Multiunit Pay-Your-Bid Auction with One-Dimensional ∗ Multiunit Demands

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Multiunit Pay-Your-Bid Auction with One-Dimensional ∗ Multiunit Demands INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 44, No. 3, August 2003 MULTIUNIT PAY-YOUR-BID AUCTION WITH ONE-DIMENSIONAL ∗ MULTIUNIT DEMANDS BY BERNARD LEBRUN AND MARIE-CHRISTINE TREMBLAY1 Department of Economics, York University; Finance Canada, Policy Analysis, Ottawa An arbitrary number of units of a good is sold to two bidders through a discriminatory auction. The bidders are homogeneous ex ante and their demand functions are two-step functions that depend on a single parameter. We character- ize the symmetric Bayesian equilibrium and prove its existence and uniqueness. We compare this equilibrium with the equilibrium of the multiunit Vickrey auc- tion and with the equilibria of the single-unit first price and second price auctions. We examine the consequences of bundling all units into one package. We study the impacts that variations of the “relative” supply have on the equilibrium, on the bidders’ average payoffs per unit, and on the efficiency of the equilibrium allocation. 1. INTRODUCTION In the commonly used discriminatory or “pay-your-bid” auction, the bidders submit demand curves for multiple units of a good and the auctioneer acts as a perfectly discriminating monopolist. It has been used to sell, for example, bonds, bills, foreign exchange, import quota licenses, airport landing slots, mineral rights, timber rights (see Tenorio, 1999; Bikhchandani and Huang, 1993; Ausubel and Cramton, 1998), SO2 emission allowances (by the EPA, see Ellerman et al., 2000), and gold (by the IMF, see Feldman and Reinhart, 1995a, 1995b). When the auctioneer sells only one unit, the discriminatory auction is also called the first price auction. Researchers have studied extensively the first price auction and the discriminatory auction with multiple units where every bidder demands only one unity. In this article, we consider the two-bidder case with multiple units where both bidders have multiple-unit demands. In our model, the auctioneer puts n units of a good up for sale and sets a reserve price. A bidder values equally the first m units at vh each and values equally the remaining units at vl = g (vh) ≤ vh each. The function g is strictly increasing and common to both bidders. We refer to a bidder’s m first units as his high valuation 2 units, to his other units as his low valuation units, and to his valuation vh for ∗ Manuscript received November 1998; revised June 2002. 1 Constructive remarks by one referee and the associate editor are gratefully acknowledged. Bernard Lebrun benefited from the financial support of the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. Please address correspondence to: Bernard Lebrun, Department of Economics, York University, 4700 Keele Street, Toronto, ON, Canada M3J 1P3. Phone: 416 736 2100 (ext 33663). Fax: 416 736 5987. E-mail: [email protected]. 2 All n units are identical units of the same homogeneous good. However, because his demand curve is nondecreasing, a bidder values his first units more than his last units. 1135 1136 LEBRUN AND TREMBLAY each of his first m units as his type. Because the bidders’ types are distributed independently according to the same probability distribution F, the bidders are homogeneous ex ante. A bidder knows only his own type. We characterize the symmetric equilibrium where the bidders use the same “pure” strategy satisfying some standard regularity assumptions. We prove ex- istence and uniqueness of this equilibrium. At the equilibrium, bidders submit identical bids for units of identical valuations. When the bidders’ demand curves are flat at least up to the supplied quantity (m ≥ n), they thus submit flat curves and the equilibrium is as if the n units were bundled together. If a bidder’s bids win with strictly positive probability and if his type is differ- ent from the highest possible type, his “high bid”—the common bid on his high valuation units—is strictly larger than his “low bid”—the common bid on his low valuation units. Because the equilibrium of the discriminatory auction “separates” the high valuation units from the low valuation units, it allocates the units more ef- ficiently than the equilibrium of the first price auction where all units are bundled together. However, even without bundling, the allocation at the equilibrium of the dis- criminatory auction can be inefficient. Since bidders shade their bids less on low valuation units than on high valuation units, even if a bidder values his low valua- tion units less than his opponent values his high valuation units, his low bid may be higher than his opponent’s high bid. Indeed, this does occur with strictly positive probability and the equilibrium allocation is inefficient. In the two-unit case, there is a link between the