A Tale of Three Supply Shocks, National Inflation and the Region's

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Tale of Three Supply Shocks, National Inflation and the Region's federal reserve I SSUE 2MARCH/A PRIL 1997 thwe u s o tt ss e c y onom bank of dallas A TALE OF THREE SUPPLY SHOCKS, NATIONAL INFLATION AND THE REGION’S ECONOMY N RECENT YEARS,s several supply shocks —unusual shifts in production costs —have kept U.S. inflation low by putting downward pressure on prices for certain commodities, espe- cially computers, health care and, until 1996, energy.1 Because the sectors producing these goods and services are important to the Eleventh Federal Reserve District, these shocks Ihave had an impact on its economy. After examining these shocks’ effect on U.S. inflation, this article analyzes their impact on the Dis- trict and assesses the outlook for computers, energy and health care. Supply Shocks and U.S. Inflation INSIDE U.S. inflation has remained low through early 1997, even though, Does Electronic Money since 1995, the unemployment rate has been below 5.75 to 6 percent, Mean the Death of Cash? a range below which inflation had previously tended to rise. There are three plausible explanations for this change in behavior. The Mexican Economy One is that job uncertainty has held down wages.2 Another is that the Snaps Back competitive pricings environment of the 1990s has enabled the econ- Chart 1 As shown in the upper panel of Overall and Core Inflation Chart 2, medical inflation resumed Supply Shocks and the Region Diverge in 1996 … falling in late 1995 after leveling off Year-over-year percent change over mid-1994 to early 1995. Indeed, Each of these supply shocks has 4 medical inflation has declined more affected Eleventh District employment 3.6 than overall inflation has in the mid- trends. With respect to computers, ad- Overall 3.2 1990s, reflecting the shift toward man- vances in technology have spawned 2.8 aged health care and the adoption of an increased demand for information 2.4 Core other cost-saving practices. equipment and, until late 1995, a con- 2 In the mid-1990s, the pace at which comitant rise in production and capac- 1993 1994 1995 1996 computer prices have fallen (deflation) ity. Indeed, as semiconductor orders … As Energy Price Swings has swung substantially. After slowing continued to exceed shipments, re- Drive Overall U.S. Inflation sharply in 1994, deflation in the “elec- flected in a domestic book-to-bill ratio 7 Year-over-year percent change tronic computers” category of the pro- above 1, high-tech manufacturing job 10 ducer price index accelerated sharply growth was very strong in District states 8 (middle panel, Chart 2 ), partly reflect- (Texas, Louisiana and New Mexico), as 6 8 4 ing technological advances in computer shown in the upper panel of Chart 4. 2 chips as well as excess plant capacity However, as demand growth for 0 and inventory buildup prompted by computer equipment unexpectedly –2 –4 overly optimistic expectations. These slowed in 1996, computer chip plant 1993 1994 1995 1996 wholesale price movements influence SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics. retail consumer prices in the CPI’s home furnishings category, which comprises Chart 2 furniture, computers, other electronic After Pausing in 1994, omy to operate at higher capacity levels goods and home appliances. Comparing Health Care Disinflation without a pickup in inflation, or —put the middle and lower panels of Chart 2, Resumes … another way—has slowed the pace at one can see how wholesale computer Year-over-year percent change which excess demand pressures induce price deflation has influenced consumer 7.5 rises in inflation, as some of my home furnishings’ inflation in the mid- 6.5 research under way suggests.3 A third 1990s. Indeed, on a year-over-year basis, 5.5 explanation—the focus of this article— prices for home furnishings actually had 4.5 is that inflation has been low because dipped 0.1 percent as of December 3.5 several supply shocks have put down- 1996, while producer prices for elec- 2.5 ward pressure on prices for three key tronic computers had fallen 21 percent. 1993 1994 1995 1996 commodities: computers, energy and Excluding its home furnishings com- Computer Price Deflation health care. ponent, core inflation barely deceler- Accelerates … Between 1993 and early 1994, infla- ated in 1996. Year-over-year percent change tion fell, according to both the con- Thus, the pickup in overall infla- 0 sumer price index (CPI) and the core tion and the decline in core inflation –5 CPI, which excludes food and energy during 1996 largely reflect the two ex- –10 prices (top panel, Chart 1 ). The overall tremes of an acceleration of energy –15 CPI has drifted upward since early 1994, price inflation (overall) and an accel- –20 picking up from mid-1994 to mid-1995, eration of computer price deflation –25 slowing in late 1995 and then picking (core). This pattern suggests that iso- 1993 1994 1995 1996 up again in 1996. In contrast, core CPI lated price developments may be dis- NOTE: Prices based on the producer price