CATALLACTICS: Hayek's 'evolutionary' theory of Economics, applied to public policy and education through competition and market forces. ® Nesta Devine, University of Waikato In this paper I am going, loosely, to use the method described by Michel Foucault as 'genealogy' to shed some light on the assumptions and practices of those who construct education in the form of a series of exchanges between interested parties. By examining the ancestry of these ideas and practices I aim to shed some doubt on their claims to pre- emptive rationality. In part this relies on a challenge to the 'displacement' as Derrida calls it, of ideas from one discipline to another through the medium of metaphor. I am not trying to establish a series of causal links, and I do not discuss here the method of dissemination of these ideas. For listeners/readers interested in the process by which this set of ideas have become common currency, I recommend Thinking the unthinkable by Richard Cockett, (1994) and for New Zealand readers, particularly, First Knights by Paul Harris and Linda Twiname (1998). In this paper I shall use the writings of the 'Austrian School' economist F.A. Hayek, who has been an important source of ideas for economists and public officials seeking to use the principles of economics to reform the nature of government. More recent followers of Hayek in the belief that economics offers guidelines for practice in other fields have called themselves 'Public Choice Theorists'. The principle architects of 'Public Choice Theory' are James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock. Many economists who do not identify themselves in such a way have also adopted the view that the principles of economics can be generally applied to all fields of human interaction, among them Milton Friedman, and the very significant New Zealand public policy bodies, the Treasury and the State Services Commission, who have been the principal agents in the reform of education in New Zealand along economistic lines.
    [Show full text]
  • Can We Design Spontaneity? the Tension Between Evolution and Design and the Defense of Liberalism in Hayek
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Colin-Jaege, Nathanaël Working Paper Can we design spontaneity? The tension between evolution and design and the defense of liberalism in Hayek CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2021-05 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Colin-Jaege, Nathanaël (2021) : Can we design spontaneity? The tension between evolution and design and the defense of liberalism in Hayek, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2021-05, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3841087 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/234316 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Drei Methodenstreite and Intramural Strife
    DREI METHODENSTREITE AND INTRAMURAL STRIFE A University Thesis Presented to the Faculty of California State University, Hayward In Partial Fulfillment ofthe Requirements for the Degree Master ofArts in Economics By Christopher R. Inama February, 1996 Copyright © 1996 by Christopher R. Inama ii DREI METHODENSTREITE AND INTRAMURAL STRIFE By Christopher R. Inama Approved: Dated: iii TABLE OF CONTENTS l. INTRODUCTION II. 7lfF METHODENSTREIT 2 A. ORIGINS OF THE GERMAN HISTORICAL SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS 2 1. Some Forerunners ofthe German Historical School ofEconomics .,. 5 2. An Initial Criticism ofHistoricism , 10 B. THE GERMAN HISTORICAL SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS , 12 C. MENGER'S CHALLENGE 20 D. THE OUTCOME 27 III. FIFTY YEARS LATER 30 A. HAYEK'S THEORY 33 B. KEYNES'S THEORY 40 C. THE DISPUTE 43 D. THE OUTCOME 45 IV. AN ONGOING DEBATE 51 A. POSITIVISTS, COLLECTIVISTS, AND OTHERS OF THEIR ILK 52 B. AUSTRIAN RESPONSES TO THAT ILK 68 I. ADDITIONAL PHILOSOPHICAL INFLUENCES ON AUSTRIAN THOUGHT 68 2. SOME VARIATIONS WITHIN THE AUSTRIAN SCHOOL 80 C. SOME METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES 82 I. Internal Contradictions ofLogical Positivism 82 2. Is Empirical Knowledge Inconsistent with the Austrian Theory? 84 D. HAYEK'S CRITICISMS OF DIFFERENT FORMS OF POSITIVISM 85 IV. AN INTRAMURAL FRAY 90 A. SOME DIFFERENCES BETWEEN MISES AND HAYEK 90 B. A MISESIAN BRANCH OF THE FAMILY TREE 95 C. ANOTHER STUDENT OF MISES CLAIMS THE MIDDLE-GROUND 106 D. RADICAL SUBJECTIVISTS DESCENDED THROUGH HAYEK .... 108 V. CONCLUSION 111 BIBLIOGRAPHY ..................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: a Framework for the Intimate and Extended Orders
    STUDIES IN EMERGENT ORDER VOL 7 (2014): 239-257 Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: A Framework for the Intimate and Extended Orders Daniel J. Smith1 Abstract: Even notable free market scholars in the 20th Century lamented the inescapable decline in intimate social relations that would emerge from the wide-scale adoption of an extended market order. This paper challenges this view that markets erode social relations by challenging the concept that the usage of money or barter are the logical distinction between the intimate and extended order, and then by offering the framework of exit, voice, and loyalty as an improved distinction between the intimate and extended order. With this new framework, it is possible to see that the extended market order can not only preserve the intimate order, by reducing material strain on the intimate order, but also extend the intimate order, by creating the shared social space for the formation of harmonious relations between diverse people. Rather than undermining intimate social relations, market exchange preserves and extends the intimate order. EXIT, VOICE, AND LOYALTY 240 Introduction While Adam Smith recognized the natural proclivity of humankind to “…truck, barter, and exchange…,” there has been a philosophical tendency to attempt to separate and isolate these natural commercial exchange proclivities from other human relations (1776[1976]: 25). Exchange relations, while being recognized as mutually beneficial–and perhaps even civilizing (Hirschman 1997)–have been winnowed out as an entirely separate realm of human behavior. Separating out commercial exchange relations from the rich cultural, biological, and social aspects of humankind, has allowed social scientists to render diagnoses of reform, ostracism, or even removal of this commonly regarded ‘untouchable’ aspect of human behavior.
