Robert Pollin WORKING POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE ECONOMY RESEARCH POLITICAL University of Massachusetts Amherst University of Massachusetts 1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Robert Pollin WORKING POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE ECONOMY RESEARCH POLITICAL University of Massachusetts Amherst University of Massachusetts 1 RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE University of Massachusetts Amherst "Saving" Robert Pollin 2002 10th floor Thompson Hall University of Massachusetts Amherst, MA, 01003-7510 Telephone: (413) 545-6355 Facsimile: (413) 545-2921 Email:[email protected] Website: http://www.umass.edu/peri/ WORKINGPAPER SERIES Number 31 1 Entry on “Saving” for John King, Editor, The Elgar Companion to Post Keynesian Economics Robert Pollin Department of Economics and Political Economy Research Institute University of Massachusetts-Amherst Amherst, MA 01002, USA January, 2002 What is the relationship between saving behaviour in capitalist economies and their macroeconomic performance? This question is a hardy perennial in the history of economics, and one that has carried great theoretical and practical significance through its many revivals. It is easy to see why this is so, since any economy that aspires to long-term increases in productivity and average living standards must devise effective means of raising the quantity and quality of its capital stock. The role of saving is central to this process, though how exactly it exerts influence has long been a matter of contention. Debates on how saving behavior affects long-term growth and business cycles stretch back to those between Ricardo and Malthus on whether Say’s law of markets that ‘supply creates its own demand’ can be violated, thereby creating the possibility for ‘general gluts’ or depressions. The Keynesian revolution, of course, was also focused on this issue, as Keynes rebelled against the 1934 ‘Treasury View’ that higher saving rates were a necessary precondition for stimulating investment and lifting the British economy out of depression. Arguing against the intuitively appealing notion that an adequate pool of saving must exist before the funds for investment can be drawn, Keynes and Richard Kahn developed the concept of the multiplier to demonstrate the counterintuitive point that higher levels of saving will generate higher saving as well. Many of the most pressing policy concerns of today remain centered on the relationship between saving and macroeconomic performance. What is saving? The answer is not obvious. Moreover, answering the most basic questions about the impact of saving on macroeconomic activity—including whether saving rates 2 are rising or falling—depends on how one defines and measures the term (this discussion follows Pollin 1997b). Two standard approaches to measuring saving are as an increase in net worth and as the residual of income after consumption. As accounting categories, these two saving measures should be equal in value. But making this distinction raises a major question: when one considers the category of asset-specific saving, should the value of assets be measured at historical costs or market values? Only the historical cost measure is equivalent conceptually to residual saving. Measured at market values, asset-specific saving will of course fluctuate along with fluctuations in asset prices themselves. Another major issue is distinguishing gross saving, including depreciation allowances, and net saving, which excludes depreciation. In principle, net saving measures the funds available to finance economic growth, while gross saving would also include funds set aside for replacing worn out capital stock. In practice, however, depreciation allowances do not simply finance replacement. Rather, they are primarily used to finance investment in capital stock that represents some advance over previous vintages. As such, depreciation funds are also utilized to promote economic growth. What is the most appropriate definition of saving? In fact, for the purposes of economic analysis, there are legitimate reasons to examine each concept. There are three basic purposes for considering saving patterns by any measure. The first is to observe households’ portfolio choices, in which case asset-specific saving is obviously the only option. The second purpose would be to understand consumer behavior. Here we would want to measure consumption directly relative to income, making saving a residual. However, asset-specific saving at market values would also be important here insofar as it contributes to understanding consumer behavior. The third reason for measuring saving is with respect to examining its role in determining credit supply, i.e. the source of funds available to finance investment and other uses of funds. This role for saving is clearly the primary consideration among analysts seeking to understand the relationship between saving and macroeconomic performance. In fact, however, the connections between any given measures 3 of saving, the provisioning of credit, and overall rates of economic activity are quite loose. We can see some indication of such loose connections through the table below on the U.S. economy. TABLE BELONGS HERE The first three rows of the table show