Quantitative Tools for Microeconomic Policy Analysis, Conference Proceedings, 17–18 November 2004, Canberra

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Quantitative Tools for Microeconomic Policy Analysis, Conference Proceedings, 17–18 November 2004, Canberra Quantitative Tools for Microeconomic Conference Proceedings Policy Analysis Canberra, 17–18 November 2004 © Commonwealth of Australia 2005 ISBN 1 74037 184 4 This work is subject to copyright. Apart from any use as permitted under the Copyright Act 1968, the work may be reproduced in whole or in part for study or training purposes, subject to the inclusion of an acknowledgment of the source. Reproduction for commercial use or sale requires prior written permission from the Attorney-General’s Department. Requests and inquiries concerning reproduction and rights should be addressed to the Commonwealth Copyright Administration, Attorney-General’s Department, Robert Garran Offices, National Circuit, Canberra ACT 2600. This publication is available in hard copy or PDF format from the Productivity Commission website at www.pc.gov.au. If you require part or all of this publication in a different format, please contact Media and Publications (see below). Publications Inquiries: Media and Publications Productivity Commission Locked Bag 2 Collins Street East Melbourne VIC 8003 Tel: (03) 9653 2244 Fax: (03) 9653 2303 Email: [email protected] General Inquiries: Tel: (03) 9653 2100 or (02) 6240 3200 An appropriate citation for this paper is: Productivity Commission 2005, Quantitative Tools for Microeconomic Policy Analysis, Conference Proceedings, 17–18 November 2004, Canberra. JEL code: C, D, H The Productivity Commission The Productivity Commission, an independent agency, is the Australian Government’s principal review and advisory body on microeconomic policy and regulation. It conducts public inquiries and research into a broad range of economic and social issues affecting the welfare of Australians. The Commission’s independence is underpinned by an Act of Parliament. Its processes and outputs are open to public scrutiny and are driven by concern for the wellbeing of the community as a whole. Information on the Productivity Commission, its publications and its current work program can be found on the World Wide Web at www.pc.gov.au or by contacting Media and Publications on (03) 9653 2244. Foreword This publication contains the papers from a Productivity Commission conference on Quantitative Tools for Microeconomic Policy Analysis, held in November 2004 in Canberra. Policy modelling has played an important role in the work of the Productivity Commission and its predecessors over the years1. Reform can be disruptive and costly to some. Gaining some assurance that the beneficial impacts will justify such costs is critical to developing and selling proposals for policy change. Quantitative models cannot replicate reality, but they can provide us with a better understanding of the ramifications of policy changes. Over time, increased access to and understanding of sophisticated quantitative modelling have improved the basis for policy decisions. The objective of the conference was to provide an opportunity for the dissemination of new, data-related, modelling approaches, relevant to contemporary policy discussion. The invited audience was not confined to modellers, but also included policy analysts and advisors from government, universities and the private sector. Presentations at the conference were therefore not overly technical. However, the authors were invited to include necessary technical material in the versions of their papers contained in this volume. The Commission would like to thank the authors, who responded well to the invitation to make what is a technical subject accessible to a wider audience. Thanks are also due to all those who attended the conference, whose questions and discussions kept the focus on policy relevance. Last, but not least, thanks to Margaret Mead for organising the conference so well and assisting with the production of this volume. Gary Banks Chairman 1 For a history of the Commission’s activities over the last three decades see From Industry Assistance to Productivity: 30 Years of ‘the Commission’, Productivity Commission 2003. FOREWORD III IV FOREWORD Contents Foreword III Section 1 Estimating policy effects — computable general equilibrium models 1 1 Asset markets and financial flows in general equilibrium models 3 Warwick J McKibbin and Alison Stegman 2 Combining engineering-based water models with a CGE model 17 Peter B Dixon, Sergei Schreider and Glyn Wittwer Section 2 Labour markets and human capital — discrete choice models 31 3 Selectivity and two-part models 33 Tim R L Fry 4 The determinants of students’ tertiary academic success 45 Elisa Rose Birch and Paul W Miller Section 3 Evaluating microeconomic policies — experimental techniques 81 5 Experimental and quasi-experimental methods of microeconomic program and policy