    [Show full text]
  • A Critique on the Social Justice Perspectives in the Works of Friedrich A. Hayek
    RESEARCH ASSOCIATION for RAIS INTERDISCIPLINARY DOI: 10.5281/zenodo.1215124 MARCH 2018 STUDIES A Critique on the Social Justice Perspectives in the Works of Friedrich A. Hayek Anusha Mahendran Curtin University [email protected] ABSTRACT: Given that the academic work of Friedrich Hayek has received eminent accolades (including the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics Sciences) and has been well recognised and widely referenced, this paper reviews the denial of the concept of social justice in many of the academic economic theory papers written by the renowned British-Austrian economist. The paper therefore effectively provides a critical analysis of some of Hayek’s socio-political and economic theories relating to this issue. It attempts to do this by adopting the perspective of an objective and analytical economist with reference to and by examining the content of three of Hayek’s well known economic texts, namely The Road to Serfdom (1944); Law, Legislation and Liberty (1973-79) and the Fatal Conceit Conceit: The Errors of Socialism (1988). KEYWORDS: social justice, economics, Friedrich Hayek 1. Introduction Friedrich August von Hayek (who was also commonly referred to as F.A. Hayek) was an Austrian-British economist and was well known for his staunch defence of classical liberalism (Birner and van Rip 1994). Hayek was born in Vienna, Austria in 1899 and the majority of his perspectives were derived from theories and philosophies from the Austrian School of Economics (Birner and van Rip 1994). 82 MAHENDRAN: A Critique on the Social Justice Perspectives The primary basis of the Austrian School of Economic Thought is centred around the concept of methodological individualism which entails the ideology that the motivations and actions of individuals drive social phenomenon (Boettke and Leeson 2003).
    [Show full text]
  • F. A. Hayek on the Role of Reason in Human Affairs Linda Catherine Raeder
    University of Richmond UR Scholarship Repository Master's Theses Student Research 8-1993 F. A. Hayek on the role of reason in human affairs Linda Catherine Raeder Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.richmond.edu/masters-theses Part of the Political Science Commons Recommended Citation Raeder, Linda Catherine, "F. A. Hayek on the role of reason in human affairs" (1993). Master's Theses. Paper 831. This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Research at UR Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Master's Theses by an authorized administrator of UR Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. F. A. HAYEK ON THE ROLE OF REASON IN HUMAN AFFAIRS by Linda Catherine Raeder Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of the University of Richmond in Candidacy for the Degree of M.A. in Political Science August 1993 Thesis Director: Dr. Ellis M. West This-study examines the views of F. A. Hayek on the role of reason in human affairs. The author explicates certain elements of Hayekian theory that bear on this issue-his views on the nature of mind, rules, law, and cultural evolution-and discusses the characteristics of both the constructivist and critical "kinds of rationalism" Hayek identifies. She then examines the views of various critics who have challenged Hayek's argument. She concludes that, contrary to certain critics, 1) the distinction he draws between constructivist and critical rationalism is meaningful and that the two kinds of rationalism appear to be related to certain political views; 2) whether Hayek, despite his criticism of the constructivistic conceit, should himself be considered a constructivist depends on whether one adopts a broad or narrow interpretation of constructivism; and 3) Hayek's method of social criticism-what he terms "immanent criticism"-does provide the basis for a meaningful critical theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Religion and the Social Order John Robert Subrick Lessons from Smith, Associate Professor of Economics Hayek, and Smith James Madison University
    Journal of Markets & Morality Volume 18, Number 2 (Fall 2015): 309–329 Copyright © 2015 Religion and the Social Order John Robert Subrick Lessons from Smith, Associate Professor of Economics Hayek, and Smith James Madison University Adam Smith, F. A. Hayek, and Vernon Smith have made bold claims about the role of religion in the emergence and maintenance of the social order. Without religion, they argue, civilization would not have emerged. Unfortunately, they did not fully develop the argument to support their hypothesis. This article combines their insights to articulate their implicit argument. Adam Smith argued that religion provided simple constraints that limited opportunism in competitive markets. Hayek claimed that the major religions of the world provided the basis for the transition from the microcosmos to the macrocosmos. Vernon Smith recognized that the generality of religious rules provide ample scope for innovation and invention that furthered the division of labor. Combining their insights leads to a new understanding of how religion formed the foundations for the modern world. Introduction The role of religion in the creation and maintenance of the social order has re- ceived little systematic attention in economic thought. The major treatises in the development of economic thought, those of David Ricardo, John Stuart Mill, Carl Menger, Leon Walras, William Stanley Jevons, and Alfred Marshall contain no systematic discussion of religion if they mention religion at all.1 Joseph Spengler selectively surveyed economic ideas and their relation to the social order back to Aristotle, and he did not discuss the role of religious ideas and institutions.2 Instead, he framed the discussion as a debate over the proper role of the state relative to the market.