annual figures on net, gross and net worth saving in the U.S. relative to nominal GDP between 1960 – 2000. The data are grouped on a peak-to-peak basis according to National Bureau of Economic Analysis business cycles. The last two rows of the table show, respectively, measures of credit supply and overall activity: first the ratio of total lending in the U.S. economy relative to gross private saving, then the average annual growth rate of real GDP. To begin with, the table shows substantial differences in the cycle-to-cycle behavior of the three saving ratios. For example, between the 1970s and 1980s cycles, the net saving ratio fell from 9.8 to 8.9 percent, the gross saving ratio rose from 18.4 to 19.1 percent, and the net worth ratio fell from 39.5 to 32.4 percent. Meanwhile, between these same two cycles, the lending/saving ratio rose sharply from 86.9 to 106.1 percent, while the rate of GDP growth fell from 3.3 to 2.9 percent. At the very least, one can conclude from these patterns that we cannot take for granted any analytic foundation through which we assume a simple one-way Pre-Keynesian causal connection whereby, as James Meade (1975) put it, ‘a dog called saving wagged its tail labeled investment’ instead of the Keynesian connection in which ‘a dog called investment wagged its tail labeled saving.’ The pre-Keynesian orthodox view held that the saving rate is the fundamental determinant of the rate of capital accumulation, because the saving rate determines the interest rate at which funds will be advanced to finance investment. Keynes’s challenge to this position constituted the core of the ensuing Keynesian revolution in economic theory. Nevertheless, what we may call the ‘causal saving’ view was nevertheless restored fairly quickly to its central role in the mainstream macroeconomic literature. 4 Despite neglect among mainstream economists, the ‘causal investment’ perspective has advanced substantially since the publication of Keynes’s General Theory (1936). One major development has been precisely to establish a fuller understanding of the interrelationship between saving, financial structures, and real activity. This has brought recognition that the logic of the causal investment position rests on the analysis of the financial system as well as the real- sector multiplier-accelerator model. Of course, the multiplier-accelerator analysis is the basis for the ‘paradox of thrift’, that is, low saving rates (saving as a proportion of income) can yield high levels of saving and vice versa when real resources are not fully employed. However, considered by itself, the multiplier- accelerator analysis neglects a crucial prior consideration: that the initial increment of autonomous investment must be financed, and the rate at which financing is available will influence the size of this investment increment and the subsequent expansion of output, income and saving. Kaldor (1960) was an early critic of the multiplier-accelerator causal investment position, and his argument was revived by Asimakopulos (1983). Their critique focuses on the interim period between an autonomous investment increase and the attainment, through the multiplier- accelerator process, of a new level of saving-investment equilibrium. The Kaldor-Asimakopulos position is that, as a general case during such interregnum periods, intermediaries could not be expected to accept a reduction in liquidity without receiving an interest rate inducement to do so. Rather, for intermediaries to supply an increased demand for credit would require either a rise in interest rates or a prior increase in saving. As such, low rates of saving again yield high interest rates and a dampening of investment—an argument, in other words, that returns us to the causal- saving position. In fact, Keynes himself addressed this issue, working from his theory of liquidity preference and interest rate determination. But this dimension of his argument is far less well- 5 known than the consumption function and multiplier analysis, at least in part because it is less fully developed in the General Theory itself. Holding the level of saving constant, Keynes argued that the banking system—private institutions as well as the central bank—was capable of financing investment growth during the interregnum period without necessarily inducing a rise in interest rates. That is, as he put it, ‘In general, the banks hold the key position in the transition from a lower to a higher scale of activity,’ (1973, p. 222). Keynes based his position on a central institutional fact, that private bansk and other intermediaries, not ultimate savers, are responsible for channeling the supply of credit to nonfinancial investors. The central bank can also substantially encourage credit growth by increasing the supply of reserves to the private banking system, thereby raising the banks’ liquidity. But, even without central bank initiative, the private intermediaries could still increase their lending if they were willing to accept a temporary decline in their own liquidity. The reason the that the fall in intermediaries’ liquidity would be only temporary is that liquidity would rise again, even before the completion of the multiplier, when the recipients of the autonomous investment funds deposited those funds with an intermediary.