equilibria of the multiple unit discriminatory auction with ex ante homogeneous bidders and the equilibria of the first price auction with ex ante heterogeneous bidders. The equilibrium of the discriminatory auction is as if every bidder was split into two agents, each one bidding only for one unit: a first agent, bidding for the bidder’s first unit; and a second agent, bidding for the bidder’s second unit. Since a bidder wins his first unit if and only if the other bidder does not win his second unit, a bidder’s first agent competes with the other bidder’s second agent in a first price auction. Since the valuations on the first and second units are distributed differently, the agents competing in a first price auction are heteroge- neous ex ante. In the equilibrium of the discriminatory auction, each agent bids according to the equilibrium of the first price auction. Even if a bidder’s agents bid independently, his first agent submits a bid higher than his second agent. The link in the two-unit case between the discriminatory auction with ex ante homogeneous bidders and the first price auction with ex ante heterogeneous bid- ders extends immediately to the case of an even number of units where exactly half are high valuation units. In the general case, there is no such explicit link between equilibria of the discriminatory auction and the first price auction. Nev- ertheless, we successfully apply the methods of proof from the study of the first price auction with ex ante heterogeneous bidders to the study of the discriminatory auction. A general link exists between the equilibria in weakly dominant strategies of the multiunit Vickrey auction, or Vickrey–Groves–Clark mechanism, and the (one unit) second price auction. From this link, we prove that bundling all units into one MULTIUNIT PAY-YOUR-BID AUCTION 1137 package decreases efficiency and increases the seller’s revenue from the Vickrey auction. From the link between the discriminatory auction with two units and the first price auction, we show that no such trade-off between efficiency and revenue exists in the discriminatory auction. With ex ante heterogeneous bidders, there exists no general ranking between the auctioneer’s revenues from the discriminatory and Vickrey auctions. In fact, in the one-unit case, these auctions reduce to the first price and second price auctions and, as it is well known, no general ranking exists between these two auctions when the bidders are heterogeneous ex ante. However, from the revenue equivalence theorem (see Myerson, 1981; Riley and Samuelson, 1981), the first and second price auctions are equivalent when the bidders are homogeneous ex ante. Because of the links mentioned above between the multiunit auctions with ex ante homogeneous bidders and the one-unit auctions with ex ante heterogeneous bidders, this equivalence does not extend to the multiunit case. Moreover, the nonexistence of a general ranking between the revenues from the two one-unit auctions with ex ante heterogeneous bidders implies the nonexistence of such a ranking between the revenues from the multiunit discriminatory and Vickrey auctions, even in the symmetric case of ex ante homogeneous bidders. Since the parameter m determines the position of the demand curves along the quantity axis, the ratio n/m determines the position of the supply relative to the demands.3 The equilibrium bid functions depend only on this “relative supply” n/m or, equivalently, its inverse m/n—the “relative demand” or the proportion of high valuation units in the total supply. An increase of the relative supply always increases the bidders’ per unit averages of their interim and ex ante expected payoffs. When the relative supply is equal to 2, the total supply is, in a sense, the least homogeneous to the bidders since it counts the same number of high valuation units as of low valuation units. The difference in bid shading between high and low valuation units and the probability of an inefficient allocation increase when the relative supply becomes closer to 2. If n/m < 2 or, equivalently, if a majority of units in the total supply are high valuation units to the bidders, an increase of the relative supply decreases the bid function on the high valuation units. It also decreases the “average” of the low- and high-bid probability distributions a bid on a high valuation unit competes against. In general, there are types where the bid function on the low valuation units increases. When n/m ≥ 2 or, equivalently, when a majority of units are low valuation units to the bidders, an increase of the relative supply results in a decrease of the bid function on the low valuation units and of the “average” bid probability distribution a bid on a low valuation unit competes against. The bid function on the high valuation units increases for some types. We study the two-unit case in Section 2. We extend our results to the n unit case in Section 3.