index for the inflation was stable over 1994 –95 be- torting the inflation picture. One way to computer electronic category. fore slowing in 1996. A comparison of filter out the disproportionate influence … Driving Down the upper and lower panels of Chart 1 of unusual price factors is to measure Home Furnishings Prices suggests that most of the wiggles in the inflation by excluding the highest 10 Year-over-year percent change overall CPI reflect swings in consumer percent inflation components (by ex- 3 energy prices. On the surface, the slow- penditure weights) and the lowest 10 2 ing of core inflation last year seems percent inflation components.5 This puzzling in the face of rising energy “trimmed mean” CPI measure (Chart 3) 1 prices, which had tended to bolster shows an upward drift in inflation since 0 4 core inflation in the past. However, in- late 1995 — consistent with the view –1 novations in both health care delivery that the economy has been operating at 1993 1994 1995 1996 and computers have played an impor- levels of the unemployment rate pre- SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics. tant role in holding down core inflation. viously associated with rising inflation.6 Page 2 Southwest Economy March/April 1997 Chart 3 and, within this sector, is less focused wane over 1997–98 if some analysts are Filtering Reveals a Modest on computer chip production. correct in predicting that microproces- Pickup in U.S. Inflation In contrast to computer prices, en- sors are nearing the end of the current Year-over-year percent change ergy prices rose in 1996, reflecting a wave of innovation, as suggested by 3 sudden weather-related rise in demand the slower pace of microprocessor price Trimmed mean coupled with low inventories. This deflation since early 1996. Perhaps for 2.8 consumer price index price rise spurred the oil industry to similar reasons, prices for integrated expand exploration and hiring.11 In circuits—another key computer com- 2.6 addition, new exploration technology ponent—have declined at a slower pace made it more profitable to search for since spring 1996. 2.4 oil under waters where an ocean- Nevertheless, computer price defla- 2.2 bottom salt layer had previously tion actually picked up to more typical obscured reserves— especially true of levels last year, as reflected in the GDP 2 1993 1994 1995 1996 the Gulf of Mexico. Both high energy chain-weight price index for computers SOURCES: Bureau of Labor Statistics; author’s calculations. prices and a technological innovation and peripheral equipment investment favoring oil exploration in local waters (lower panel, Chart 5 ). This index ex- have boosted drilling in the gulf and cludes typewriters and noncomputer energy employment in the Eleventh equipment, whose share of GDP’s capacity outstripped demand. The tem- District’s states (middle panel, Chart 4 ). broader “information-processing and porary imbalance between production Increased worldwide demand for drill- related equipment” component of busi- and orders was reflected in a decline in ing equipment has also bolstered manu- the domestic book-to-bill ratio to levels facturing employment in areas such as below 1, generally indicating that do- Houston. Chart 4 mestic shipments exceeded orders.9 Finally, the restructuring of health District High-Tech Overproduction and overexpansion of care has slowed job growth in that sec- Manufacturing Jobs Reflect Semiconductor capacity led to a buildup of inventories tor, despite the continued increasing Industry’s Fortunes and an unexpected drop in memory demand for health care associated with chip prices, which in turn slowed job a general aging of the population. Year-over-year percent change Book-to-bill ratio growth in the overall high-tech manu- Health care restructuring likely con- 8 1.2 facturing industry in District states. tributed to a recent slowing of the pace 6 1.1 This deceleration in high-tech job at which the share of private health care 4 1 High-tech Book-to-bill growth helps explain why nonfarm job employees in the District’s three states 2 job growth ratio .9 growth in Texas slowed toward the U.S. has risen (lower panel, Chart 4 ).12 0 .8 –2 .7 average in 1996, after several years in 1993 1994 1995 1996 which it substantially exceeded the Oil Drilling and District national average. As demonstrated by The Outlook for Computers, Energy Jobs Recover two Dallas Fed researchers, the high- tech sector—which includes high-tech Energy and Health Care Year-over-year percent change Number 2 320 manufacturing along with communica- District energy job growth 300 tions and computer-related services— Computers. Some analysts attribute 0 280 was a major contributor to Texas job last year’s speedup in computer price –2 growth over 1988 –94.10 Roughly half of deflation to two factors that reduced Texas 260 –4 rig count the broadly defined high-tech jobs in prices for semiconductors (memory and 240 –6 220 Texas are in the Dallas–Fort Worth metro- microprocessor chips), which are im- 1993 1994 1995 1996 plex, where there is a high concentra- portant computer components.
