Interview with Neil Wallace

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Interview with Neil Wallace Neil Wallace thinks about money a lot. That might be true of all economists, of course, but Wallace is widely considered the father of money’s “microfoundations,” which is to say, its very essence—how families and firms conceive of and use it. Without that base, many believe, macroeconomic theory and policy stand on unsteady ground. But once solid micro-level fundamentals are established, predictions about the impact of change at macroeconomic levels can be made with greater certainty. Wallace began working on monetary microfoundations in the early 1970s after reading a paper by former classmate Robert Lucas, an early proponent. The so-called Lucas critique, says Wallace in the following interview, “essentially broke down the barrier between microeconomic theory and macroeconomic theory.” Ever since, he has been building crucial monetary bridges from one to the other. In his early years at the University of Minnesota, often in partnership with the Minneapolis Fed, Wallace collaborated frequently with Tom Sargent. They, with Chris Sims and Ed Prescott, were soon anointed the “Four Horsemen” of Minnesota economics and viewed as leaders of a new wave in economic theory. Prescott, Sargent and Sims recently won Nobel awards for research begun at Minnesota. Wallace is far more modest about the value of his early work, pioneering though it was. “I learned all my serious economics very slowly at the University of Minnesota. And I’m still learning. I started at such a low base,” he jokes, “and I’ve been pretty lazy.” Few agree with that assessment, of course, and the following conversation gives a glimpse of the range and insights of his prodigious research, from analyses of government guarantees and risk-taking to the impact of quantitative easing and why foreign currency markets are different from all others. SEPTEMBER 2013 PHOTOGRAPHS BY PETER TENZER 28 13 DECEMBERSEPTEMBER 2013 2013 THE INFLUENCE OF LUCAS ’72 Fed at that time. We were engaged in a number of projects to try to, you might That Lucas paper, “Expectations Region: In the early 1970s, you were say, bring some sort of rigor into the and the Neutrality of Money,” working with Tom Sargent at the Univer- making of monetary policy. had a major impact on our work. sity of Minnesota to build better models John’s vision involved building a mod- for deriving optimal policy rules under el of the macroeconomy that would be Even aside from its very varying economic assumptions. And useful to policymakers. Well, the Phillips important role as a counterex- then you got an early draft of Bob Lu- curve and how to build a relationship in ample to thinking of a Phillips cas’ 1972 paper on rational expectations. a model to account for it, and then to say Several years ago, you told me, “That pa- whether this relationship is exploitable curve correlation as invariant per cut away the underpinnings of what or not through policy—that was clearly to policy interventions and, we’d been doing.” at the heart of any such model. Tom and therefore, exploitable, it changed I were working on it, and doing nothing Wallace: Right. very different from what was standard at the standards for how we do the time. macroeconomics. It said you’ve Region: How did that paper influence And then I came across this working got to think about the econo- your work? In what fundamental ways paper by Bob Lucas. did it change your thinking about eco- And had I not known Lucas from hav- mies of dynamic systems. It also nomics and macro models? And perhaps ing been a classmate, I probably wouldn’t essentially broke down the barrier the course of your career since then. have read the paper. But knowing him between microeconomic theory and having a high opinion of him, I did Wallace: Bob Lucas and I had been fellow try to read the paper. Although it was and macroeconomic theory. grad students at the University of Chica- a pretty hard paper, I could quickly see go, and we both took Milton Friedman’s what the main message was, and I real- price theory course at the same time. This ized that it undercut what we were do- ing and that we ought to reorient our was two quarters of two, two-hour ses- move on to the next date. But it was re- research endeavor in a major way. sions a week, so it’s a lot. And Friedman ally just solving the model one date at a was well known for giving take-home time. Region: It was that convincing to you at exams, which were very open-ended That’s what Keynes did, and almost that point? questions—like, “This is a mystery; how everything up until that time, pret- do you think about it? How do you ex- ty much everything that grew out of plain it?” Those were the exams. Wallace: Yes, it was. Because I kind of Keynes’ general theory, was like that. Although this was microeconomics, believe that some of the best econom- And yet, all macroeconomic phenom- called “price theory” at Chicago, he gave ics consists of counterexamples. People ena inherently involved many dates. For us a question about the Phillips curve, a think A is true, and someone builds a lit- instance, people are making decisions negative association between inflation tle model whose ingredients don’t seem about how much to save and consume. and unemployment. He had briefly talk- particularly weird and it implies not A. Well, if they’re saving, it’s for the future, ed about this in class, but the take-home And so you’ve got to confront that. so they obviously have to be