Recommended publications
  • Comparing Auction Designs Where Suppliers Have Uncertain Costs and Uncertain Pivotal Status
    RAND Journal of Economics Vol. 00, No. 0, Winter 2018 pp. 1–33 Comparing auction designs where suppliers have uncertain costs and uncertain pivotal status ∗ Par¨ Holmberg and ∗∗ Frank A. Wolak We analyze how market design influences bidding in multiunit procurement auctions where suppliers have asymmetric information about production costs. Our analysis is particularly relevant to wholesale electricity markets, because it accounts for the risk that a supplier is pivotal; market demand is larger than the total production capacity of its competitors. With constant marginal costs, expected welfare improves if the auctioneer restricts offers to be flat. We identify circumstances where the competitiveness of market outcomes improves with increased market transparency. We also find that, for buyers, uniform pricing is preferable to discriminatory pricing when producers’ private signals are affiliated. 1. Introduction Multiunit auctions are used to trade commodities, securities, emission permits, and other divisible goods. This article focuses on electricity markets, where producers submit offers before the level of demand and amount of available production capacity are fully known. Due to demand shocks, unexpected outages, transmission-constraints, and intermittent output from renewable energy sources, it often arises that an electricity producer is pivotal, that is, that realized demand is larger than the realized total production capacity of its competitors. A producer that is certain to be pivotal possess a substantial ability to exercise market power because it can withhold output ∗ Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), Associate Researcher of the Energy Policy Research Group (EPRG), University of Cambridge; [email protected]. ∗∗ Program on Energy and Sustainable Development (PESD) and Stanford University; [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Auctions
    ARE 202 Villas-Boas Introduction to auctions What is an Auction? 1. A public sale in which property or merchandise are sold to the highest bidder. 2. A market institution with explicit rules determining resource allocation and prices on the basis of bids from participants. 3. Games: The bidding in bridge, for example. Examples of Auctions FCC Spectrum McMillan, 1994, Selling Spectrum Rights, JEP. http://www.paulklemperer.org Procurement Auctions Treasury Bills Internet Wine Options Quota Rights, Auctioning countermeasures in WTO Working paper, Bagwell K., Staiger R., et al: http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/~rstaiger/auctionation071803.pdf 1 ARE 202 Villas-Boas Lots of good theory and empirical work. • Game is simple with well defined rules • Actions are observed directly • Payoffs can sometimes be inferred Also, a lot of data • Government sales: o Timber rights, mineral rights, oil and gas, treasury bills, spectrum auctions, emission permits, electricity • Government sales: o Defense, construction, school milk • Private sector: o Auctions houses, agriculture, real estate, used cars, machinery • Online auctions: Many possible mechanisms • Open versus sealed • First price versus second price • Secret versus fixed reserve price 2 ARE 202 Villas-Boas Several Formats: 4 auction types: • First-price sealed-bid auction: you don’t see your opponents’ bids. Highest bid wins. Winner pays her bid, b. The winner’s profit is: v−b. Losers get nothing. • Second-price sealed-bid auction: you don’t see your opponents’ bids. Highest bid wins. Winner pays the second highest bid in the auction. Therefore the winner’s profit is: v minus the second highest bid. Losers get nothing.
    [Show full text]
  • CO2 Emission Allowance Allocation Mechanisms, Allocative Efficiency and the Environment
    CO2 emission allowance allocation mechanisms, allocative efficiency and the environment Stefan Weishaar [email protected] Metro Maastricht University The Netherlands Proposal for a paper to be presented at: First annual meeting of the Asian Law and Economics Association Seoul National University, Korea 24-25 June 2005 University of Maastricht, Faculty of Law PO Box 616, 6200 MD Maastricht The Netherlands Tel: +31-43-3883060 Fax: +31-43-3259091 E-mail: [email protected] Abstract: The paper places allocation mechanisms into a framework of emission trading systems and analyses these mechanisms within a closed static economy and an open dynamic economy with regard to price determination, allocative efficiency and environmental considerations. Firstly the paper examines how market-based allocation mechanisms (auctions) perform in light of the above issues. Secondly the paper distinguishes between the two types of administrative allocation mechanisms: (1) financial administrative allocation mechanisms, combining payment schemes with bureaucratic expertise, and (2) free administrative allocation mechanisms, based inter alia on industrial policy considerations and on passed emission records (grandfathering). In particular, the value added of "relative performance standards" as an allocation mechanism is examined. The overall finding is that in a closed static economy and in the presence of an efficient trading market, different allocation methods produce equally efficient outcomes in allocative and environmental respects. With regard to an open dynamic economy impacts of initial allocation mechanisms resemble those of a static closed economy. In an open economy the upper limit to the internalisation of negative externalities is given by operator’s costs of environmentally harmful relocation and hence the cost burden placed upon operators is crucial.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Auction
    E Business Professor Mamata Jenamani Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering Indian Institute of Technology Kharagpur Lecture-57 Introduction to Auction Welcome back in continuation with our last lecture on dynamic pricing where we learned that dynamic pricing is very natural and it has it is convenient to implement fixed pricing that is why people were going for fixed pricing but because of Internet, now again dynamic pricing has become a reality. So in this context we saw there are many dynamic pricing models out of which we have chosen to discuss about auctions. In today’s class we are going to learn about different kinds of auctions, how to classify auctions and look at few applications if possible. (Refer Slide Time: 1:06) Now what are auctions? Auctions are again very oldest form of market. In fact if you look at the history, probably you can have the evidence of auction being happening even before price even I mean the, it has the written history of at least 500 BC. And the auctions like that of your reverse auction or auctions at EBay and similar such sites are the recent phenomena which is which means this auction has always been there and will be there. This is because as we know this provides a first-degree differentiation where actually the price can be decided based on the demand and supply conditions. Now, example of this auction is not limited to online buying, in fact starting from your spectrum auction for which there has been certain I mean even in India people were talking about this auctions and all for selling spectrum and the selling spectrum to auction is very old.
