1 Chapter 7: Public Goods OPTIMAL PROVISION of PUBLIC GOODS

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

1 Chapter 7: Public Goods OPTIMAL PROVISION of PUBLIC GOODS OPTIMAL PROVISION OF Chapter 7: Public Goods PUBLIC GOODS Outline Pure public goods have two traits: Optimal provision of public goods. They are non-rival in consumption: The marginal cost of another person consuming the good is zero, Under-provision generally characterizes markets with public goods, absent government intervention. and does not affect your opportunity to consume the good. Private sector provision. They are non-excludable: There is no way to Crowd out deny someone the opportunity to consume the Problems good. Table 1 gives some examples. If a IcegoodIce cream cream is both is is rival, rivalalso andbecauseexcludable, excludable, ThismyCableSomeIt istable excludable, TV goods showsis non-rival, are examples since“impure” because the ofpubliccable pure my consumptionTablebecause 1it Iis can aof private simplyit precludes good.not share youpubliccompanygoods frommyconsumption goods, because can impuresimply they of it publicrefuse arein no non-rival, way goods,to hook consumingYetForOther itexample, is non-excludablegoodsice the cream a sameare crowded with“impure” ice you.because cream.sidewalk publicFinally,It Theitisdiminishes butNational isis also they andpure non-excludable,up areprivatedefense publicthe your (to system. someconsumption. goods.goods is a classicextent) becauseare both goodsonlyrivalDefiningclearly way because because forvery you difficultthey your to pure consumeare enjoyment to rival, prohibit and butitexample.once is is non-rivalnotto impure an area It isexcludable.and is non-rival protected, non-excludable. public because everyone goods my pedestriansreducedmake as from excludable.more using pedestriansice cream. the sidewalk. alsoconsumption“consumes” of that national protection. defense Optimal Provision of Private Goods use the same sidewalk. protectionIs the does good not diminish rival your in consumption of it. consumption? Consider a private good, like ice cream. Yes No Yes Ice cream Cable tv Figure 1 shows the market for ice cream Is the cones, assuming that the alternative use of good No Crowded city National defense the money is buying cookies at $1 each. sidewalk excludable This makes cookies the numeraire good. ? 1 Adding up Ben’s and Jerry’s Price At a priceBenAdding of has $3, up an neither Ben’s individual, andperson Jerry’s individual demands at each S=SMC of ice demandsJerrydownward-sloping individualalso much has an icedemands individual, cream. demand give price gives society’s demand. cream downward-slopingcurvesociety’s for ice demand cream. demand at $3. curveAt a price for ice of Adding$2,cream.Leading both up people toBen’s a competitive and Jerry’s Optimal Provision of Private Goods $3 demand moreequilibriumindividual ice cream. at demands $2. Ben give& Jerry consumesociety’s different demandThere quantities. at $2.is a market supply curve In this figure, as price adjusted, each person changed his associated with producing ice quantity consumed. cream. $2 For a private good, consumers demand different quantities at the same market price. We can also represent this relationship mathematically. Ben has preferences over cookies D DJERRY BEN SMB =DBEN+JERRY (C) and ice cream (IC): 0 Q Q Q Quantity JERRY BEN TOTAL UCICB ( , ) of ice cream As does Jerry: Figure 1 Demand for a private good UCICJ (), Optimal Provision of Private Goods Optimal Provision of Private Goods Utility maximization requires that each of The private market equilibrium in this case is their indifference curves is tangent to the socially efficient. budget constraint. Moreover, suppliers set The MRS for any quantity of ice cream equals P=MC. For Ben, we have: the SMB of that quantity–the marginal value MUPMCB ICICIC===MRS B to society equals the marginal value to any B IC, C P MC MUC CC individual in the perfectly competitive market. For Jerry we have: MUPMCJ ICICIC===MRS J J IC, C MUC PMCCC 2 Price of AddingAdding up Ben’sup Ben’s and and Jerry’s Jerry’s missiles willingnesswillingness to to pay pay gives for each society’squantity demand gives society’s for 1 missile. demand. Optimal Provision of Public Goods As does Jerry. $6 There is a market supply curve Leading to a competitiveAddingassociated up Ben’s with andproducing Jerry’s Now consider the tradeoff between a public equilibrium at 5 missiles.willingness Ben & tomissiles pay gives society’s Ben hasJerry a downward consume sloping the same Q. WhileBen’s Jerry’swillingness willingness to pay fortodemand paythe for the 5th missile. demand Dcurve for missiles. S=SMC