Recommended publications
  • Liam Brunt – Teaching Material – Keynesian Revolution 1 Week 4
    Liam Brunt – Teaching Material – Keynesian Revolution Week 4. The Keynesian Revolution. What were the major theoretical and practical obstacles to the adoption of Keynesian demand management to cure unemployment in the inter-war years? Would it have been effective? Was there a ‘Keynesian Revolution’ in economic thought and policy in the 1940s and 1950s? Readings. Peden, G. C., ‘The “Treasury View” on Public Works and Employment in the Inter-war Period,’ Economic History Review (1984). Outlines the theoretical orthodoxy against which Keynes rebelled. Middleton, R. C., ‘The Treasury in the 1930s: Political and Administrative Constraints to the Acceptance of the “New” Economics,’ Oxford Economic Papers (1982). McKibbin, R. I., ‘The Economic Policy of the Second Labour Government, 1929-31,’ Past and Present (1975). [Number 68, p96-102]. A useful look at the international reception of Keynesian policies. Floud, R., and D. N. McCloskey, The Economic History of Britain since 1700, vol. 2 (1860-1939). (Second edition, 1994). [Chapter 14 (Thomas)]. Quantitative analysis of the impact of plausible Keynesian policies. Booth, A. R., ‘The “Keynesian Revolution” in Economic Policy-making,’ Economic History Review (1983). See also the comment by Tomlinson, Economic History Review (1984). Discusses the definition and timing of the Keynesian revolution. Rollings, N., ‘British Budgetary Policy, 1945-54: a “Keynesian Revolution”?’ Economic History Review (1988). A strong rebuttal of Booth. Note: if you are unsure about the Keynesian model of the labour market then refer to Levacic and Rebmann, p70-5, 86-93. 1 Liam Brunt – Teaching Material – Keynesian Revolution KEYNESIANISM. The Central Features Of Keynesianism. 1. The economy was not self-adjusting and the government should use active policy to bring the economy back to full employment in a recession.
    [Show full text]
  • Report to Congress on International Economic and Exchange Rate Policies
    Report to Congress on International Economic and Exchange Rate Policies U.S. Department of the Treasury Office of International Affairs February 2011 This report reviews developments in international economic and exchange rate policies and is submitted pursuant to the Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act of 1988, 22 U.S.C. § 5305 (the “Act”).1 1 The Treasury Department has consulted with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and IMF management and staff in preparing this report. Table of Contents KEY FINDINGS ........................................................................................................................... 2 INTRODUCTION......................................................................................................................... 2 U.S. MACROECONOMIC TRENDS ......................................................................................... 5 THE GLOBAL ECONOMY ........................................................................................................ 7 U.S. INTERNATIONAL ACCOUNTS ....................................................................................... 9 THE DOLLAR IN FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKETS ..................................................... 10 ANALYSES OF INDIVIDUAL ECONOMIES ....................................................................... 12 ASIA ........................................................................................................................................................................ 12 China .................................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Indian Institute of Management Calcutta Working Paper Series WPS No 849/ August 2020
    Indian Institute of Management Calcutta Working Paper Series WPS No 849/ August 2020 To Spend or Not to Spend?: The Austerity Debate in Retrospect Parthapratim Pal* Professor, Economics Group IIM Calcutta, Joka, Kolkata 700104, India Email: [email protected] Partha Ray Professor, Economics Group IIM Calcutta, Joka, Kolkata 700104, India Email: [email protected] *Corresponding Author Indian Institute of Management Calcutta, Joka, D.H. Road, Kolkata 700104 URL: http://facultylive.iimcal.ac.in/workingpapers To Spend or Not to Spend?:The Austerity Debate in Retrospect Parthapratim Pal1 Partha Ray2 Abstract The concept of the desirability of government expenditure has undergone a roller-coaster evolution over the years. This paper provides a longitudinal map of this evolutionary journey. The traditional skepticism against any role of government in classical economics has been seriously questioned and effectively done away with the advent of Keynesian macroeconomics during the great depression. This was epitomized in the US President Roosevelt’s New Deal during the 1930s. While the notion of a fiscal stimulus was in vogue during the 1940s through the 1960s, with spiraling inflation, the efficacy of fiscal stimulus came to be questioned, and slowly the intellectual tradition of austerity was reborn. Theoretically, this got a fillip initially from Milton Friedman and later by the rational expectationists like Robert Lucas or Robert Barro. While the birth of the new Keynesians since the 1980s swung the austerity pendulum away from a hands- off policy of the government, absence of any major recession in the advanced world during the 1990s and first few years of the new millennium, gave credence towards a policy of fiscal minimalism and associated austerity.