evaluation 83 Jeff Borland, Yi-Ping Tseng and Roger Wilkins 6 Discrete choice experiments in the analysis of health policy 119 Denzil G Fiebig and Jane Hall Section 4 Measuring productivity 137 7 A ‘model consistent’ approach to productivity measurement 139 Russel Cooper and Gary Madden 8 Environmental productivity accounting 171 C A Knox Lovell 9 Estimation of total factor productivity 195 Robert Breunig and Marn-Heong Wong CONTENTS V Section 5 Assessing health and ageing policies using microsimulations 215 10 The new frontier of health and aged care 217 Laurie Brown and Ann Harding 11 Behavioural microsimulation modelling with the Melbourne Institute Tax and Transfer Simulator (MITTS): uses and extensions 247 John Creedy and Guyonne Kalb Section 6 Trade and welfare 293 12 Extending CGE modelling to the liberalisation of services trade 295 Philippa Dee 13 Welfare analysis in an empirical trade model with oligopoly: the case of Australian non-durable goods imports 323 Harry Bloch and Han Hwee Chong VI CONTENTS VII 1 Asset markets and financial flows in general equilibrium models Warwick J. McKibbin Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis and Economics Division, RSPAS, Australian National University and The Lowy Institute for International Policy and Alison Stegman Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis and Economics Division, RSPAS, Australian National University Abstract This paper summarises the role of asset markets in general equilibrium models, focusing on the approach in the MSG and G-Cubed models. It is argued that asset markets play a critical role in macroeconomic dynamics and that ignoring this role is a weakness of many general equilibrium models that attempt to analyse dynamic adjustment. The important role of asset markets is highlighted in several applications of the G-Cubed and MSG models, including analysis of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), trade policy reform, the Asian crisis and climate policy. 1.1 Introduction This paper discusses the importance of asset markets and financial flows in general equilibrium models. Asset markets and financial flows play an important role in adjustment to economic shocks and policy changes. If this role is not integrated into economic models, the dynamic story of adjustment will be incomplete and the usefulness of modelling results will be limited. The MSG and G-Cubed models are dynamic intertemporal general equilibrium models that combine the approaches of traditional computable general equilibrium (CGE) models,1 real business cycle 1 These are also referred to as applied general equilibrium (AGE) models. Hereafter, we use only the term ‘CGE models’. See Dervis, de Melo and Robinson (1982), de Melo (1988), Robinson ASSET MARKETS AND 3 FINANCIAL FLOWS IN GE MODELS models 2 and macroeconometric models.3 An explicit treatment of asset markets and financial flows allows the models to provide important insights into the adjustment process following economic shocks and policy changes.4 This paper provides a general outline of the MSG and G-Cubed approaches, focusing on the role of asset markets and financial flows. These models have been used extensively to analyse the impact of economic shocks and policy adjustments. A range of studies, where the models provide important insights into policy issues, are summarised. Policy issues covered in the studies include the impacts of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), of trade policy reform and of alternative climate policy initiatives, as well as the causes and consequences of the Asian crisis. In each of these studies, the G-Cubed and MSG models provided insights that were difficult to explore in traditional CGE modelling analyses. 1.2 The MSG and G-Cubed models The MSG and G-Cubed set of models are dynamic intertemporal general equilibrium models that attempt to integrate the best features of traditional CGE models, real business cycle models and Keynesian macroeconometric models. The sectoral and country coverage of the models is flexible, and there are a range of alternative specifications. The original MSG model was developed by Warwick McKibbin and Jeffrey Sachs during the 1980s in response to the poor performance of existing macroeconometric models in understanding oil price shocks and macroeconomic imbalances, and the theoretical attack provided by the Lucas Critique (Lucas 1973). This early work, which was largely macroeconomics with rational expectations in several financial markets, evolved into the MSG2 model, documented in McKibbin and Sachs (1991), which is a single-sector (plus oil) (1989) and Shoven and Whalley (1984) for an overview of CGE models. This approach can be traced back to Johansen (1960) and, in the Australian context, see Dixon et al. (1982). 2 See Backus, Kehoe and Kydland (1992) for real business cycle models. 3 See
Recommended publications
  • COVID-19 and Economic Policy Toward the New Normal: a Monetary-Fiscal Nexus After the Crisis?
    IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS Requested by the ECON committee Monetar y Dialogue Papers, November 2020 COVID-19 and Economic Policy Toward the New Normal: A Monetary-Fiscal Nexus after the Crisis? Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Directorate-General for Internal Policies Author: Thomas MARMEFELT EN PE 658.193 - November 2020 COVID-19 and Economic Policy Toward the New Normal: A Monetary-Fiscal Nexus after the Crisis? Monetary Dialogue Papers, November 2020 Abstract Current developments during the COVID-19 pandemic involve strongly complementary monetary and fiscal policy, but both as responses to COVID-19 and not the outcome of an emergent monetary-fiscal nexus. Therefore, the ECB maintains its independence by using unconventional monetary policy measures to reach price stability, according to its mandate. This document was provided by the Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies at the request of the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs (ECON) ahead of the Monetary Dialogue with the ECB President on 19 November 2020. This document was requested by the European Parliament's committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs (ECON). AUTHOR Thomas MARMEFELT, CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research (Warsaw, Poland) and University of Södertörn (Huddinge, Sweden) ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Drazen RAKIC EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support European Parliament committees
    [Show full text]
  • Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics After World War I
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER June 2018 Working Paper 2018-06 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2018/06/ Suggested citation: Lopez, Jose A., Kris James Mitchener. 2018. “Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2018-06. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2018-06 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER* May 9, 2018 ABSTRACT. Fiscal deficits, elevated debt-to-GDP ratios, and high inflation rates suggest hyperinflation could have potentially emerged in many European countries after World War I. We demonstrate that economic policy uncertainty was instrumental in pushing a subset of European countries into hyperinflation shortly after the end of the war. Germany, Austria, Poland, and Hungary (GAPH) suffered from frequent uncertainty shocks – and correspondingly high levels of uncertainty – caused by protracted political negotiations over reparations payments, the apportionment of the Austro-Hungarian debt, and border disputes. In contrast, other European countries exhibited lower levels of measured uncertainty between 1919 and 1925, allowing them more capacity with which to implement credible commitments to their fiscal and monetary policies.
    [Show full text]
  • Making Sense of Unemployment Data
    PAGE ONE Economics® Making Sense of Unemployment Data Scott A. Wolla, Ph.D., Senior Economic Education Specialist GLOSSARY “Unemployment is like a headache or a high temperature—unpleasant and Cyclical unemployment: Unemployment exhausting but not carrying in itself any explanation of its cause.” associated with recessions in the business —William Henry Beveridge, Causes and Cures of Unemployment cycle. Discouraged worker: Someone who is not working and is not looking for work because of a belief that there are no jobs Job growth has been healthy for five years.1 However, many people still available to him or her. express concern over the health of the overall labor market. For example, Employed: People 16 years and older who Jim Clifton, CEO of Gallup, states that the “official unemployment rate, as have jobs. reported by the U.S. Department of Labor, is extremely misleading.”2 He Frictional unemployment: Unemployment proposes the Gallup Good Jobs rate as a better indicator of the health of the that results when people are new to the labor market. At the heart of Clifton and others’ concern is what the official job market, including recent graduates, or are transitioning from one job to another. unemployment rate actually measures and whether it is a reliable indicator. Labor force: The total number of workers, including both the employed and the The Labor Force: Are You In or Out? unemployed. To measure the unemployment rate, the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Labor force participation rate: The percent- (BLS) surveys 60,000 households—about 110,000 individuals—which age of the working-age population that is in the labor force.