good, like missiles, and a private good like $4 forJERRY thefirst first missile missile is $2. is $4. WhileBen’s Jerry’swillingness willingness to pay forto paythe cookies. $3 for thefifth fifth missile missile is $1. is $2. SMB=D Figure 2 shows the market for missiles, $2$2 BEN+JERRY DBEN assuming that the alternative use of the $1 money is buying cookies at $1 each. 0 1 5 Quantity of missiles Figure 2 Demand for a public good Optimal Provision of Public Goods Optimal Provision of Public Goods Unlike the case of private goods, where We can also represent this relationship aggregate demand is found by summing the mathematically. Ben has preferences over individual demands horizontally, with public cookies (C) and missiles (M): UCMB ( , ) goods, aggregate demand is found by To Ben, the marginal missile is worth MU B summing vertically. M B B = MRS MC, MU C That is, holding quantity fixed, what is each Jerry’s preferences are UCM(), person’s willingness to pay? J To Jerry, the marginal missile is worth J MU M J J = MRS MC, MU C 3 Optimal Provision of Public Goods Optimal Provision of Public Goods The social marginal benefit (SMB) of the next That is, social efficiency is maximized when missile is the sum of Ben and Jerry’s marginal the marginal costs are set equal to the sum of i rates of substitution: ∑ MRS MC, the marginal rates of substitution (rather than i where “i” represents each person in society. each individual’s MRS). Efficiency requires This is because the good is non-rival. Since a unit can be consumed by all consumers, i MCM ∑ MRSMC, = society would like the producer to take into i MCC account all consumers’ preferences. PRIVATE PROVISION OF PUBLIC GOODS: Private-sector Underprovision Private-sector Underprovision In general, the private sector underprovides Ben and Jerry benefit equally from a firework that is public goods because of the free rider provided by either of them. What matters is the total amount of fireworks. problem. Each person chooses combinations of ice cream and Consider two people, Ben and Jerry, and two fireworks in which his own MRS equals the ratio of price. consumption goods, ice cream and fireworks. For both Ben and Jerry, they set: Set the prices of each good at $1, but fireworks are a public good. Assume that MRSFIC, ==1, MU IC MU F Ben and Jerry have identical preferences. i Whereas optimal provision requires:∑ MRS FIC, = 1 i 4 Private-sector Underprovision The Free Rider Problem in Practice With identical preferences, the optimal condition is: There are some interesting examples of the free- rider problem in practice. ⎛⎞MU F MU IC 2⎜⎟== 1, which implies MU F Only 7.5% of public radio listeners in New York ⎝⎠MU IC 2 contribute to the stations–that is, there is a lot of free- riding. In the United Kingdom, the BBC charges an Recall that marginal utilities diminish with increasing annual licensing fee for all television owners. consumption of a good. Many users of file sharing services never contribute In this example, optimal provision would require uploaded files; they only download files. Some of these that fireworks are consumed until their utility equals services, like Kazaa, give download priority to those who half the marginal utility of ice cream. contribute. Thus, each individually buys too much ice cream privately. When Is Private Provision Likely to Overcome the Free Rider Problem? Some individuals care more than others Under what circumstances are private market When some individuals have especially high demand forces likely to solve the free rider problem? for a public good, private provision may emerge (but not necessarily provide efficiently – in Intense preferences. particular, the public good is still likely to be Altruism. underprovided). Utility from one’s own contribution to the public The key intuition is that the decision to provide a good. public good is a function of the enjoyment that the individual gets from the total amount of the public good, net of cost. If a person gets a lot of enjoyment, or has a lot of money, he will choose to purchase more of the public good even though it benefits others. 