    [Show full text]
  • Cornell-Dyson-Wp1607
    WP 2016-07 April 2016 Working Paper Charles H. Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853-7801 USA ECONOMICS AND ECONOMIC POLICY Ravi Kanbur It is the Policy of Cornell University actively to support equality of educational and employment opportunity. No person shall be denied admission to any educational program or activity or be denied employment on the basis of any legally prohibited discrimination involving, but not limited to, such factors as race, color, creed, religion, national or ethnic origin, sex, age or handicap. The University is committed to the maintenance of affirmative action programs which will assure the continuation of such equality of opportunity. Economics and Economic Policy* Ravi Kanbur www.kanbur.dyson.cornell.edu This version: 19 March, 2016 Contents 1. Introduction: Two Axes 2. Adam Smith, The Corn Laws, and The Compensation Principle 3. Keynes, Laissez Faire and The Treasury View 4. The Post-War Consensus in Macroeconomics and its Breakdown 5. W. Arthur Lewis, Economics, and Economic Development Policy 6. The Washington Consensus and The End of History 7. Economics and the Financial Crisis of 2008 8. Rising Inequality: Economic Analysis and Policy Concerns 9. Conclusion: The Two Axes Again References * Contribution to Report of the International Panel on Social Progress 3 1. Introduction: Two Axes The emergence of economics as a self-standing discipline relatively independent of moral philosophy is commonly dated at the publication of Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations in 1776. In this founding tract, and in the subsequent quarter millennium of disciplinary discourse, economics has rarely been far from policy making.
    [Show full text]
  • Official Information Act Response 20150339
    Reference: 20150339 28 September 2015 Thank you for your Official Information Act request, received on 7 August 2015. You requested the following: “copies of any papers, briefings or reports done by the Treasury on different ways the Government measures the growth of the country, (i.e. as alternatives to using only GDP). This request is for work done since January 1 2014.” On 3 September we extended the time limit for deciding on your request by an additional 20 working days. Information Being Released Please find enclosed the following documents: Item Date Document Description Decision 1. December 2014 Evidence Brief on economic Release relevant section growth and productivity 2. 5 February 2015 Assessing Economic Growth Release, withholding Within Treasury’s Living personal contact details Standard’s Framework I have decided to release the relevant parts of the documents listed above, subject to information being withheld under the following section of the Official Information Act, as applicable: • personal contact details of officials, under section 9(2)(a) – to protect the privacy of natural persons, including deceased people. The first paper was prepared as part of the development of Treasury’s narrative Holding On and Letting Go and the 2014 Briefing to the Incoming Minister. Only a small portion of this document is relevant to the request so we have included the five relevant pages. The full paper we are releasing (document 2) provides a more up-to-date and fulsome exploration of the issues. Document 2 was prepared by a summer intern as part of their intern project. As such, it does not necessarily consider or reflect Treasury views.
    [Show full text]
  • Geoff Tily, Another “Useful Fiction”?
    REVIEW ESSAY 1 Another “Useful Fiction”? A review essay on Backhouse & Bateman, 2 The Cambridge Companion to Keynes 3 Geoff Tily Abstract In the Companion, various authors address issues of great importance concerning the interpretation of Keynes’s econo- mics. From a theoretical perspective, IS-LM and sticky-wage interpretations are rejected. From a practical perspective, the authors argue that the profession has neglected Keynes’s monetary policies. So far so good. In this article, however, I am concerned with how the Companion appears to raise these issues merely in order to then set them aside, as unimportant, or as resolved by today’s policy consensus (as was). Through a 1 The title mimics a Samuelson observation, cited on p. 53 of the book under re- view. His “useful fiction” was that Keynes’s explanation of unemployment equi- librium relied on the assumption of rigid wages (Worswick and Trevithick 1983, 216); Howitt (1986) notes that it was “useful” because IS-LM was a “fruitful” ap- paratus only if fixed wages were imposed. 2 Roger E. Backhouse and Bradley W. Bateman (eds.), The Cambridge Compan- ion to Keynes. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, 2006, pp. xiv + 327. Subse- quent references to this work shall be indicated by page number only, in paren- theses or square brackets. All references to Keynes's work are to his Collected Writings (Keynes 1973-1982) and shall be indicated by CW and the volume number. 3 Government Economics Service, United Kingdom. e-mail: geoff.tily@hm-treasury. gov.uk. 121 122 TILY /ANOTHER “U SEFUL FICTION ”? detailed examination, I aim to show that the manner of argu- ment in the book does not conform to reasonable standards of scholarship.
