Foundations of Risk Management: the Modern

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Foundations of Risk Management: the Modern FOUNDATIONS OF RISK MANAGEMENT: THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER 푛 퐸 푋 = 휇푥 = 푃(푋 = 푋푖)( 푋푖) 푖=1 FOR TWO VARIABLES 퐸 푋 + 푌 = 푃 푋 = 푋푖, 푌 = 푌푗 푋푖 + 푌푗 = 푃푖푗 푋푖 + 푌푗 = 푖 푗 푖 푗 = 푃푖푗 푋푖 + 푃푖푗 푌푗 = 푃푖푋푖 + 푃푗푌푗 = 푬 푿 + 푬(풀) 푖 푗 푖 푗 푖 푖 푃푖푗 = 푃푖 푃푖푗 = 푃푗 푗 푖 FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 2 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER The expected return on portfolio is a weighted sum of returns on individual assets 푁 퐸 푅푝 = 휔푖 퐸 푅푖 푖=1 퐸 푅푝 – expected return on portfolio 푤푖 – weight of Asset i in portfolio 퐸 푅푖 – expected return on Asset i All weights should sum up to 100% of portfolio FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 3 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Old (alternative approach) is the evaluate each investment opportunity on its own N σp = ωi σi i=1 Let’s consider the following example Portfolio consist of two assets $100 is invested in asset A (standard deviation σA = $4) $100 is invested in asset B standard deviation σB = $6 N 1 1 σ = ω σ = × $4 + × $6 = $5 p i i 2 2 i=1 FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 4 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER In 1950s Harry Markowitz provided a framework for measuring risk- reduction benefits of diversification; he concluded that, unless the returns of risky assets are perfectly positively correlated, risk is reduced by diversifying across assets Markowitz used standard deviation as a measure of risk of the assets; it is still used as the best proxy Diversification – process of including additional different assets in the portfolio in order to minimize market risk (i.e. include bonds and ETFs to all-stock portfolio) The modern portfolio theory (MPT) was founded in 1960s by several independent scientific studies FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 5 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER n 2 2 2 Var X = (σx) = E X − E X X − E X = E (X − E(X)) = P(Xi)(Xi − E(X)) i=1 FOR TWO VARIABLES Var X + Y = E (X + Y − E(X + Y))2 = = E (X + Y − E X − E(Y))2 = E (퐗 − 퐄 퐗 + 퐘 − 퐄(퐘))2 = 퐄 퐗 − 퐄 퐗 퐗 − 퐄 퐗 + 퐄 퐘 − 퐄 퐘 퐘 − 퐄 퐘 + 퐄 퐗 − 퐄 퐗 퐘 − 퐄 퐘 + 퐄 퐘 − 퐄 퐘 퐗 − 퐄 퐗 = 퐂퐨퐯 퐗, 퐗 + 퐂퐨퐯 퐘, 퐘 + 퐂퐨퐯 퐗, 퐘 + 퐂퐨퐯 퐘, 퐗 = 퐕퐚퐫 퐗 + 퐕퐚퐫 퐘 + ퟐ × 퐂퐨퐯 퐗, 퐘 FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 6 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Amount Expected Expected Correlation invested return volatility ABC 20000 7% 15% 0.3 XYZ 30000 11% 22% Investor has invested cash in two companies: ABC and XYZ Weights of companies in portfolio are 20000 ◦ 푤 = = 0.4 퐴퐵퐶 20000+30000 30000 ◦ 푤 = = 0.6 푋푌푍 20000+30000 FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 7 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Expected return 퐸 푅푝 = 푤퐴퐵퐶 ∙ 퐸 푅퐴퐵퐶 + 푤푋푌푍 ∙ 퐸 푅푋푌푍 = 0.4 ∙ 7% + 0.6 ∙ 11% = 9.4% Expected volatility 2 2 2 2 푝 = 푤1 ∙ 1 + 푤2 ∙ 2 + 2 ∙ 푤1 ∙ 푤2 ∙ 1,2 ∙ 1 ∙ 2 = = 0.42 ∙ 0.152 + 0.62 ∙ 0.222 + 2 ∙ 0.4 ∙ 0.6 ∙ 0.3 ∙ 0.15 ∙ 0.22 = 16.05% FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 8 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER ABC and XYZ example shows only one allocation of capital between two assets Expected return and risk of portfolio depends on the allocation ABC/ XYZ 100%/0% 80%/20% 60%/40% 50%/50% 40%/60% 20%/80% 0% /100% 퐸 푅푝 7.00% 7.80% 8.60% 9.00% 9.40% 10.20% 11.00% 푝 15.00% 13.97% 14.35% 15.06% 16.05% 18.72% 22.00% FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 9 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER PORTFOLIO POSSIBILITIES CURVE (RETURN) 12,00% 11,00% 11,00% 10,20% 10,00% 9,40% 9,00% 8,60% 9,00% 8,00% 7,80% 7,00% 7,00% 6,00% 10,00% 15,00% 20,00% 25,00% FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 10 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER PORTFOLIO POSSIBILITIES CURVE (RISK) 12,00% 11,00% 22,00% 10,00% 18,72% 16,05% 9,00% 14,35% 15,06% 8,00% 13,97% 7,00% 15,00% 6,00% 10,00% 15,00% 20,00% 25,00% FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 11 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Minimum variance portfolio is a portfolio that has the minimum variance among all possible allocation of capital between assets. Allocation weights are solution of following problem 2 2 2 2 2 푝 = 푤1 ∙ 1 + 푤2 ∙ 2 + 2 ∙ 푤1 ∙ 푤2 ∙ 1,2 ∙ 1 ∙ 2 → 푚푛 푤1 + 푤2 = 1 푤1 = 75.34%, 푤2 = 24.66% MINIMUM VARIANCE PORTFOLIO 12,00% 11,00% 10,00% 9,00% E(R)=7.99%, 8,00% s.d.