5 PUBLIC PROVISION OF PUBLIC Altruism and Warm Glow GOODS A second reason is that there is evidence that many In principle, the government could solve the individuals are altruistic, caring about the outcomes of optimal public goods provision problem and others as well as themselves. then either provide the good directly or A third reason is that that individuals may provide for a mandate individuals to provide the amount. public good is due to warm glow. In practice, three problems emerge: The warm glow model is a model of public good provision in which individuals care about both the total amount of the public Crowd-out. good and their particular contributions as well. Measuring costs and benefits. For example, they may get some psychological benefit from knowing they helped a worthy cause. Determining the public’s preferences. In this case, the public good becomes more like a private good, though it also does not fully solve the underprovision problems. Private Responses to Public Provision: Private Responses to Public Provision: The Problem of Crowd-Out The Problem of Crowd-Out In some cases, the private market may already For example, in the fireworks example with Ben and be providing a socially inefficient level of the Jerry, if one assumes: Ben and Jerry care only about the total number of private good.
Recommended publications
  • Labour Supply
    7/30/2009 Chapter 2 Labour Supply McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4th edition Copyright © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 2- 2 Introduction to Labour Supply • This chapter: The static theory of labour supply (LS), i. e. how workers allocate their time at a point in time, plus some extensions beyond the static model (labour supply over the life cycle; household fertility decisions). • The ‘neoclassical model of labour-leisure choice’. - Basic idea: Individuals seek to maximise well -being by consuming both goods and leisure. Most people have to work to earn money to buy goods. Therefore, there is a trade-off between hours worked and leisure. 1 7/30/2009 2- 3 2.1 Measuring the Labour Force • The US de finit io ns in t his sect io n a re s imila r to t hose in N Z. - However, you have to know the NZ definitions (see, for example, chapter 14 of the New Zealand Official Yearbook 2008, and the explanatory notes in Labour Market Statistics 2008, which were both handed out in class). • Labour Force (LF) = Employed (E) + Unemployed (U). - Any person in the working -age population who is neither employed nor unemployed is “not in the labour force”. - Who counts as ‘employed’? Size of LF does not tell us about “intensity” of work (hours worked) because someone working ONE hour per week counts as employed. - Full-time workers are those working 30 hours or more per week. 2- 4 Measuring the Labour Force • Labor Force Participation Rate: LFPR = LF/P - Fraction of the working-age population P that is in the labour force.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 8 8 Slutsky Equation
    Chapter 8 Slutsky Equation Effects of a Price Change What happens when a commodity’s price decreases? – Substitution effect: the commodity is relatively cheaper, so consumers substitute it for now relatively more expensive other commodities. Effects of a Price Change – Income effect: the consumer’s budget of $y can purchase more than before, as if the consumer’s income rose, with consequent income effects on quantities demanded. Effects of a Price Change Consumer’s budget is $y. x2 y Original choice p2 x1 Effects of a Price Change Consumer’s budget is $y. x 2 Lower price for commodity 1 y pivots the constraint outwards. p2 x1 Effects of a Price Change Consumer’s budget is $y. x 2 Lower price for commodity 1 y pivots the constraint outwards. p2 Now only $y’ are needed to buy the y' original bundle at the new prices , as if the consumer’s income has p2 increased by $y - $y’. x1 Effects of a Price Change Changes to quantities demanded due to this ‘extra’ income are the income effect of the price change. Effects of a Price Change Slutskyyg discovered that changes to demand from a price change are always the sum of a pure substitution effect and an income effect. Real Income Changes Slutsky asserted that if, at the new pp,rices, – less income is needed to buy the original bundle then “real income ” is increased – more income is needed to buy the original bundle then “real income ” is decreased Real Income Changes x2 Original budget constraint and choice x1 Real Income Changes x2 Original budget constraint and choice New budget constraint
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Curve