    [Show full text]
  • IS-LM: an Inquest
    IS-LM: An Inquest William Darity Jr. and Warren Young Introduction Whether the IS-LM framework is to be vilified for its elusive, chameleon- like character or to be cherished for its flexibility remains an open question. What is not open to question is that its development and widespread adoption as the central mode of analytical expression for macroeconomists in the post-World War I1 era was linked intimately to the endeavor to give mathematical structure to Keynes’s General Theory (1936). In his book, Interpreting MKKeynes: The IS-LM Enigma (1987), one of the coauthors of this article, Warren Young, has examined the social and intellectual interactions among the principal figures involved in the creation of the IS-LM approach. The current essay has a different emphasis. Our focus here is on the tools rather than on the toolmakers. Therefore, we explore the content of the various models purporting to represent Keynes’s message below in comparative fashion, rather than the personalities who developed the models. There is surprising diversity in these early models. What places a macroeconomic model in the IS-LM tradition now seems to be its amenability to inclusion of equations that equate sav- Correspondence may be addressed to Professor William Darity, Department of Economics, CB ## 3305, Gardner Hall, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill NC 275 14 and Warren Young, Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University, Israel. We are grateful to David Colander, Don Patinkin, and Thomas Rymes for valuable suggestions. Patinkin provided us with several valuable documents, including copies of Palander’s work. History of Political Economy 27: I @ 1995 by Duke University Press.
    [Show full text]
  • Keynesianism and the Scandinavian Models of Economic Policy
    Jukka Pekkarinen* KEYNESIANXSM AND THE SCANDINAVIAN MODELS OF ECONOMIC POLICY * Labour Institute for Economic Research, Helsinki, and University of Helsinki, Finland. This study is partly based on the author's joint work with Juhana Vartiainen of the University of Helsinki. Special thanks are due to Peter A. Hall of Harvard University for his extensive help and encouragement. Financial support by the Ministry for Foreign affairs of the Goverment of Finland is gratefully acknowledged. 1. INTRODUCTION The relations between economic theory, economic policy and economic development are complex, The most common perception of this triangle of interactions derives from the conventional Keynesian view best represented by Keynes' famous description of politicians as the slaves of some defunct economist. According to this view, economic policy is capable of moulding economic development quite strongly. But economic policy makers, in turn, are heavily dependent on the advice of economists when choosing policy moves, Consequently, economic theory assumes a key role. This essay takes as its starting point this Keynesian view which, in its strong version, sees a unilateral chain of in£hence from economic theory through economic policy to the economy. I do not want to deny outright the existence of such a chain of influence, but I shall maintain that it is conditioned by a set of crucial economic- structural, institutional, ideological and political intervening variables which are too often neglected by economists. A study from an economist's point of view of the role of these intervening variables in the diffusion of economic ideas is the main aim of this essay, These intervening variables are investigated in a limited context, that of the Nordic economies, Contrary to what one might suppose, economic policies in the different Nordic countries display clear and systematic differences which call into question the notion of a common Scandinavian model.