    [Show full text]
  • Efficient Multiunit Auctions for Normal Goods
    Theoretical Economics 15 (2020), 361–413 1555-7561/20200361 Efficient multiunit auctions for normal goods Brian Baisa Department of Economics, Amherst College I study multiunit auction design when bidders have private values, multiunit de- mands, and non-quasilinear preferences. Without quasilinearity, the Vickrey auc- tion loses its desired incentive and efficiency properties. I give conditions under which we can design a mechanism that retains the Vickrey auction’s desirable in- centive and efficiency properties: (1) individual rationality, (2) dominant strategy incentive compatibility, and (3) Pareto efficiency. I show that there is a mechanism that retains the desired properties of the Vickrey auction if there are two bidders who have single-dimensional types. I also present an impossibility theorem that shows that there is no mechanism that satisfies Vickrey’s desired properties and weak budget balance when bidders have multidimensional types. Keywords. Multiunit auctions, multidimensional mechanism design, wealth ef- fects. JEL classification. D44, D47, D61, D82. 1. Introduction 1.1 Motivation Understanding how to design auctions with desirable incentive and efficiency proper- ties is a central question in mechanism design. The Vickrey–Clarke–Groves (hereafter, VCG) mechanism is celebrated as a major achievement in the field because it performs well in both respects—agents have a dominant strategy to truthfully report their private information and the mechanism implements an efficient allocation of resources. How- ever, the VCG mechanism loses its desired incentive and efficiency properties without the quasilinearity restriction. Moreover, there are many well-studied cases where the quasilinearity restriction is violated: bidders may be risk averse, have wealth effects, face financing constraints, or be budget constrained.
    [Show full text]
  • Online Auction Markets
    Online Auction Markets by Song Yao Department of Business Administration Duke University Date: Approved: Carl Mela, Chair Han Hong Wagner Kamakura Andr´esMusalem Dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Department of Business Administration in the Graduate School of Duke University 2009 Abstract (Business Administration) Online Auction Markets by Song Yao Department of Business Administration Duke University Date: Approved: Carl Mela, Chair Han Hong Wagner Kamakura Andr´esMusalem An abstract of a dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Department of Business Administration in the Graduate School of Duke University 2009 Copyright c 2009 by Song Yao All rights reserved except the rights granted by the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial Licence Abstract Central to the explosive growth of the Internet has been the desire of dispersed buy- ers and sellers to interact readily and in a manner hitherto impossible. Underpinning these interactions, auction pricing mechanisms have enabled Internet transactions in novel ways. Despite this massive growth and new medium, empirical work in mar- keting and economics on auction use in Internet contexts remains relatively nascent. Accordingly, this dissertation investigates the role of online auctions; it is composed of three essays. The first essay, “Online Auction Demand,” investigates seller and buyer interac- tions via online auction websites, such as eBay. Such auction sites are among the earliest prominent transaction sites on the Internet (eBay started in 1995, the same year Internet Explorer was released) and helped pave the way for e-commerce.