    Econ 201: Introduction to Economics Analysis September 4 Lecture: Supply and Demand Jeffrey Parker Reed College Daily dose of The Far Side Keeping with the vegetable theme from Wednesday… www.thefarside.com 2 Preview of this class session • Basic principles of market analysis using supply and demand curves are central to economics • Formal conditions for “perfectly competitive” markets are strict and rarely satisfied • We discuss what supply curves and demand curves are • We define market equilibrium and why we expect markets to move there • We consider effects of shifts in curves on equilibrium price and quantity 3 “Two-curve” analysis • Why is it useful? • Two key variables (price, quantity) • One curve slopes up and the other down • Some exogenous variables affect one curve, others the other • Few affect both • Change in any exogenous variable affects one curve in predictable way: • Intersection moves SE, NE, NW, or SE • Predictable changes in price and quantity exchanged https://www.econgraphs.org/graphs/micro/supply_and_demand/supply_and_demand?textbook=varian 4 Demand function • Relates quantity of good demanded to its relative price • Quantity demanded = amount buyers are willing and able to purchase • Relative price is price of good holding all other goods constant • Reflects decision-making by potential buyers • Demand function: QD = D (P ) • Negative relationship • Downward-sloping curve • Need not be straight line https://www.econgraphs.org/graphs/micro/supply_and_demand/supply_and_demand?textbook=varian 5 Demand curves 6 Demand
    [Show full text]
  • Theory of Public Goods
    Public Goods Private versus Public Goods A private good (bread) exhibits the following two properties: exclusive: A good is exclusive if once you have purchased a good, then you can exclude others from consuming it. rival: A good is rival in consumption, in the sense that once someone buys a loaf of bread and consumes it, then that precludes you from consuming that same loaf of bread. • A rival good is depletable. A technical consequence of depletability is that consumption of additional amounts of rival goods involve some marginal costs of production. A public good (air quality) may exhibit the following two properties: nonexclusive: A good is nonexclusive if no one can be excluded from benefiting from or consuming the good once it is produced. An implication of nonexclusivity is that goods can be enjoyed without direct payment. nonrivalrous: One person's consumption of a good does not diminish the amount or quality available for others. • A nonrival good is nondepletable. A technical consequence of nondepletability is that the marginal cost of providing a nonrival good to an additional consumer is zero. • All public goods exhibit the nonexcludability property but they do not necessarily exhibit the nonrivalrous property. nonrival rival • water pollution in small body of private good excludable water, indoor air pollution pure public good/bad congestible public good/bad • users neither interfere with each • users affect good's usefulness to other nor increase good's others — mutual interference usefulness to each other of users creates negative nonexcludable (free–rider problem) externality (free–access • biodiversity, greenhouse gases problem) • noise, defence, radio signal • ocean fishery, parks • bridge, highway Aggregate Demand Curves for Private and Public Goods 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Unit 4. Consumer Behavior
    UNIT 4. CONSUMER BEHAVIOR J. Alberto Molina – J. I. Giménez Nadal UNIT 4. CONSUMER BEHAVIOR 4.1 Consumer equilibrium (Pindyck → 3.3, 3.5 and T.4) Graphical analysis. Analytical solution. 4.2 Individual demand function (Pindyck → 4.1) Derivation of the individual Marshallian demand Properties of the individual Marshallian demand 4.3 Individual demand curves and Engel curves (Pindyck → 4.1) Ordinary demand curves Crossed demand curves Engel curves 4.4 Price and income elasticities (Pindyck → 2.4, 4.1 and 4.3) Price elasticity of demand Crossed price elasticity Income elasticity 4.5 Classification of goods and demands (Pindyck → 2.4, 4.1 and 4.3) APPENDIX: Relation between expenditure and elasticities Unit 4 – Pg. 1 4.1 Consumer equilibrium Consumer equilibrium: • We proceed to analyze how the consumer chooses the quantity to buy of each good or service (market basket), given his/her: – Preferences – Budget constraint • We shall assume that the decision is made rationally: Select the quantities of goods to purchase in order to maximize the satisfaction from consumption given the available budget • We shall conclude that this market basket maximizes the utility function: – The chosen market basket must be the preferred combination of goods or services from all the available baskets and, particularly, – It is on the budget line since we do not consider the possibility of saving money for future consumption and due to the non‐satiation axiom Unit 4 – Pg. 2 4.1 Consumer equilibrium Graphical analysis • The equilibrium is the point where an indifference curve intersects the budget line, with this being the upper frontier of the budget set, which gives the highest utility, that is to say, where the indifference curve is tangent to the budget line q2 * q2 U3 U2 U1 * q1 q1 Unit 4 – Pg.