    [Show full text]
  • Attacking the Treasury View, Again Dean Baker
    Attacking the Treasury View, Again Dean Baker June 2012 This paper was presented as part of a keynote address to the “After Austerity: Where next for the UK economy?” conference, convened by the Trades Union Congress in London on June 26, 2012. Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Suite 400 Washington, D.C. 20009 202-293-5380 www.cepr.net CEPR Attacking the Treasury View, Again i Contents Introduction ........................................................................................................................................................ 1 Evidence on Contraction and Austerity ......................................................................................................... 1 The Logic of Expansionary Contraction ........................................................................................................ 4 A Progressive Path Forward ............................................................................................................................ 7 Conclusion: There is Much to be Done ....................................................................................................... 11 About the Authors Dean Baker is an economist and Co-director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, D.C. CEPR Attacking the Treasury View, Again 1 Introduction When I first read The General Theory more than three decades ago, I was curious about Keynes’ repeated references to the “Treasury View” – the idea that even in a recession, government spending
    [Show full text]
  • Backwater Economics and New Pragmatism: Crises and Evolution of Economics
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Galbraith, James K. Working Paper Backwater economics and new pragmatism: Crises and evolution of economics TIGER Working Paper Series, No. 138 Provided in Cooperation with: TIGER - Transformation, Integration and Globalization Economic Research, Warsaw Suggested Citation: Galbraith, James K. (2018) : Backwater economics and new pragmatism: Crises and evolution of economics, TIGER Working Paper Series, No. 138, Transformation, Integration and Globalization Economic Research (TIGER), Warsaw This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/173165 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu TIGER TRANSFORMATION, INTEGRATION and GLOBALIZATION ECONOMIC RESEARCH CENTRUM BADAWCZE TRANSFORMACJI, INTEGRACJI I GLOBALIZACJI TIGER Working Paper Series No. 138 Backwater Economics and New Pragmatism: Crises and Evolution of Economics James K.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Depression and Its Legacy Transcript
    The Great Depression and its Legacy Transcript Date: Thursday, 27 November 2014 - 6:00PM Location: Barnard's Inn Hall 27 November 2014 The Great Depression and its Legacy Professor Jagjit Chadha 1. Introduction. The foundations of knowledge, which include language and economics, can be subject to intellectual earthquakes.[1] Such earthquakes test the robustness of established views and may lead to previously unanticipated directions for thought. A classic example is the impact of the Great Depression on the direction of economics as it led to the development of an obligation for the government to run counter-cyclical economic policies and subsequently to the growth of national income accounting, which laid the basis for the development of macroeconomic modelling. These earthquakes expose fissures between different schools of thought and economics continues to be torn between those who are broadly-speaking, expansionists and those who are more conservative.[2] It is now hard to turn on the TV, our tablets or open the newspapers without some commentary on the most recent or breaking economic story. The global financial crisis has dominated headlines for the best part of a decade and has probably driven a generation of economists to think about the financial sector in the same way that earlier generations were driven to think about unemployment. It was probably during the twentieth century that the economy began to take centre stage in the public debate. A series of crises related to managing adjustment after World War One, which was called the Great Slump and the Great Depression in the 1930s, promoted not only executive discussion of economic policy but also the need to collect data and explore the relevance of different theories of adjustment.
    [Show full text]
  • Foreign Exchange Policies of Major Trading Partners of the United States
    RE PORTT O CON GRESS FOREIGN EXCHANGE POLICIES OF MAJOR TRADING PARTNERS OF THE UNITED STATES U.S. DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS April 29, 2016 Contents EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ........................................................................................ 1 SECTION 1: GLOBAL ECONOMIC AND EXTERNAL DEVELOPMENTS ....................... 8 U.S. DOMESTIC ECONOMIC TRENDS ............................................................................ 9 U.S. EXTERNAL TRENDS .......................................................................................... 11 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC TRENDS .......................................................................... 13 SECTION 2: INTENSIFIED EVALUATION OF MAJOR TRADING PARTNERS ............ 27 KEY CRITERIA ........................................................................................................ 27 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS .......................................................................................... 29 SECTION 3: NEW ASSESSMENT FACTORS FOR ENHANCED ANALYSIS ................. 32 GLOSSARY OF KEY TERMS IN THE REPORT ......................................................... 36 This Report reviews developments in international economic and exchange rate policies and is submitted pursuant to the Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act of 1988, 22 U.S.C. § 5305, and Section 701 of the Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement Act of 2015, 19 U.S.C. § 4421.1 1 The Treasury Department has consulted with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
    [Show full text]