thinking exam question was basically, “How does about the future. this correlation come about?” I have no Region: These are theoretical counterex- Tom and I had been struggling with recollection of what I wrote. amples, not necessarily empirical? how to put these notions about the fu- ture into models. Tom had already done Region: This was the early ’60s? Wallace: Well, for me, yes, and certainly some of this in his Ph.D. dissertation at that paper was a theoretical counterex- Harvard several years earlier, but we were Wallace: This was the winter of 1961. Bob ample. And people had varying reac- struggling with trying to do this kind of Lucas was in this class, as I said, so may- tions to it, but Tom and I bought into it. thing in complete economy models. At be this was the start of his eight, nine, 10 And, in part, we bought into it because the time, my mathematical tools weren’t years of work on this question. Now, in macroeconomics at the time was emerg- good enough to do this. the early 1970s, Tom and I were work- ing from what we call static models. Such ing together under the general auspices models take conditions at a date and try Region: But as you and Tom developed of John Kareken, who was economic ad- to sort of figure out what is going to hap- the math, how did it focus your future viser to the president of the Minneapolis pen at that date and then, based on that, research? DECEMBER 2013 14 Wallace: Well, that Lucas paper, “Expec- to have. But economists are not satis- tations and the Neutrality of Money,”— fied with that easy acceptance and have When two people meet, it’s often which, by the way, I’ve heard Lucas say developed a number of theories about the case that one has something at a conference, speaking publicly, that its existence and utility, as a measure of that the other person wants, he regards as having been a waste of his value, medium of exchange and so on. time—had a major impact on our work. As a monetary theorist, you’ve studied but not vice versa. And without Even aside from its very important money far more deeply than most. Many money, nothing can happen. role as a counterexample to thinking of a economists consider you the intellectual Trade will not occur. Now, this Phillips curve correlation as invariant to father of money’s microfoundations. policy interventions and, therefore, ex- When you introduce this topic to story is incomplete. ploitable for policy, that paper did other students, how do you discuss the issues things. involved? Maybe it makes sense here to It changed the standards for how we quote from your 2008 discussion of fiat do macroeconomics. It not only said money in Palgrave, where you wrote, you’ve got to think about the economies “Money is helpful when there are ab- Aristotle have this absence-of-double- of dynamic systems and solve for the sence-of-double-coincidence difficul- coincidence notion? Probably not. But whole path of outcomes, not thinking ties that cannot be easily overcome he finds someone named Paulus, a Ro- about solving it just one date at a time, with credit; and a good money has de- man jurist in the second or third century but it also essentially broke down the sirable physical properties—recogniz- A.D., who said something like, when barrier between microeconomic theory ability, portability and divisibility.” two people meet, it’s often the case that and macroeconomic theory. [See Wallace 2008.] one has something that the other person I don’t know if that’s a good starting wants, but not vice versa. And without Region: Which is why establishing mi- point, but … money, nothing can happen. crofoundations became crucial. Wallace: It’s a reasonable starting point.
Recommended publications
  • Risk, Return, and the Overthrow of the Capital Asset Pricing Model Andrew West, CFA Manager, Investment Research
    Special Topics: Fundamental Research March 2014 Risk, Return, and the Overthrow of the Capital Asset Pricing Model Andrew West, CFA Manager, Investment Research Harding Loevner invests based on common-sense principles drawn Competitive advantage within a favorable industry structure is a from our founders’ experience: we stick to high-quality, growing prerequisite for durable profitability in a company. A company in companies that we can identify through fundamental research. This an industry with unfavorable dynamics has a much steeper chal- general philosophy flows naturally from our nature as cautious, pa- lenge than one well-positioned with few rivals and strong bargain- tient people. It has been a constant throughout our firm’s existence ing power over buyers and suppliers. But, we also require that our since it was founded in 1989. In contrast to the boring continuity of companies possess competitive advantages that will allow them to thought in our little community, the prevailing wisdom in the larger sustain superior levels of return over time. Our analysts are primarily world of academic investment theory has turned about completely organized by industry rather than by geography as we believe that over this same quarter century. Theories regarding market behavior the understanding of industry structure and peer groups is key to and investment outcomes that were proclaimed as essential verities identifying such investment opportunities. and celebrated with Nobel Prizes at the beginning of this period were subsequently overturned at the end. That academic battle is an en- Sustainable growth allows cash flow and earnings to compound as grossing tale that we have followed with interest.