=13.93% 7,00% 6,00% 10,00% 15,00% 20,00% 25,00% FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 12 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Correlation impact on PPC 12,00% 11,00% Corr = 1 10,00% Corr = 0.7 9,00% Corr = 0.3 Corr = 0 8,00% Corr = -0.5 7,00% Corr = -1 6,00% 0,00% 5,00% 10,00% 15,00% 20,00% 25,00% FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 13 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Expected return INEFFICIENT PORTFOLIOS Risk-free Portfolio risk (σ) FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 14 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER . All portfolios on efficient frontier are made up with risky assets . Risk-free assets earns some return (at risk-free rate) and this return is expected to have zero volatility . Combination of risk-free asset and portfolio gives a new set of portfolios that form a line Expected return of combinations 퐸 푅퐶 = 푤퐹푅퐹 + 푤푃퐸 푅푃 Volatility of returns 2 2 2 2 2 퐶 = 푤퐹 퐹 + 푤푃푃 + 2푤퐹푤푃퐶표푣퐹,푃 Volatility of risk-free asset is zero, so its variance and covariance with risky portfolio are zero as well 2 2 2 퐶 = 푤푃푃 ; 푐 = 푤푃푝 FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 15 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Expected return CAL (C) CAL (B) (B) CAL (A) (C) (A) Risk-free Portfolio risk (σ) FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 16 EXPLAIN MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND INTERPRET THE MARKOWITZ EFFICIENT FRONTIER Expected return and volatility of combination of risk-free asset and risky portfolio are linear functions Relationship of expected return and volatility is also linear 퐸 푅퐶 = 푤퐹푅퐹 + 푤푃퐸 푅푃 푐 = 푤푃푝 푤퐹 + 푤푃 = 1 퐶 푤푃 = 푃 푤퐹 = 1 − 푤푃 퐶 퐶 퐸 푅퐶 = 1 − 푃 푅퐹 + 푃 ∙ 퐸 푅푃 푬 푹푷 − 푹푭 푬 푹푪 = 푹푭 + ∙ 흈푪 흈푷 FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 17 INTERPRET THE CAPITAL MARKET LINE Newly formed line that is tangent to efficient frontier is called Capital Market Line (CML) • the intercept equals a risk-free rate • the tangency point is known as a market portfolio • the slope equals a reward-to-risk ratio of risky (market) portfolio If investors have same expectations of risk and return for assets, all they will hold combination of risk-free asset and market portfolio • More risk-averse investors will buy less part of market portfolio and lend cash at risk-free rate • More risk-tolerant investors will borrow cash and buy more market portfolio FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 18 INTERPRET THE CAPITAL MARKET LINE Expected return CML 퐸 푟푚 − 푟푓 퐶푀퐿: 퐸 푟 = 푟푓 + 푀 Tangency portfolio (Market Portfolio) 퐸 푅푀 − 푅퐹 Risk-free 푇ℎ푒 푠푙표푝푒 표푓 퐶푀퐿 = 푀 Portfolio risk (σ) FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 19 INTERPRET THE CAPITAL MARKET LINE Differential Borrowing and Lending Rates. Most investors can lend unlimited amounts at the risk-free rate by buying government securities, but they must pay a premium relative to the prime rate when borrowing money. The effect of this differential is that there will be two different lines going to the Markowitz efficient frontier. Expected return New Tangency Portfolio Borrowing rate (Market Portfolio) Risk-free Portfolio risk (σ) FRM® PART I THE MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY AND THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 20 UNDERSTAND THE DERIVATION AND COMPONENTS OF THE CAPM DESCRIBE THE ASSUMPTIONS UNDERLYING THE CAPM The CAPM is an equilibrium model that predicts the expected return on a stock, given the expected return on the market, the stock's beta coefficient, and the risk-free rate.