    [Show full text]
  • Estimating the Effects of Fiscal Policy in OECD Countries
    Estimating the e®ects of ¯scal policy in OECD countries Roberto Perotti¤ This version: November 2004 Abstract This paper studies the e®ects of ¯scal policy on GDP, in°ation and interest rates in 5 OECD countries, using a structural Vector Autoregression approach. Its main results can be summarized as follows: 1) The e®ects of ¯scal policy on GDP tend to be small: government spending multipliers larger than 1 can be estimated only in the US in the pre-1980 period. 2) There is no evidence that tax cuts work faster or more e®ectively than spending increases. 3) The e®ects of government spending shocks and tax cuts on GDP and its components have become substantially weaker over time; in the post-1980 period these e®ects are mostly negative, particularly on private investment. 4) Only in the post-1980 period is there evidence of positive e®ects of government spending on long interest rates. In fact, when the real interest rate is held constant in the impulse responses, much of the decline in the response of GDP in the post-1980 period in the US and UK disappears. 5) Under plausible values of its price elasticity, government spending typically has small e®ects on in°ation. 6) Both the decline in the variance of the ¯scal shocks and the change in their transmission mechanism contribute to the decline in the variance of GDP after 1980. ¤IGIER - Universitµa Bocconi and Centre for Economic Policy Research. I thank Alberto Alesina, Olivier Blanchard, Fabio Canova, Zvi Eckstein, Jon Faust, Carlo Favero, Jordi Gal¶³, Daniel Gros, Bruce Hansen, Fumio Hayashi, Ilian Mihov, Chris Sims, Jim Stock and Mark Watson for helpful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Ten Tips for Interpreting Economic Data F Jason Furman Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers
    Ten Tips for Interpreting Economic Data f Jason Furman Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers July 24, 2015 1. Data is Noisy: Look at Data With Less Volatility and Larger Samples Monthly Employment Growth, 2014-Present Thousands of Jobs 1,000 800 Oct-14: +836/-221 600 400 200 0 -200 Mar-15: Establishment Survey -502/+119 -400 Household Survey (Payroll Concept) -600 Jan-14 Apr-14 Jul-14 Oct-14 Jan-15 Apr-15 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. • Some commentators—and even some economists—tend to focus too closely on individual monthly or weekly data releases. But economic data are notoriously volatile. In many cases, a longer-term average paints a clearer picture, reducing the influence of less informative short-term fluctuations. • The household employment survey samples only 60,000 households, whereas the establishment employment survey samples 588,000 worksites, representing millions of workers. 1 2. Data is Noisy: Look Over Longer Periods Private Sector Payroll Employment, 2008-Present Monthly Job Gain/Loss, Seasonally Adjusted 600,000 400,000 200,000 0 -200,000 12-month -400,000 moving average -600,000 -800,000 -1,000,000 2008 2010 2012 2014 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. • Long-term moving averages can smooth out short-term volatility. Over the past year, our businesses have added 240,000 jobs per month on average, more than the 217,000 per month added over the prior 12 months. The evolving moving average provides a less noisy underlying picture of economic developments. 2 2. Data is Noisy: Look Over Longer Periods Weekly Unemployment Insurance Claims, 2012-2015 Thousands 450 400 Weekly Initial Jobless Claims 350 300 Four-Week Moving Average 7/18 250 2012 2013 2014 2015 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomics Course Outline and Syllabus
    City University of New York (CUNY) CUNY Academic Works Open Educational Resources New York City College of Technology 2018 Macroeconomics Course Outline and Syllabus Sean P. MacDonald CUNY New York City College of Technology How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! More information about this work at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu/ny_oers/8 Discover additional works at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu This work is made publicly available by the City University of New York (CUNY). Contact: [email protected] COURSE OUTLINE FOR ECON 1101 – MACROECONOMICS New York City College of Technology Social Science Department COURSE CODE: 1101 TITLE: Macroeconomics Class Hours: 3, Credits: 3 COURSE DESCRIPTION: Fundamental economic ideas and the operation of the economy on a national scale. Production, distribution and consumption of goods and services, the exchange process, the role of government, the national income and its distribution, GDP, consumption function, savings function, investment spending, the multiplier principle and the influence of government spending on income and output. Analysis of monetary policy, including the banking system and the Federal Reserve System. COURSE PREREQUISITE: CUNY proficiency in reading and writing RECOMMENDED TEXTBOOK and MATERIALS* Krugman and Wells, Eds., Macroeconomics 3rd. ed, Worth Publishers, 2012 Leeds, Michael A., von Allmen, Peter and Schiming, Richard C., Macroeconomics, Pearson Education, Inc., 2006 Supplemental Reading (optional, but informative): Krugman, Paul, End This Depression