    [Show full text]
  • Myron S. Scholes [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B
    Myron S. Scholes [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B. Klein, Ryan Daza, and Hannah Mead Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 590-593 Abstract Myron S. Scholes is among the 71 individuals who were awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel between 1969 and 2012. This ideological profile is part of the project called “The Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” which fills the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. Keywords Classical liberalism, economists, Nobel Prize in economics, ideology, ideological migration, intellectual biography. JEL classification A11, A13, B2, B3 Link to this document http://econjwatch.org/file_download/766/ScholesIPEL.pdf ECON JOURNAL WATCH Schelling, Thomas C. 2007. Strategies of Commitment and Other Essays. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Schelling, Thomas C. 2013. Email correspondence with Daniel Klein, June 12. Schelling, Thomas C., and Morton H. Halperin. 1961. Strategy and Arms Control. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund. Myron S. Scholes by Daniel B. Klein, Ryan Daza, and Hannah Mead Myron Scholes (1941–) was born and raised in Ontario. His father, born in New York City, was a teacher in Rochester. He moved to Ontario to practice dentistry in 1930. Scholes’s mother moved as a young girl to Ontario from Russia and its pogroms (Scholes 2009a, 235). His mother and his uncle ran a successful chain of department stores. Scholes’s “first exposure to agency and contracting problems” was a family dispute that left his mother out of much of the business (Scholes 2009a, 235). In high school, he “enjoyed puzzles and financial issues,” succeeded in mathematics, physics, and biology, and subsequently was solicited to enter a engineering program by McMaster University (Scholes 2009a, 236-237).
    [Show full text]
  • Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to Be Justified by Subsequent Changes
    Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justifiedby SubsequentChanges in Dividends? By ROBERTJ. SHILLER* A simple model that is commonlyused to and RichardPorter on the stock market,and interpret movements in corporate common by myself on the bond market. stock. price indexes asserts that real stock To illustrategraphically why it seems that prices equal the present value of rationally stock pricesare too volatile,I have plotted in expected or optimally forecastedfuture real Figure 1 a stock price index p, with its ex dividendsdiscounted by a constant real dis- post rational counterpart p* (data set 1).' count rate. This valuation model (or varia- The stock price index pt is the real Standard tions on it in which the real discount rate is and Poor's Composite Stock Price Index (de- not constant but fairly stable) is often used trended by dividing by a factor proportional by economistsand marketanalysts alike as a to the long-run exponential growth path) and plausible model to describe the behaviorof p* is the present discounted value of the aggregatemarket indexes and is viewed as actual subsequentreal dividends (also as a providing a reasonable story to tell when proportionof the same long-rungrowth fac- people ask what accounts for a sudden tor).2 The analogous series for a modified movement in stock price indexes. Such Dow Jones IndustrialAverage appear in Fig- movementsare then attributedto "new in- ure 2 (data set 2). One is struck by the formation" about future dividends. I will smoothness and stability of the ex post ra- refer to this model as the "efficientmarkets tional price series p* when compared with model"although it shouldbe recognizedthat the actualprice series.This behaviorof p* is this name has also been applied to other due to the fact that the presentvalue relation models.