Recommended publications
  • Understanding the Risks of Smart Beta and the Need for Smart Alpha
    UNDERSTANDING THE RISKS OF SMART BETA, AND THE NEED FOR SMART ALPHA February 2015 UNCORRELATED ANSWERS® Key Ideas Richard Yasenchak, CFA Senior Managing Director, Head of Client Portfolio Management There has been a proliferation of smart-beta strategies the past several years. According to Morningstar, asset flows into smart-beta offerings have been considerable and there are now literally thousands of such products, all offering Phillip Whitman, PhD a systematic but ‘different’ equity exposure from that offered by traditional capitalization-weighted indices. During the five years ending December 31, 2014 assets under management (AUM) of smart-beta ETFs grew by 320%; for the same period, index funds experienced AUM growth of 235% (Figure 1 on the following page). Smart beta has also become the media darling of the financial press, who often position these strategies as the answer to every investor’s investing prayers. So what is smart beta; what are its risks; and why should it matter to investors? Is there an alternative strategy that might help investors meet their investing objectives over time? These questions and more will be answered in this paper. This page is intentionally left blank. Defining smart beta and its smart-beta strategies is that they do not hold the cap-weighted market index; instead they re-weight the index based on different intended use factors such as those mentioned previously, and are therefore not The intended use of smart-beta strategies is to mitigate exposure buy-and-hold strategies like a cap-weighted index. to undesirable risk factors or to gain a potential benefit by increasing exposure to desirable risk factors resulting from a Exposure risk tactical or strategic view on the market.
    [Show full text]
  • Low-Beta Strategies
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Korn, Olaf; Kuntz, Laura-Chloé Working Paper Low-beta strategies CFR Working Paper, No. 15-17 [rev.] Provided in Cooperation with: Centre for Financial Research (CFR), University of Cologne Suggested Citation: Korn, Olaf; Kuntz, Laura-Chloé (2017) : Low-beta strategies, CFR Working Paper, No. 15-17 [rev.], University of Cologne, Centre for Financial Research (CFR), Cologne This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/158007 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten
    [Show full text]
  • 11.50 Margin Constraints and the Security Market Line
    Margin Constraints and the Security Market Line Petri Jylh¨a∗ June 9, 2016 Abstract Between the years 1934 and 1974, the Federal Reserve frequently changed the initial margin requirement for the U.S. stock market. I use this variation in margin requirements to test whether leverage constraints affect the security market line, i.e. the relation between betas and expected returns. Consistent with the theoretical predictions of Frazzini and Ped- ersen (2014), but somewhat contrary to their empirical findings, I find that tighter leverage constraints result in a flatter security market line. My results provide strong empirical sup- port for the idea that funding constraints faced by investors may, at least partially, help explain the empirical failure of the capital asset pricing model. JEL Classification: G12, G14, N22. Keywords: Leverage constraints, Security market line, Margin regulations. ∗Imperial College Business School. Imperial College London, South Kensington Campus, SW7 2AZ, London, UK; [email protected]. I thank St´ephaneChr´etien,Darrell Duffie, Samuli Kn¨upfer,Ralph Koijen, Lubos Pastor, Lasse Pedersen, Joshua Pollet, Oleg Rytchkov, Mungo Wilson, and the participants at American Economic Association 2015, Financial Intermediation Research Society 2014, Aalto University, Copenhagen Business School, Imperial College London, Luxembourg School of Finance, and Manchester Business School for helpful comments. 1 Introduction Ever since the introduction of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) by Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966), finance researchers have been studying why the return difference between high and low beta stocks is smaller than predicted by the CAPM (Black, Jensen, and Scholes, 1972). One of the first explanation for this empirical flatness of the security market line is given by Black (1972) who shows that investors' inability to borrow at the risk-free rate results in a lower cross-sectional price of risk than in the CAPM.