    [Show full text]
  • The Demand Curve
    Introduction to Supply and Demand Markets are … Consumers and producers Exchange goods/services for payment Most basic is a COMPETITIVE MARKET 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve Supply curve 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve Supply curve Equilibrium 5 Elements of S&D Model Demand curve Supply curve Equilibrium Demand and Supply factors Changes in equilibrium The Demand Curve Chapter 3: Supply and Demand (pages 62-71) Think for a minute… How do we calculate the amount of coffee demanded in a given year? We need a DEMAND SCHEDULE… Demand Schedule and Curve Price Quantity Law of Demand ⇑ Price=⇓ Quantity Demanded Downward-sloping curves Change in quantity demanded Caused by a ∆ in PRICE Demand schedule unchanged Movement along curve Determinants of Demand M.E.R.I.T. shifts the curve Market size (# consumers) Expectations Related prices Income Tastes and preferences Shifts in Demand Demand shifts with ∆ M.E.R.I.T. Increase = shift to right Decrease = shift to left Market Size Amount of goods demanded at a given price will change More buyers = ⇑ Demand Fewer buyers = ⇓ Demand Example: Cost of prescription drugs as the population gets older Expectations Future prices, product availability, and income can shift demand Example: What do you do if the price of gas is expected to fall next week? Example: If the iPhone 5 will be released in October what happens to demand for iPhone 4? Related prices Depends on whether the good is a SUBSTITUTE ⇑P for good 1 ⇑D for good 2 Example: Coffee and Tea COMPLEMENT ⇑P for good 1 ⇓D for good 2 Example: Peanut butter and jelly Income ⇑Income = ⇑Demand (usually…) True for NORMAL goods INFERIOR goods are different ⇑ Income = ⇓ Demand Example: Bus vs.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Unit 4. Consumer Choice Learning Objectives to Gain an Understanding of the Basic Postulates Underlying Consumer Choice: U
    Unit 4. Consumer choice Learning objectives to gain an understanding of the basic postulates underlying consumer choice: utility, the law of diminishing marginal utility and utility- maximizing conditions, and their application in consumer decision- making and in explaining the law of demand; by examining the demand side of the product market, to learn how incomes, prices and tastes affect consumer purchases; to understand how to derive an individual’s demand curve; to understand how individual and market demand curves are related; to understand how the income and substitution effects explain the shape of the demand curve. Questions for revision: Opportunity cost; Marginal analysis; Demand schedule, own and cross-price elasticities of demand; Law of demand and Giffen good; Factors of demand: tastes and incomes; Normal and inferior goods. 4.1. Total and marginal utility. Preferences: main assumptions. Indifference curves. Marginal rate of substitution Tastes (preferences) of a consumer reveal, which of the bundles X=(x1, x2) and Y=(y1, y2) is better, or gives higher utility. Utility is a correspondence between the quantities of goods consumed and the level of satisfaction of a person: U(x1,x2). Marginal utility of a good shows an increase in total utility due to infinitesimal increase in consumption of the good, provided that consumption of other goods is kept unchanged. and are marginal utilities of the first and the second good correspondingly. Marginal utility shows the slope of a utility curve (see the figure below). The law of diminishing marginal utility (the first Gossen law) states that each extra unit of a good consumed, holding constant consumption of other goods, adds successively less to utility.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Demand and Supply Are the Two Words Most Used in Economics and for Good Reason. Supply and Demand Are the Forces That Make Market Economies Work
