The Economics of Tobacco Control in South Africa
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO CONTROL IN SOUTH AFRICA Corné van Walbeek Thesis presented for the Degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY in the Department of Economics UNIVERSITY OF CAPE TOWN October 2005 Supervisor: Prof. Murray Leibbrandt The Economics of Tobacco Control in South Africa Abstract ABSTRACT Between the early 1990s and 2004 aggregate cigarette consumption in South Africa decreased by more than a third and per capita cigarette consumption decreased by about half. Smoking prevalence decreased from 32 per cent in 1993 to 24 per cent in 2003. The average number of cigarettes smoked by smokers decreased from 229 packs in 1993 to 163 packs in 2003. Africans, males, young adults and poorer people experienced the most rapid decreases in smoking prevalence, while the decrease was less pronounced among whites, females, and older and more affluent people. The sharp decrease in smoking in South Africa was the result of an active and consistent tobacco control policy. The policy had two distinct pillars: (1) tobacco control legislation and (2) rapidly increasing excise taxes. In 1993 the Tobacco Products Control Act was passed which introduced health warnings on cigarette packs and advertising material for the first time. A 1999 amendment to the original legislation banned tobacco advertising, prohibited smoking in all indoor public areas, and prohibited the sale of tobacco to minors. The degree of compliance to the legislation is high. While its direct impact on cigarette consumption is not clear, the legislation has helped to de-glamorise smoking and has transferred property rights from smokers to non-smokers. Previously, through social convention, the right to pollute the air with cigarette smoke rested with smokers. The 1999 legislation assigned non-smokers the right to air unpolluted by tobacco smoke. In 1994 the government announced that it would increase the excise tax on cigarettes to 50 per cent of the retail price. This increase was phased in over a number of years. As a result of this policy the real excise tax per pack of cigarettes has increased by 256 per cent between 1994 and 2004, and the real price of cigarettes has increased by 127 per cent over the same period. Despite the sharp fall in cigarette consumption, real government revenue from tobacco excise taxes has increased by more than 140 per cent between 1994 and 2004. The effectiveness of excise tax increases as a mechanism to decrease cigarette consumption depends crucially on the magnitude of the price elasticity of demand. The price elasticity of demand is estimated at about –0.4 for developed countries and between –0.4 and –0.8 for developing countries. In this study the price elasticity of demand for cigarettes in South Africa was estimated at –0.78. Cigarette consumption was found to be highly responsive to income changes. No statistically significant relationship was found between tobacco advertising expenditure and cigarette consumption. Despite the sharp fall in cigarette consumption, the real revenue accruing to the cigarette industry (which includes the cigarette manufacturing industry, its suppliers and downstream service providers) has increased sharply. After decreasing moderately since the 1960s, the real industry price of cigarettes has more than doubled since the early 1990s. The industry price is the retail price net of excise tax and VAT. The increase in the real industry price cannot be attributed to a sharp increase in the real input 2 The Economics of Tobacco Control in South Africa Abstract costs of producing cigarettes. The most plausible explanation is that the high degree of concentration in the cigarette manufacturing industry (British American Tobacco currently has a 93 per cent market share) enabled the industry to exploit its monopoly power. Whenever the excise tax on cigarettes was raised, the industry raised the real retail price of cigarettes by a significantly larger amount. This pricing strategy led to a more rapid decline of the cigarette market than would have been achieved by the excise tax increases alone. As such, the industry’s pricing strategy has had very positive tobacco control consequences, but smokers might feel that the industry has taken advantage of its monopoly power at their expense. It is sometimes argued that excise taxes on tobacco are misdirected, because they are regressive. While tobacco control economists acknowledge this, they contend that this should not be a reason for reducing the excise tax. Instead, they argue that increases in the excise tax tend to reduce the regressivity of the excise tax, because the poor’s cigarette demand is more price sensitive than that of the rich. Using the 1990, 1995 and 2000 Income and Expenditure Surveys, it was found that the regressivity of the cigarette excise tax has decreased sharply in South Africa, for two reasons. Firstly, smoking prevalence among the poor has decreased more rapidly than among the rich. Secondly, the percentage of household income spent on cigarettes has increased by a greater amount