    [Show full text]
  • Arbitrage Pricing Theory∗
    ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY∗ Gur Huberman Zhenyu Wang† August 15, 2005 Abstract Focusing on asset returns governed by a factor structure, the APT is a one-period model, in which preclusion of arbitrage over static portfolios of these assets leads to a linear relation between the expected return and its covariance with the factors. The APT, however, does not preclude arbitrage over dynamic portfolios. Consequently, applying the model to evaluate managed portfolios contradicts the no-arbitrage spirit of the model. An empirical test of the APT entails a procedure to identify features of the underlying factor structure rather than merely a collection of mean-variance efficient factor portfolios that satisfies the linear relation. Keywords: arbitrage; asset pricing model; factor model. ∗S. N. Durlauf and L. E. Blume, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, forthcoming, Palgrave Macmillan, reproduced with permission of Palgrave Macmillan. This article is taken from the authors’ original manuscript and has not been reviewed or edited. The definitive published version of this extract may be found in the complete The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics in print and online, forthcoming. †Huberman is at Columbia University. Wang is at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and the McCombs School of Business in the University of Texas at Austin. The views stated here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Introduction The Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) was developed primarily by Ross (1976a, 1976b). It is a one-period model in which every investor believes that the stochastic properties of returns of capital assets are consistent with a factor structure.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Alpha Versus Beta in High Yield Bond Investing
    PERITUS ASSET MANAGEMENT, LLC Market Commentary Independent Credit Research – Leveraged Finance – July 2012 Understanding Alpha versus Beta in High Yield Bond Investing Investors have come to recognize that there is a secular change occurring in financial markets. After the 2008 meltdown, we have watched equities stage an impressive rally off the bottom, only to peter out. There is no conviction and valuations are once again stretched given the lack of growth as the world economy remains on shaky ground. In another one of our writings (“High Yield Bonds versus Equities”), we discussed our belief that U.S. businesses would plod along, but valuations would continue their march toward the lower end of their historical range. So far, this looks like the correct call. Europe still hasn’t been fixed, the China miracle is slowing and, perhaps, the commodity supercycle is also in the later innings. The amount of debt assumed by the developed world is unsustainable so deleveraging began a few years ago. These are not short or pleasant cycles and both governments and individuals will be grumpy participants in this event. It simply means that economic growth will be subdued for years to come. I have never really been able to understand economic growth rates that are significantly ahead of the population growth anyway…oh yeah, the productivity miracle. I have written chapter and verse on the history of financial markets and where returns have come from: yield. Anyone with access to the internet can verify that dividends, dividend growth and dividend re-investment are what have driven stock returns over the decades.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effect of Systematic Risk Factors on the Performance of the Malaysia Stock Market
    57 Proceedings of International Conference on Economics 2017 (ICE 2017) PROCEEDINGS ICE 2017 P57 – P68 ISBN 978-967-0521-99-2 THE EFFECT OF SYSTEMATIC RISK FACTORS ON THE PERFORMANCE OF THE MALAYSIA STOCK MARKET Shameer Fahmi, Caroline Geetha, Rosle Mohidin Faculty of Business, Economics and Accountancy, Universiti Malaysia Sabah ABSTRACT Malaysia has undergone a tremendous transformation in its economic due to the New Economic This has created instability on the changes in the macroeconomic fundamental, called systematic risk. The study aims to determine the effect of the systematic risk towards the performance of the stock returns. The paper aims to use the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) framework to relate the systematic risk with the performance of stock return. The variables chosen to represent the systematic risk were variables that were in line with the transformation policy implemented. The independent variables chosen were interest rate, inflation rate due to the removal of fuel subsidy and the implementation of good and service tax, exchange rate which is influenced by the inflow of foreign direct investment, crude oil price that determines the revenue of the country being an oil exporter and industrial production index that reflect political as well as business news meanwhile the dependent variable is stock returns. All the macroeconomic variables will be regressed with the lagged 2 of its own variable to obtain the residuals. The residuals will be powered by two to obtain the variance which represents the risk of each variable. The variables were run for unit root to determine the level of stationarity. This was followed by the establishment of long run relationship using Johansen Cointegration and short run relationship using Vector Error Correction Modeling.