    [Show full text]
  • Editor's Letter
    Why I Shall Miss Merton Miller Peter L. Bernstein erton Miller’s death received the proper somewhere,” he recalls. Miller was instrumental in tak- notices due a winner of the Nobel Prize, but ing Sharpe to the Quadrangle Club in Chicago, where Mthese reports emphasize the importance of he could present his ideas to faculty members like his intellectual contributions rather than his significance Miller, Lorie, and Fama. The invitation led to an as a human being. Nobody gives out Nobel Prizes for appointment to join the Chicago faculty, and Sharpe being a superior member of the human race, but Miller and his theories were on their way. would surely have been a laureate if someone had ever Miller’s role in launching the Black-Scholes- decided to create such a prize. Merton option pricing model was even more deter- Quite aside from the extraordinary insights gained mining. In October 1970, the three young scholars from Modigliani-Miller, we owe Merton Miller a deep had completed their work, and began the search for a debt of gratitude for his efforts to promote the careers journal that would publish it. “A Theoretical Valuation of young scholars whose little-noted innovations would Formula for Options, Warrants, and Other in time rock the world of finance. Works at the core of Securities”—subsequently given the more palatable modern investment theory might still be gathering dust title of “The Pricing of Options and Corporate somewhere—or might not even have been created— Liabilities”—was promptly rejected by Chicago’s by guest on October 1, 2021.
    [Show full text]
  • The International Monetary System: Quo Vadis
    Columbia University Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series The International Monetary System: Quo Vadis Robert A. Mundell Discussion Paper #:0102-34 Department of Economics Columbia University New York, NY 10027 March 2002 The International Monetary System: Quo Vadis Robert Mundell Columbia University February 8, 2001 Manuel Guitian Memorial Lecture, International Monetary Fund, February 8, 2001 I. Manuel Guitian Manuel Guitian was one of two brilliant students I met in 1965 at the Graduate Institute of International Studies in Geneva. Both went on to the University of Chicago for the Ph.D. program and to great distinction as economists. The other student was Rudiger Dornbusch. My students at Geneva were required to write a research paper on international monetary economics. Manuel and I agreed that he should look into the Poincare-Rist stabilization of the franc in 1926. That got him interested in exchange rate theory and it was an interest that persisted throughout his life. The quality of his analysis of that important episode from the inter-war years convinced me that Manuel had a good future as an economist and I encouraged him to go to Chicago for his Ph.D. University of Chicago Economics in the late 1960s was in one of its golden periods, maybe comparable to Vienna in the 1880s or Harvard, Chicago or Cambridge in the 1930s. There were Frank Knight (emeritus), Earl Hamilton (emeritus), Milton Friedman, Theodore Schultz, Harry Johnson, George Stigler, Hiro Uzawa, Arnold Harberger, Merton Miller, Bert Hoselitz, Robert Fogel, D. Gale Johnson, Gary Becker, Robert Aliber, Arthur Laffer, Stanley Fischer, Herbert Grubel, and myself.
    [Show full text]
  • Eugene F. Fama Booth School, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, USA
    Two Pillars of Asset Pricing Prize Lecture, December 8, 2013 by Eugene F. Fama Booth School, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, USA. he Nobel Foundation asks that the Prize lecture cover the work for which T the Prize is awarded. Te announcement of this year’s Prize cites empirical work in asset pricing. I interpret this to include work on efcient capital markets and work on developing and testing asset pricing models—the two pillars, or perhaps more descriptive, the Siamese twins of asset pricing. I start with ef- cient markets and then move on to asset pricing models. EFFICIENT CAPITAL MARKEts A. Early Work Te year 1962 was a propitious time for Ph.D. research at the University of Chi- cago. Computers were coming into their own, liberating econometricians from their mechanical calculators. It became possible to process large amounts of data quickly, at least by previous standards. Stock prices are among the most acces- sible data, and there was burgeoning interest in studying the behavior of stock returns, centered at the University of Chicago (Merton Miller, Harry Roberts, Lester Telser, and Benoit Mandelbrot as a frequent visitor) and MIT (Sidney Alexander, Paul Cootner, Franco Modigliani, and Paul Samuelson). Modigli- ani ofen visited Chicago to work with his longtime coauthor Merton Miller, so there was frequent exchange of ideas between the two schools. It was clear from the beginning that the central question is whether asset prices refect all available information—what I labeled the efcient markets hy- pothesis (Fama 1965b). Te difculty is making the hypothesis testable. We can’t 365 6490_Book.indb 365 11/4/14 2:30 PM 366 The Nobel Prizes test whether the market does what it is supposed to do unless we specify what it is supposed to do.