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Policy Response to the Covid-19 Crisis Note for Discussion April 9, 2020 *
    The economic policy response to the Covid-19 crisis Note for discussion April 9, 2020 * The dramatic social distancing measures that were needed to contain the Covid-19 outbreak and save lives have resulted in a major economic crisis. The magnitude and spread of the global decline in output exceeds that triggered by the Global Financial Crisis, if not the Great Depression. But the very nature of the crisis is unprecedented. As in previous major downturns, developing countries are facing a decline in foreign demand and a drop of commodity prices. They are also being locked out from global financial markets, suffer capital outflows and experience a fall of remittances. But in addition to the demand shortfall and the financial stress, this new crisis involves a major supply shock. Domestically, social distancing measures drastically reduce labor supply and increase transaction costs. Internationally, supply chains break down, which may result in shortages of key inputs and potentially in higher food prices. Another important difference with previous crises is the potential, recurrent return of the supply shock until a vaccine is developed, weighing on the prospects for recovery. A crisis of this magnitude and nature is not going to be reverted quickly. Even once the crisis bottoms out, widespread bankruptcies, increased unemployment and under-employment, and a depressed investment climate will make its effects persist. Moreover, developing countries are confronting this crisis from a weaker position compared to the Global Financial Crisis. Some financial sectors are vulnerable, corporate debt is generally high, and sovereign debt levels often constrain the fiscal space available to governments.
    [Show full text]
  • Pandemic 101:A Roadmap to Help Students Grasp an Economic Shock
    Social Education 85(2) , pp.64–71 ©2021 National Council for the Social Studies Teaching the Economic Effects of the Pandemic Pandemic 101: A Roadmap to Help Students Grasp an Economic Shock Kim Holder and Scott Niederjohn This article focuses on the major national economic indicators and how they changed within the United States real GDP; the over the course of the COVID-19 pandemic. The indicators that we discuss include output from a Ford plant in Canada is not. Gross Domestic Product (GDP), the unemployment rate, interest rates, inflation, and Economists typically measure real GDP other variations of these measures. We will also present data that sheds light on the as a growth rate per quarter: Is GDP get- monetary and fiscal policy responses to the pandemic. Graphs of these statistics are ting bigger or smaller compared to a prior sure to grab teachers’ and students’ attention due to the dramatic shock fueled by the quarter? In fact, a common definition of pandemic. We will explain these economic indicators with additional attention to what a recession is two quarters in a row of they measure and the limitations they may present. Teachers will be introduced to the declining real GDP. Incidentally, it also Federal Reserve Economic Database (FRED), which is a rich source of graphs and measures total U.S. income (and spend- information for teacher instruction and student research. Further classroom-based ing) and that explains why real GDP per resources related to understanding the economic effects of the COVID-19 pandemic capita is a well-established measure used are also presented.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy and the Long Boom
    NOVEMBER/DECEMBER1998 John B. Taylor is a professor of economics at Stanford University. The article that follows is a reprint of The Homer Jones Lecture delivered at Southern Illinois University-Edwardsville on April 16, 1998. Kent Koch provided research assistance. this lecture. This month (April 1998) the Monetary Policy United States economy celebrates seven years of economic expansion. By definition and The Long an economic expansion is the period between recessions; that is, a period of con- Boom tinued growth without a recession. The last recession in the United States ended in April 1991, so as of this April we have had seven John B. Taylor years of expansion and we are still going. This current expansion is a record breaker: regret that I never had the opportunity to to be exact it is the second longest peacetime work or study with Homer Jones. But I expansion in American history. Iknow people who worked and studied with But what is more unusual is that this him, and I have enjoyed talking with them and current expansion was preceded by the reading about their recollections of Homer first longest peacetime expansion in Amer- Jones. What is most striking to me, of all that ican history. That expansion began in has been said and written about Homer Jones, November 1982 and continued through is his incessant striving to learn more about August 1990. It lasted seven years and economics and his use of rigorous economic eight months. Although the 1980s expansion research to improve the practical operation of was the first longest peacetime expansion in economic policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Integration, Macroeconomic Policy and Micro Markets*