    [Show full text]
  • Frictional Finance “Fricofinance”
    Frictional Finance “Fricofinance” Lasse H. Pedersen NYU, CEPR, and NBER Copyright 2010 © Lasse H. Pedersen Frictional Finance: Motivation In physics, frictions are not important to certain phenomena: ……but frictions are central to other phenomena: Economists used to think financial markets are like However, as in aerodynamics, the frictions are central dropping balls to the dynamics of the financial markets: Walrasian auctioneer Frictional Finance - Lasse H. Pedersen 2 Frictional Finance: Implications ¾ Financial frictions affect – Asset prices – Macroeconomy (business cycles and allocation across sectors) – Monetary policy ¾ Parsimonious model provides unified explanation of a wide variety of phenomena ¾ Empirical evidence is very strong – Stronger than almost any other influence on the markets, including systematic risk Frictional Finance - Lasse H. Pedersen 3 Frictional Finance: Definitions ¾ Market liquidity risk: – Market liquidity = ability to trade at low cost (conversely, market illiquidity = trading cost) • Measured as bid-ask spread or as market impact – Market liquidity risk = risk that trading costs will rise • We will see there are 3 relevant liquidity betas ¾ Funding liquidity risk: – Funding liquidity for a security = ability to borrow against that security • Measured as the security’s margin requirement or haircut – Funding liquidity for an investor = investor’s availability of capital relative to his need • “Measured” as Lagrange multiplier of margin constraint – Funding liquidity risk = risk of hitting margin constraint
    [Show full text]
  • Leverage and the Beta Anomaly
    Downloaded from https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109019000322 JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL AND QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS COPYRIGHT 2019, MICHAEL G. FOSTER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON, SEATTLE, WA 98195 doi:10.1017/S0022109019000322 https://www.cambridge.org/core Leverage and the Beta Anomaly Malcolm Baker, Mathias F. Hoeyer, and Jeffrey Wurgler * . IP address: 199.94.10.45 Abstract , on 13 Dec 2019 at 20:01:41 The well-known weak empirical relationship between beta risk and the cost of equity (the beta anomaly) generates a simple tradeoff theory: As firms lever up, the overall cost of cap- ital falls as leverage increases equity beta, but as debt becomes riskier the marginal benefit of increasing equity beta declines. As a simple theoretical framework predicts, we find that leverage is inversely related to asset beta, including upside asset beta, which is hard to ex- plain by the traditional leverage tradeoff with financial distress that emphasizes downside risk. The results are robust to a variety of specification choices and control variables. , subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at I. Introduction Millions of students have been taught corporate finance under the assump- tion of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) and integrated equity and debt markets. Yet, it is well known that the link between textbook measures of risk and realized returns in the stock market is weak, or even backward. For example, a dollar invested in a low beta portfolio of U.S. stocks in 1968 grows to $70.50 by 2011, while a dollar in a high beta portfolio grows to just $7.61 (see Baker, Bradley, and Taliaferro (2014)).
    [Show full text]
  • Effects of Estimating Systematic Risk in Equity Stocks in the Nairobi Securities Exchange (NSE) (An Empirical Review of Systematic Risks Estimation)
    International Journal of Academic Research in Accounting, Finance and Management Sciences Vol. 4, No.4, October 2014, pp. 228–248 E-ISSN: 2225-8329, P-ISSN: 2308-0337 © 2014 HRMARS www.hrmars.com Effects of Estimating Systematic Risk in Equity Stocks in the Nairobi Securities Exchange (NSE) (An Empirical Review of Systematic Risks Estimation) Paul Munene MUIRURI Department of Commerce and Economic Studies Jomo Kenyatta University of Agriculture and Technology Nairobi, Kenya, E-mail: [email protected] Abstract Capital Markets have become an integral part of the Kenyan economy. The manner in which securities are priced in the capital market has attracted the attention of many researchers for long. This study sought to investigate the effects of estimating of Systematic risk in equity stocks of the various sectors of the Nairobi Securities Exchange (NSE. The study will be of benefit to both policy makers and investors to identify the specific factors affecting stock prices. To the investors it will provide useful and adequate information an understanding on the relationship between risk and return as a key piece in building ones investment philosophy. To the market regulators to establish the NSE performance against investors’ perception of risks and returns and hence develop ways of building investors’ confidence, the policy makers to review and strengthening of the legal and regulatory framework. The paper examines the merged 12 sector equity securities of the companies listed at the market into 4sector namely Agricultural; Commercial and Services; Finance and Investment and Manufacturing and Allied sectors. This study Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) of Sharpe (1964) to vis-à-vis the market returns.