    [Show full text]
  • Two Pillars of Asset Pricing †
    American Economic Review 2014, 104(6): 1467–1485 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.6.1467 Two Pillars of Asset Pricing † By Eugene F. Fama * The Nobel Foundation asks that the Nobel lecture cover the work for which the Prize is awarded. The announcement of this year’s Prize cites empirical work in asset pricing. I interpret this to include work on efficient capital markets and work on developing and testing asset pricing models—the two pillars, or perhaps more descriptive, the Siamese twins of asset pricing. I start with efficient markets and then move on to asset pricing models. I. Efficient Capital Markets A. Early Work The year 1962 was a propitious time for PhD research at the University of Chicago. Computers were coming into their own, liberating econometricians from their mechanical calculators. It became possible to process large amounts of data quickly, at least by previous standards. Stock prices are among the most accessible data, and there was burgeoning interest in studying the behavior of stock returns, cen- tered at the University of Chicago Merton Miller, Harry Roberts, Lester Telser, and ( Benoit Mandelbrot as a frequent visitor and MIT Sidney Alexander, Paul Cootner, ) ( Franco Modigliani, and Paul Samuelson . Modigliani often visited Chicago to work ) with his longtime coauthor Merton Miller, so there was frequent exchange of ideas between the two schools. It was clear from the beginning that the central question is whether asset prices reflect all available information—what I labelled the efficient markets hypothesis Fama 1965b . The difficulty is making the hypothesis testable. We can’t test whether ( ) the market does what it is supposed to do unless we specify what it is supposed to do.
    [Show full text]
  • Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates · Econ Journal Watch
    Discuss this article at Journaltalk: http://journaltalk.net/articles/5811 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 10(3) September 2013: 255-682 Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates LINK TO ABSTRACT This document contains ideological profiles of the 71 Nobel laureates in economics, 1969–2012. It is the chief part of the project called “Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” presented in the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. A formal table of contents for this document begins on the next page. The document can also be navigated by clicking on a laureate’s name in the table below to jump to his or her profile (and at the bottom of every page there is a link back to this navigation table). Navigation Table Akerlof Allais Arrow Aumann Becker Buchanan Coase Debreu Diamond Engle Fogel Friedman Frisch Granger Haavelmo Harsanyi Hayek Heckman Hicks Hurwicz Kahneman Kantorovich Klein Koopmans Krugman Kuznets Kydland Leontief Lewis Lucas Markowitz Maskin McFadden Meade Merton Miller Mirrlees Modigliani Mortensen Mundell Myerson Myrdal Nash North Ohlin Ostrom Phelps Pissarides Prescott Roth Samuelson Sargent Schelling Scholes Schultz Selten Sen Shapley Sharpe Simon Sims Smith Solow Spence Stigler Stiglitz Stone Tinbergen Tobin Vickrey Williamson jump to navigation table 255 VOLUME 10, NUMBER 3, SEPTEMBER 2013 ECON JOURNAL WATCH George A. Akerlof by Daniel B. Klein, Ryan Daza, and Hannah Mead 258-264 Maurice Allais by Daniel B. Klein, Ryan Daza, and Hannah Mead 264-267 Kenneth J. Arrow by Daniel B. Klein 268-281 Robert J. Aumann by Daniel B. Klein, Ryan Daza, and Hannah Mead 281-284 Gary S. Becker by Daniel B.
    [Show full text]
  • A Father of Modern Finance
    A Father of Modern Finance Eugene F. Fama, the consummate researcher in his 50 years at Booth, changed the way generations look at the stock market. His rigorous standards have elevated the work of students and colleagues. By Rebecca Rolfes An undergraduate at Tufts University in 1959, Eugene F. Fama,, had moved on from a major in French to economics and was a newlywed in need of an income. The late Harry Ernst, an economics professor who had a stock market forecasting service on the side, hired Fama to devise ways to anticipate changes in stock market prices. The formulas Fama came up with worked with historical data but never worked when he tested them going forward. It took him a while to figure out the problem, but when he did, he reshaped finance. Fama, by 1964 a PhD student at Chicago Booth, figured out that you can't beat the market because prices already incorporate the information in easily available signals. Competing traders will seize on any reliable piece of information that prices will rise tomorrow and bid up prices today until they reflect that knowledge. Fama quickly realized that this simple insight had important and unanticipated implications for finance. His dissertation, "The Behavior of Stock Market Prices," followed by "Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work," published in the Journal of Finance in 1970, revolutionized empirical work in finance and the understanding of financial markets. Fama's work provides the intellectual underpinnings for passively-managed and indexed mutual funds - paving the way for a new approach to investing.