    LC Economics www.thebusinessguys.ie© Demand Demand and Supply are the two words most used in economics and for good reason. Supply and Demand are the forces that make market economies work. They determine the quan@ty of each good produced and the price that it is sold. If you want to know how an event or policy will affect the economy, you must think first about how it will affect supply and demand. This note introduces the theory of demand. Later we will see that when demand is joined with Supply they form what is known as Market Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium decides the quan@ty and price of each good sold and in turn we see how prices allocate the economy’s scarce resources. The quan@ty demanded of any good is the amount of that good that buyers are willing and able to purchase. The word able is very important. In economics we say that you only demand something at a certain price if you buy the good at that price. If you are willing to pay the price being asked but cannot afford to pay that price, then you don’t demand it. Therefore, when we are trying to measure the level of demand at each price, all we do is add up the total amount that is bought at each price. Effec0ve Demand: refers to the desire for goods and services supported by the necessary purchasing power. So when we are speaking of demand in economics we are referring to effec@ve demand. Before we look further into demand we make ourselves aware of certain economic laws that help explain consumer’s behaviour when buying goods.
    [Show full text]
  • ELASTICITY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, Et Al.), 2Nd Edition
    Chapter 5 ELASTICITY Principles of Economics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2nd Edition Chapter Overview This chapter continues dealing with the demand and supply curves we learned about in Chapter 3. You will learn about the notion of elasticity of demand and supply, the way in which demand is affected by income, and how a price change has both income and substitution effects on the quantity demanded. Objectives After reading and reviewing this chapter, you should be able to: 1. Define elasticity of demand and differentiate between elastic and inelastic demand. 2. Calculate the elasticity of demand. 3. Understand how to apply an elasticity of demand to a business seeking to maximize revenues as well as to a policy situation. 4. Define elasticity of supply and differentiate between elastic and inelastic supply. 5. Understand the income and substitution effects of a price change. 6. Discuss the differences between short-run and long-run elasticities. Key Terms elasticity price elasticity of demand price-inelastic demand price-elastic demand price-inelastic demand (technical definition) price-elastic demand (technical definition) perfectly inelastic demand perfectly elastic demand unit-elastic demand price elasticity of supply income elasticity of demand normal goods inferior goods substitution effect of a price change income effect of a price change short-run elasticity long-run elasticity Chapter 5 – Elasticity 1 Active Review Questions Fill in the blank 1. When you drop by the only coffee shop in your neighborhood, you notice that the price of a cup of coffee has increased considerably since last week. You decide it’s not a big deal, since coffee isn’t a big part of your overall budget, and you buy a cup of coffee anyway.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. Consider the Following Preferences Over Three Goods: �~� �~� �~� � ≽ �
    1. Consider the following preferences over three goods: �~� �~� �~� � ≽ � a. Are these preferences complete? Yes, we have relationship defined between x and y, y and z, and x and z. b. Are these preferences transitive? Yes, if �~� then � ≽ �. If �~� then � ≽ �. If �~� then �~� and � ≽ �. Thus the preferences are transitive. c. Are these preferences reflexive? No, we would need � ≽ � � ≽ � 2. Write a series of preference relations over x, y, and z that are reflexive and complete, but not transitive. � ≽ � � ≽ � � ≽ � � ≽ � � ≽ � � ≻ � We know this is not transitive if � ≽ � and � ≽ � then � ≽ �. But � ≻ �, which would contradict transitivity. 3. Illustrate graphically a set of indifference curves where x is a neutral good and y is a good that the person likes: We know that this person finds x to be a neutral good because adding more x while keeping y constant (such as moving from bundle A to D, or from B to E), the person is indifferent between the new bundle with more x and the old bundle with less x. We know this person likes y because adding more y while keeping x constant (such as moving from bundle A to B, or from D to E), the person is strictly prefers the new bundle with more y than the old bundle with less y. 4. Draw the contour map for a set of preferences when x and y are perfect substitutes. Are these well-behaved? Explain why or why not. We know these are perfect substitutes because they are linear (the MRS is constant) We know they are strictly monotonic because adding Y while keeping X constant (moving from bundle A to bundle B), leads to a strictly preferred bundle (� ≻ �).