    Economic integration, macroeconomic policy and micro markets¤ Christopher Loewald South African National Treasury ABSTRACT: The New Partnership For Africa’s Development (NEPAD) has been established to provide a substantive platform for African countries to initiate a series of policy steps toward more rapid economic growth and poverty reduction. Critics have argued that some of the policies, especially regional integration, will do more harm than good, and have cast the debate as a binary choice between the open and closed economy. Neither a fully closed nor a fully open economy is likely to maximize welfare and growth. In contrast to the notion of policy autonomy in the closed economy, the closed economy requires far more stringent application of price controls, monetary, …scal, and competition policies than do more open economies to prevent rising in‡ation and worsening income distribution. On balance, more open trade and capital relationships are preferred, because they help to ensure consistency between macroeconomic policy and microeconomic behaviour and are more conducive to improving income distribution. ¤Dr Christopher Loewald is Chief Director of International Economics in the National Treasury. The views and opinions in this paper are solely those of the author. They should not be attributed to the National Treasury. The author thanks Kevin Fletcher, Johann Fedderke, Adam Schwartzman and John Luiz for their helpful comments. Economic integration, macroeconomic policy and micro markets 1 1 Introduction Over the past year, NEPAD has emerged as the primary vehicle for bringing African countries into what might be described as the ‘reformist’ wing of the world’s economic and political community.
    [Show full text]
  • Experimental Tests of Self-Selection and Screening in Insurance Decisions
    The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 24: 139–158 (1999) c 1999 The Geneva Association Experimental Tests of Self-Selection and Screening in Insurance Decisions ZUR SHAPIRA Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, NY 10012-1126 [email protected] ITZHAK VENEZIA School of Business, Hebrew University, Jerusalem, Israel [email protected] Abstract A major characteristic of insurance markets is information asymmetry that may lead to phenomena such as adverse selection and moral hazard. Another aspect of markets with asymmetric information is self-selection, which refers to the pattern of choices that individuals with different personal characteristics make when facing a menu of contracts or options. To combat problems of asymmetric information, insurance firms can use screening. That is, they can offer the clients a menu of choices and infer their characteristics from their choices. This article reports the results of several studies that examined the degree to which people behave according to the notions of self-selection and screening. Subjects played the role of either insurance buyers or sellers. The results of these studies provide partial support for the hypothesis that subjects use self-selection and screening in insurance markets. Our study also points at the importance of learning in experimental studies. In one-stage experiments where subjects did not get feedback, screening was not detected. When multistage experiments were conducted, and the subjects learned from experience and were also taught the relevant theories, their decisions were more aligned with screening. Key words: self-selection, screening, information asymmetry, insurance markets 1. Introduction Adverse selection is an incentive problem that emerges from informational asymmetry.
    [Show full text]
  • CHAPTER 18 Economic Policy
    CHAPTER 18 Economic Policy REVIEWING THE CHAPTER CHAPTER FOCUS The purpose of this chapter is to introduce you to an area of public policy that affects everyone in one way or another: economic policy. The chapter covers both the divided attitudes that voters have toward a “good” economy and the competing theories that economists offer on how to obtain a good economy. The various agencies that participate in formulating government economic policy are reviewed, along with the many stages of producing and implementing the annual federal budget. Finally, the controversial areas of government spending and tax reform are discussed. After reading and reviewing the material in this chapter, you should be able to do each of the following: 1. Show how voters have contradictory attitudes regarding their own and others’ economic benefits. 2. List and briefly explain the four competing economic theories discussed in the chapter. 3. Assess the nature and effect of Reaganomics. 4. List the four major federal government agencies involved in setting economic policy, and explain the role of each. 5. Analyze federal fiscal policy in terms of the text’s four categories of politics. 6. Trace the history of federal government budgeting practices up to the present day. 7. Comment on the prospects and the desirability of lowering federal spending and reforming the income tax. STUDY OUTLINE I. Introduction A. Deficit spending, a feature of the government since 1960 B. National debt is the total of all deficits C. Explanations 1. Economic reason a) Debt is a concern only if payments cannot be met b) Or the currency is no longer regarded as stable and valuable c) Interest on the debt is affordable—8 percent of all federal expenditures d) Future economic demands on the government may create a problem 2.
    [Show full text]