    [Show full text]
  • Fall 2006 a BRIEF HISTORY of the CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Edward J. Sullivan, Lebanon Valley College
    A BRIEF HISTORY OF THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL Edward J. Sullivan, Lebanon Valley College ABSTRACT This paper explores the near-simultaneous development of the capital asset pricing model by four men: Jack Treynor, William Sharpe, John Lintner, and Jan Mossin. Further, it identifies the key ideas that inspired the research of these men. Lastly, it considers why the work of only one of them resulted in a Noble Prize in economic science. INTRODUCTION mean-variance efficient portfolio, one needs to calculate the variance-covariance matrix with N(N- The history of scientific thought is replete 1)/2 elements. Thus, a reasonably sized portfolio of with examples of individuals who independently and 100 securities requires the daunting task calculating simultaneously discover the same concept. 4,950 variances or covariances. Markowitz Undoubtedly, the most famous example of such a suggested a possible solution to this problem by coincidence is the development of calculus by both proposing a “single index model” (now referred to in Isaac Newton and Gottfried Leibniz in the the literature as a one-factor model). Indeed, it was seventeenth century. Such examples are considerably this idea that involved William Sharpe with less common in the history of economic thought. Markowitz and put Sharpe on a line of research that However, during the early 1960s, four economists -- culminated in his version of CAPM. John Lintner (1965a, b), Jan Mossin (1966), William Sharpe (1964), and Jack Treynor (1962) -- developed The other paper which motivated essentially the same model for describing security researchers is Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller’s returns.
    [Show full text]
  • Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCE AND GROWTH: THEORY AND EVIDENCE Ross Levine Working Paper 10766 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10766 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 2004 This paper is being prepared for the Handbook of Economic Growth. Philippe Aghion, Thorsten Beck, John Boyd, Maria Carkovic, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, John Kareken, Luc Laeven, Raghu Rajan, Bruce Smith, and Luigi Zingales provided helpful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©2004 by Ross Levine. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence Ross Levine NBER Working Paper No. 10766 September 2004 JEL No. G0, O0 ABSTRACT This paper reviews, appraises, and critiques theoretical and empirical research on the connections between the operation of the financial system and economic growth. While subject to ample qualifications and countervailing views, the preponderance of evidence suggests that both financial intermediaries and markets matter for growth and that reverse causality alone is not driving this relationship. Furthermore, theory and evidence imply that better developed financial systems ease external financing constraints facing firms, which illuminates one mechanism through which financial development influences economic growth. The paper highlights many areas needing additional research. Ross Levine Carlson School of Management University of Minnesota 321 19th Avenue South Minneapolis, MN 55455 and NBER [email protected] 1 I. Introduction Economists disagree sharply about the role of the financial sector in economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ECONOMIC IMPERIALISM Edward
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ECONOMIC IMPERIALISM Edward P. Lazear Working Paper 7300 http://www.nber.org/papers/w7300 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 1999 This research was supported in part by the National Science Foundation through the NBER. I am grateful to Kenneth Arrow, James Baron, Gary Becker, Roger Faith, Claudia Goldin, Morley Gunderson, Larry Katz, Robert Lucas, Michael Schwartz, Andrei Shleifer, and Nancy Stokey for helpful comments and discussions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 1999 by Edward P. Lazear. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Economic Imperialism Edward P. Lazear NBER Working Paper No. 7300 August 1999 ABSTRACT Economics is not only a social science, it is a genuine science. Like the physical sciences, economics uses a methodology that produces refutable implications and tests these implications using solid statistical techniques. In particular, economics stresses three factors that distinguish it from other social sciences. Economists use the construct of rational individuals who engage in maximizing behavior. Economic models adhere strictly to the importance of equilibrium as part of any theory. Finally, a focus on efficiency leads economists to ask questions that other social sciences ignore. These ingredients have allowed economics to invade intellectual territory that was previously deemed to be outside the discipline’s realm. Edward P. Lazear Graduate School of Business Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-5015 and NBER [email protected] Edward P.
    [Show full text]