    [Show full text]
  • Combinatorial Auction Glossary
    In Peter Cramton, Yoav Shoham, and Richard Steinberg (eds.), Combinatorial Auctions, MIT Press, 2006. Combinatorial Auction Glossary additive set function A set function f is additive if and only if f ðS W TÞ¼ f ðSÞþ f ðTÞ for all dis- joint S and T. activity A measure of the quantity of bidding in a round by a bidder in a simultaneous ascending auction. Activity includes both standing high bids and new bids in the round. In spectrum auc- tions, activity is measured in units of bandwidth times the number of people covered by the license (e.g., MHz-pop). In electricity auctions, the quantity is in energy units (e.g., MWh). activity rule A restriction on allowable bids intended to maintain the pace and encourage price discovery in simultaneous ascending auctions. This is done by preventing the ‘‘snake in the grass’’ strategy, in which a bidder maintains a low level of activity early in the auction and then greatly expands his demand late in the auction. The activity rule forces a bidder to maintain a minimum level of activity to preserve current eligibility. Typically, the activity requirement increases in stages. For example, the activity requirement might be 60 percent in stage 1, 80 percent in stage 2, and 100 percent in stage 3 (the final stage). With a 60 percent activity requirement, each bidder must be active on a quantity of items, equal to at least 60 percent of the bidder’s current eligibil- ity. If activity falls below the 60 percent level, then the bidder’s current eligibility is reduced to its current activity divided by 60 percent.
    [Show full text]
  • Bidder Behavior in Multiunit Auctions: Evidence from Swedish Treasury Auctions Author(S): Kjell G
    Bidder Behavior in Multiunit Auctions: Evidence from Swedish Treasury Auctions Author(s): Kjell G. Nyborg, Kristian Rydqvist, Suresh M. Sundaresan Source: The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 110, No. 2 (Apr., 2002), pp. 394-424 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3078454 Accessed: 03/08/2010 10:55 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ucpress. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Political Economy. http://www.jstor.org Bidder Behavior in MultiunitAuctions: Evidence from Swedish TreasuryAuctions KjellG.
    [Show full text]
  • Strategic Behavior and Underpricing in Uniform Price Auctions Evidence from Finnish Treasury Auctions
    Strategic Behavior and Underpricing in Uniform Price Auctions Evidence from Finnish Treasury Auctions Matti Keloharju Kjell G. Nyborg Kristian Rydqvist1 May 2004 1We are indebted to Markku Malkam¨aki for institutional information and making the data available to us and to Tron Foss for help on technical issues. We are grateful to Matti Ilmanen of Nordea, Raija Hyv¨arinen, Antero J¨arvilahti, Jukka J¨arvinen, Ari-Pekka L¨atti, and Juhani Rantala of the State Treasury of Finland, and to Jouni Parviainen and Samu Peura of Sampo Bank for providing us with institutional information. We also wish to thank Geir Bjønnes, Martin Dierker, David Goldreich, Alex Goriaev, Burton Hollifield, Ilan Kremer, Espen Moen, Suresh Paul, Avi Wohl, Jaime Zender and, especially, an anonymous referee, as well as semi- nar participants at the Bank of England, Binghamton University, Copenhagen Business School, Deutsche Bundesbank, European Central Bank, European Finance Association (Berlin 2002), Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, German Finance Association, G¨oteborg University, Helsinki and Swedish School of Economics joint seminar, Humboldt University in Berlin, Lausanne, Lon- don Business School, London School of Economics, Nordea, Norwegian School of Management (BI), Norwegian School of Economics (NHH), Stanford, State Treasury of Finland, University of Bergen, University of Frankfurt, Western Finance Association (Utah 2002), and the UK Debt Management Office for comments and suggestions. Finally, we want to thank Helsinki School of Economics Support Foundation and Foundation for Savings Banks for financial support. Kelo- harju: Helsinki School of Economics and CEPR, email: keloharj@hkkk.fi; Nyborg: UCLA and CEPR. Mailing address: UCLA Anderson School of Management, Box 951481, Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481.