among rich households than among poor households. However, there has been a significant shift towards roll-your- own tobacco among poor households, which tempers the results to an extent. However, this does not alter the primary conclusion that tobacco taxes have become significantly less regressive since 1990. All tobacco advertising and sponsorship was banned in 2000. Cinemas, outdoor advertising agencies and the print media were more dependent on cigarette advertising than radio and television. Between the mid-1990s and 1999 the focus shifted from direct product advertising to sponsorship advertising, presumably because sponsorship advertisements were not subject to health warnings. Tobacco advertising expenditure had been decreasing consistently since 1994. Agencies dependent on tobacco advertising had a long period in which to adjust to the ban, which became operative in 2000. 3 The Economics of Tobacco Control in South Africa Chapter 1 CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION1 1.1 In the beginning… Tobacco was first used by the Mayans and Aztecs in Central America. Christopher Columbus introduced it to the Western world in the late fifteenth century, after his pioneering voyage to the West Indies (Brooks, 1952). During the next three centuries tobacco use waxed and waned, depending on the habits of the ruling elites. Tobacco has certainly not been without controversy. The Church in Europe sporadically banned its use, declaring smoking a sin. Opposition to tobacco was based primarily on religious grounds. The first recorded, and often quoted, condemnation of tobacco was made by King James I in Counterblast to Tobacco (1604), in which he described the “filthy novelty” “a custom loathsome to the eye, hateful to the nose, harmful to the brain, dangerous to the lungs, and in the black stinking fume thereof nearest resembling the horrible Stygian smoke of the pit that is bottomless.” Many European monarchs found tobacco a handy source of excise revenue, despite religious and moral objections to tobacco use. In fact, even King James I set aside his previous objections and sought ways for the crown to profit from the tobacco trade (USDHHS, 2000: 29). By the eighteenth century tobacco use, and tobacco taxation, were so entrenched in European and North American society that Adam Smith (1776[1937]: 889) argued that “sugar, rum, and tobacco, are commodities which are no where necessaries of life, which are become objects of almost universal consumption, and which are therefore extremely proper subjects of taxation.” Before the twentieth century tobacco was used predominantly for chewing, pipe smoking, inhaling (as snuff) and cigar smoking (Fourie, 1992: 55). Cigarettes were developed early in the nineteenth century but became popular only after the production 1. A shortened version of this chapter has been published in the South African Journal of Economic History, entitled “Tobacco control in South Africa in the 1990s: A mix of advocacy, academic research and policy”. This chapter has benefited much from comments from Yusuf Saloojee, Murray Leibbrandt, Simon Millson and a referee of the Journal. 4 The Economics of Tobacco Control in South Africa Chapter 1 process was mechanised in the 1880s. Large capital intensive companies, that were able to realise economies of scale by using cigarette-rolling machines, rapidly displaced cigarette companies that employed manual labour. In the developed countries cigarettes rapidly replaced other forms of tobacco during the first quarter of the twentieth century. Some religious and civic groups strongly opposed cigarette smoking, and some states in the US even prohibited its use.2 The anti- cigarette crusaders argued their case on moralistic and unsubstantiated and often exaggerated medical grounds. However, before the 1940s professional medical opinion was generally ambivalent about the health impact of cigarette smoking (USDHHS, 2000: 34). The First World War provided a major impetus to cigarette smoking. Cigarettes were typically part of soldiers’ rations, and when the war ended their use spread rapidly to the rest of society. Between 1920 and the mid-1960s per capita cigarette consumption increased about five-fold in the US and most other developed countries (USDHHS, 2000: 33). The first epidemiological studies that linked smoking to lung cancer were performed in the 1930s (Brooks, 1952: 311-316). Using increasingly more sophisticated epidemiological research techniques, the evidence that smoking causes lung cancer mounted in the late 1940s and 1950s. The UK’s Royal College of Physicians’ report of 1962 and the US Surgeon-General’s report of 1964 were the first comprehensive medical survey reports on the detrimental impact of cigarette smoking (Royal College of Physicians, 1962 and US Department of Health, Education and Welfare, 1964). The policy impact of these reports was immense and resulted in major tobacco control interventions in many developed countries.3 Since these early studies were published, more than 50 000 articles on tobacco and health have been published in the biomedical literature (Davis, 1992:1).