    [Show full text]
  • Systematic Risk of Cdos and CDO Arbitrage
    Systematic risk of CDOs and CDO arbitrage Alfred Hamerle (University of Regensburg) Thilo Liebig (Deutsche Bundesbank) Hans-Jochen Schropp (University of Regensburg) Discussion Paper Series 2: Banking and Financial Studies No 13/2009 Discussion Papers represent the authors’ personal opinions and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank or its staff. Editorial Board: Heinz Herrmann Thilo Liebig Karl-Heinz Tödter Deutsche Bundesbank, Wilhelm-Epstein-Strasse 14, 60431 Frankfurt am Main, Postfach 10 06 02, 60006 Frankfurt am Main Tel +49 69 9566-0 Telex within Germany 41227, telex from abroad 414431 Please address all orders in writing to: Deutsche Bundesbank, Press and Public Relations Division, at the above address or via fax +49 69 9566-3077 Internet http://www.bundesbank.de Reproduction permitted only if source is stated. ISBN 978-3–86558–570–7 (Printversion) ISBN 978-3–86558–571–4 (Internetversion) Abstract “Arbitrage CDOs” have recorded an explosive growth during the years before the outbreak of the financial crisis. In the present paper we discuss potential sources of such arbitrage opportunities, in particular arbitrage gains due to mispricing. For this purpose we examine the risk profiles of Collateralized Debt Obligations (CDOs) in some detail. The analyses reveal significant differences in the risk profile between CDO tranches and corporate bonds, in particular concerning the considerably increased sensitivity to systematic risks. This has far- reaching consequences for risk management, pricing and regulatory capital requirements. A simple analytical valuation model based on the CAPM and the single-factor Merton model is used in order to keep the model framework simple.
    [Show full text]
  • The Capital Asset Pricing Model (Capm)
    THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM) Investment and Valuation of Firms Juan Jose Garcia Machado WS 2012/2013 November 12, 2012 Fanck Leonard Basiliki Loli Blaž Kralj Vasileios Vlachos Contents 1. CAPM............................................................................................................................................... 3 2. Risk and return trade off ............................................................................................................... 4 Risk ................................................................................................................................................... 4 Correlation....................................................................................................................................... 5 Assumptions Underlying the CAPM ............................................................................................. 5 3. Market portfolio .............................................................................................................................. 5 Portfolio Choice in the CAPM World ........................................................................................... 7 4. CAPITAL MARKET LINE ........................................................................................................... 7 Sharpe ratio & Alpha ................................................................................................................... 10 5. SECURITY MARKET LINE ...................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • How Did Too Big to Fail Become Such a Problem for Broker-Dealers?
    How did Too Big to Fail become such a problem for broker-dealers? Speculation by Andy Atkeson March 2014 Proximate Cause • By 2008, Broker Dealers had big balance sheets • Historical experience with rapid contraction of broker dealer balance sheets and bank runs raised unpleasant memories for central bankers • No satisfactory legal or administrative procedure for “resolving” failed broker dealers • So the Fed wrestled with the question of whether broker dealers were too big to fail Why do Central Bankers care? • Historically, deposit taking “Banks” held three main assets • Non-financial commercial paper • Government securities • Demandable collateralized loans to broker-dealers • Much like money market mutual funds (MMMF’s) today • Many historical (pre-Fed) banking crises (runs) associated with sharp changes in the volume and interest rates on loans to broker dealers • Similar to what happened with MMMF’s after Lehman? • Much discussion of directions for central bank policy and regulation • New York Clearing House 1873 • National Monetary Commission 1910 • Pecora Hearings 1933 • Friedman and Schwartz 1963 Questions I want to consider • How would you fit Broker Dealers into the growth model? • What economic function do they perform in facilitating trade of securities and financing margin and short positions in securities? • What would such a theory say about the size of broker dealer value added and balance sheets? • What would be lost (socially) if we dramatically reduced broker dealer balance sheets by regulation? • Are broker-dealer liabilities
    [Show full text]