    [Show full text]
  • Deferred-Acceptance Auctions for Multiple Levels of Service
    1 Deferred-Acceptance Auctions for Multiple Levels of Service VASILIS GKATZELIS, Drexel University EVANGELOS MARKAKIS, Athens University of Economics & Business TIM ROUGHGARDEN, Stanford University Deferred-acceptance (DA) auctions are mechanisms that are based on backward-greedy algorithms and possess a number of remarkable incentive properties, including implementation as an obviously-strategyproof ascending auction. All existing work on DA auctions considers only binary single-parameter problems, where each bidder either “wins” or “loses.” This paper generalizes the DA auction framework to non-binary settings, and applies this generalized framework to obtain approximately welfare-maximizing DA auctions for a number of basic mechanism design problems: multi-unit auctions, problems with polymatroid constraints or multiple knapsack constraints, and the problem of scheduling jobs to minimize their total weighted completion time. Our results require the design of novel backward-greedy algorithms with good approximation guarantees. CCS Concepts: • Theory of computation → Approximation algorithms analysis; Algorithmic game theory and mechanism design; Additional Key Words and Phrases: deferred-acceptance auctions; mechanism design; social welfare; approxi- mation algorithms; scheduling 1 INTRODUCTION The work of Milgrom and Segal [33] recently proposed the framework of Deferred-Acceptance (DA) Auctions, a family of single-parameter mechanisms with a number of remarkable incentive properties. In fact, the reverse auction part of the very recently concluded FCC Incentive Auction for reallocating spectrum was a DA auction [14]. DA auctions can be thought of as running an adaptive backward greedy algorithm for deciding the set of accepted bidders. The mechanism maintains a score for each active bidder (which can change from round to round), and rejects in each round the bidder with the lowest score, stopping when the still-active bidders constitute a feasible solution.
    [Show full text]
  • Price and Quantity Collars for Stabilizing Emission Allowance Prices Laboratory Experiments on the EU ETS Market Stability Rese
    Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 76 (2016) 32–50 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Environmental Economics and Management journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jeem Price and quantity collars for stabilizing emission allowance prices: Laboratory experiments on the EU ETS market stability reserve$ Charles A. Holt a, William M. Shobe b,n a Department of Economics, University of Virginia, P.O. Box 400182, Charlottesville, VA 22904, USA b Center for Economic & Policy Studies, University of Virginia, Box 400206, Charlottesville, VA 22904, USA article info abstract Article history: We report on laboratory experiments, with financially motivated participants, comparing Received 26 May 2015 alternative proposals for managing the time path of emission allowance prices in the face of Available online 10 December 2015 random firm-specific and market-level structural shocks. Market outcome measures such as JEL classification: social surplus and price variability are improved by the use of a price collar (auction reserve C92 price and soft price cap). Comparable performance enhancements are not observed with Q5 the implementation of a quantity collar that adjusts auction quantities in response to pri- Q54 vately held inventories of unused allowances. In some specifications, the quantity collar D47 performed worse than no stabilization policy at all. The experiment implemented a specific H2 set of structural elements, and extrapolation to other settings should be done with caution. Nevertheless, an examination of the observed behavioral patterns and deviations from Keywords: optimal behavior suggests that a price collar has an important (although perhaps not Emission markets Price collars exclusive) role to play in constructing an effective market stability policy.
    [Show full text]
  • CO2 Emission Allowance Allocation Mechanisms, Allocative Efficiency
    Eur J Law Econ (2007) 24:29–70 DOI 10.1007/s10657-007-9020-z CO2 emission allowance allocation mechanisms, allocative efficiency and the environment: a static and dynamic perspective Stefan Weishaar Published online: 1 August 2007 Ó Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2007 Abstract The object of this paper is to place allocation mechanisms into a framework of Emission Trading Systems and thereby to establish a typology. It analyses how various assignment mechanisms deal with issues such as price determination, allocative efficiency and environmental considerations in a static and dynamic economy model. It analyses how allocation mechanisms are to be ranked and whether they serve the attainment of the general equilibrium. First the paper examines how market-based allocation mechanisms (auctions) perform in light of the above issues. Second the paper distinguishes between the two types of administrative allocation mechanisms: (1) financial administrative allo- cation mechanisms, combining payment schemes with bureaucratic expertise, and (2) free administrative allocation mechanisms, based inter alia on industrial policy considerations and on passed emission records (grandfathering). In par- ticular, the value added of relative performance standards, which are for example included in the ‘‘Performance Standard Rate’’ (PSR) Emission Trading System, are examined as a means to provide allowances. The overall finding is that in a closed static economy and in the presence of an efficient trading market, dif- ferent allocation methods produce equally efficient outcomes in allocative and environmental respects. With regard to an open dynamic economy, the impact of initial allocation mechanisms resembles those of a static closed economy. In such an economy the upper limit to the internalisation of negative externalities is given by operator’s costs of environmentally harmful relocation and hence the cost burden placed upon operators is crucial.
    [Show full text]