    [Show full text]
  • Hayek's 'Extended Order'
    The Irrationality of the Extended Order: The Fatal Conceit of F. A. Hayek Larry J. Sechrest* Sul Ross State University Friedrich A. Hayek (1899-1992) is considered by many to have been one of the true intellectual giants of the twentieth century. He was without doubt one of the most influential thinkers of his time. Moreover, Hayek is almost universally characterized as a dedicated-even radical-proponent of capitalism. The questionable validity of such a characterization is one of the key issues to be dealt with in this essay. Part of Hayek's fame stems from the fact that, in 1974, he shared the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Science with the socialist Gunnar Myrdal. The prize was awarded "for their pioneering work in the theory of money and economic fluctuations and for their penetrating analysis of the interdependence of economic, social, and institutional phenomena" (Machlup 1976, xv-mi). 1 There seem to have been, in other words, two different reasons why Hayek was deemed worthy of the award. The primary reason was his brilliant technical work during the 1930s on money and credit conditions and their impact on business cycles. The secondary reason was his provocative analysis of the comparative efficiency of socioeconomic systems undertaken during the 1940s and 1950s. During the last fifty years of Hayek's life, however, most of his work was devoted to political and social philosophy, legal theory, and the philosophy of science rather than to economic theory. Both the breadth of his knowledge and the scope of his work were .enormous.2 He discussed everything from anthropology to the evolution of language to the role of religion in Western civilization.
    [Show full text]
  • The Fatal Conceit of Foreign Intervention
    The Fatal Conceit of Foreign Intervention Christopher J. Coyne and Rachel L. Mathers ∗ Abstract The fatal conceit is the assumption that the world can be shaped according to human desires. This paper argues that the logic of the fatal conceit can be applied to foreign interventions which go beyond the limits of what can be rationally constructed by reason alone. In suffering from the fatal conceit, these interventions are characterized by: (1) the realization that intentions do not equal results, (2) a reliance on top-down planning, (3) the view of development as a technological issue, (4) a reliance on bureaucracy over markets, and (5) the primacy of collectivism over individualism. These characteristics explain why interventions extending beyond the limits of what can be rationally constructed tend to fail. JEL Codes: B53, O1, P00 Keywords: fatal conceit, foreign aid, foreign intervention, rational constructivism ∗ West Virginia University, Department of Economics, P.O. Box 6025, Morgantown, WV 26506-6025. Christopher J. Coyne ( [email protected] ) and Rachel L. Mathers ( [email protected] ). Coyne was the F.A. Hayek Fellow at the London School of Economic and Political Science during the initial writing of this paper and gratefully acknowledges the support of the STICERD Centre at the LSE. The Fatal Conceit of Foreign Intervention “The curious task of economics is to demonstrate to men how little they really know about what they imagine they can design.” --F.A. Hayek (1988: 76) 1. Introduction In his last book, F.A. Hayek (1988) analyzed the “fatal conceit,” which is the presumption that “man is able to shape the world around him according to his wishes” (27).
    [Show full text]
  • Rules of Spontaneous Order
    Rules of Spontaneous Order Jason Potts RMIT University, School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT College of Business, Building 80, 445 Swanston Street, Melbourne 3000, Victoria, Australia Email: [email protected] Web: http://www.rmit.edu.au/browse/About%20RMIT%2F;ID=c5w026edczcm1 Bio-sketch: Jason Potts has written three books and dozens of articles on the theory of economic evolution. His work focuses on how entrepreneurship and innovation drive economic growth and development. His books include The New Evolutionary Microeconomics: Complexity, Competence and Adaptive Behaviour (2001, Elgar) a co-recipient of the Schumpeter Prize. He also co-wrote the The General Theory of Economic Evolution (2007, Routledge). His latest book is Evolutionary Economics and Creative Industries (2011, Elgar). Abstract: This paper is a reply to Gus diZerega’s essay on the nature, scope and ambition of spontaneous order studies. I am in broad agreement with diZerega’s claims and so I will seek neither rebuttal, nor restatement. Instead, I want to argue some dif- ferent points of emphasis in the spontaneous order research program. Specifically, I argue that emergent social order should be studied as an application and indeed exemplar of the evolutionary theory of rule-based co-operation. 30 Keywords: Spontaneous order; complexity; economic evolution; Hayek; rules COSMOS + TAXIS COSMOS 1: Introduction auditioning methods and tools for their study. Its research program is still advancing through the following templates This essay is a response to Gus diZerega’s engaging, thought- —‘X is (also) a spontaneous-order domain’; and ‘Y is (also) ful and wide-ranging survey of the subject domain of a spontaneous-order theorist’.
    [Show full text]