    [Show full text]
  • Unit 2: Supply, Demand, and Consumer Choice
    Unit 2: Supply, Demand, and Consumer Choice 1 DEMAND DEFINED What is Demand? Demand is the different quantities of goods that consumers are willing and able to buy at different prices. (Ex: Bill Gates is able to purchase a Ferrari, but if he isn’t willing he has NO demand for one) What is the Law of Demand? The law of demand states There is an INVERSE relationship between price and quantity demanded 2 Why does the Law of Demand occur? The law of demand is the result of three separate behavior patterns that overlap: 1.The Substitution effect 2.The Income effect 3.The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility We will define and explain each… 3 Why does the Law of Demand occur? 1. The Substitution Effect • If the price goes up for a product, consumer but less of that product and more of another substitute product (and vice versa) 2. The Income Effect • If the price goes down for a product, the purchasing power increases for consumers - allowing them to purchase more. 4 Why does the Law of Demand occur? 3. Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility U-TIL-IT- Y • Utility = Satisfaction • We buy goods because we get utility from them • The law of diminishing marginal utility states that as you consume more units of any good, the additional satisfaction from each additional unit will eventually start to decrease • In other words, the more you buy of ANY GOOD the less satisfaction you get from each new unit. Discussion Questions: 1. What does this have to do with the Law of Demand? 2.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 4 Individual and Market Demand
    Chapter 4: Individual and Market Demand CHAPTER 4 INDIVIDUAL AND MARKET DEMAND EXERCISES 1. The ACME corporation determines that at current prices the demand for its computer chips has a price elasticity of -2 in the short run, while the price elasticity for its disk drives is -1. a. If the corporation decides to raise the price of both products by 10 percent, what will happen to its sales? To its sales revenue? We know the formula for the elasticity of demand is: %DQ E = . P %DP For computer chips, EP = -2, so a 10 percent increase in price will reduce the quantity sold by 20 percent. For disk drives, EP = -1, so a 10 percent increase in price will reduce sales by 10 percent. Sales revenue is equal to price times quantity sold. Let TR1 = P1Q1 be revenue before the price change and TR2 = P2Q2 be revenue after the price change. For computer chips: DTRcc = P2Q2 - P1Q1 DTRcc = (1.1P1 )(0.8Q1 ) - P1Q1 = -0.12P1Q1, or a 12 percent decline. For disk drives: DTRdd = P2Q2 - P1Q1 DTRdd = (1.1P1 )(0.9Q1 ) - P1Q1 = -0.01P1Q1, or a 1 percent decline. Therefore, sales revenue from computer chips decreases substantially, -12 percent, while the sales revenue from disk drives is almost unchanged, -1 percent. Note that at the point on the demand curve where demand is unit elastic, total revenue is maximized. b. Can you tell from the available information which product will generate the most revenue for the firm? If yes, why? If not, what additional information would you need? No.
    [Show full text]