Recommended publications
  • Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions by Irving Fisher
    THE DEBT-DEFLATION THEORY OF GREAT DEPRESSIONS BY IRVING FISHER INTRODUCTORY IN Booms and Depressions, I have developed, theoretically and sta- tistically, what may be called a debt-deflation theory of great depres- sions. In the preface, I stated that the results "seem largely new," I spoke thus cautiously because of my unfamiliarity with the vast literature on the subject. Since the book was published its special con- clusions have been widely accepted and, so far as I know, no one has yet found them anticipated by previous writers, though several, in- cluding myself, have zealously sought to find such anticipations. Two of the best-read authorities in this field assure me that those conclu- sions are, in the words of one of them, "both new and important." Partly to specify what some of these special conclusions are which are believed to be new and partly to fit them into the conclusions of other students in this field, I am offering this paper as embodying, in brief, my present "creed" on the whole subject of so-called "cycle theory." My "creed" consists of 49 "articles" some of which are old and some new. I say "creed" because, for brevity, it is purposely ex- pressed dogmatically and without proof. But it is not a creed in the sense that my faith in it does not rest on evidence and that I am not ready to modify it on presentation of new evidence. On the contrary, it is quite tentative. It may serve as a challenge to others and as raw material to help them work out a better product.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation and the Business Cycle
    Inflation and the business cycle Michael McMahon Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 1 / 68 To Cover • Discuss the costs of inflation; • Investigate the relationship between money and inflation; • Introduce the Romer framework; • Discuss hyperinflations. • Shocks and the business cycle; • Monetary policy responses to business cycles. • Explain what the monetary transmission mechanism is; • Examine the link between inflation and GDP. Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 2 / 68 The Next Few Lectures Term structure, asset prices Exchange and capital rate market conditions Import prices Bank rate Net external demand CPI inflation Bank lending Monetary rates and credit Policy Asset purchase/ Corporate DGI conditions Framework sales demand loans Macro prudential Household policy demand deposits Inflation expectations Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 3 / 68 Inflation Definition Inflation is a sustained general rise in the price level in the economy. In reality we measure it using concepts such as: • Consumer Price Indices (CPI); • Producer Price Indices (PPI); • Deflators (GDP deflator, Consumption Expenditure Deflator) Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 4 / 68 Inflation: The Costs If all prices are rising at same rate, including wages and asset prices, what is the problem? • Information: Makes it harder to detect relative price changes and so hinders efficient operation of market; • Uncertainty: High inflation countries have very volatile inflation; • High inflation undermines role of money and encourages barter; • Growth - if inflation increases by 10%, reduce long term growth by 0.2% but only for countries with inflation higher than 15% (Barro); • Shoe leather costs/menu costs; • Interaction with tax system; • Because of fixed nominal contracts arbitrarily redistributes wealth; • Nominal contracts break down and long-term contracts avoided.
    [Show full text]
  • Dangers of Deflation Douglas H
    ERD POLICY BRIEF SERIES Economics and Research Department Number 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks Pilipinas F. Quising Asian Development Bank http://www.adb.org Asian Development Bank P.O. Box 789 0980 Manila Philippines 2002 by Asian Development Bank December 2002 ISSN 1655-5260 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ERD Policy Brief Series is based on papers or notes prepared by ADB staff and their resource persons. The series is designed to provide concise nontechnical accounts of policy issues of topical interest to ADB management, Board of Directors, and staff. Though prepared primarily for internal readership within the ADB, the series may be accessed by interested external readers. Feedback is welcome via e-mail ([email protected]). ERD POLICY BRIEF NO. 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks and Pilipinas F. Quising December 2002 ecently, there has been growing concern about deflation in some Rcountries and the possibility of deflation at the global level. Aggregate demand, output, and employment could stagnate or decline, particularly where debt levels are already high. Standard economic policy stimuli could become less effective, while few policymakers have experience in preventing or halting deflation with alternative means. Causes and Consequences of Deflation Deflation refers to a fall in prices, leading to a negative change in the price index over a sustained period. The fall in prices can result from improvements in productivity, advances in technology, changes in the policy environment (e.g., deregulation), a drop in prices of major inputs (e.g., oil), excess capacity, or weak demand.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: a Business Perspective
    Deflation: a business perspective Prepared by the Corporate Economists Advisory Group Introduction Early in 2003, ICC's Corporate Economists Advisory Group discussed the risk of deflation in some of the world's major economies, and possible consequences for business. The fear was that historically low levels of inflation and faltering economic growth could lead to deflation - a persistent decline in the general level of prices - which in turn could trigger economic depression, with widespread company and bank failures, a collapse in world trade, mass unemployment and years of shrinking economic activity. While the risk of deflation is now remote in most countries - given the increasingly unambiguous signs of global economic recovery - its potential costs are very high and would directly affect companies. This issues paper was developed to help companies better understand the phenomenon of deflation, and to give them practical guidance on possible measures to take if and when the threat of deflation turns into reality on a future occasion. What is deflation? Deflation is defined as a sustained fall in an aggregate measure of prices (such as the consumer price index). By this definition, changes in prices in one economic sector or falling prices over short periods (e.g., one or two quarters) do not qualify as deflation. Dec lining prices can be driven by an increase in supply due to technological innovation and rapid productivity gains. These supply-induced shocks are usually not problematic and can even be accompanied by robust growth, as experienced by China. A fall in prices led by a drop in demand - due to a severe economic cycle, tight economic policies or a demand-side shock - or by persistent excess capacity can be much more harmful, and is more likely to lead to persistent deflation.
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. Working Paper The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. (2007) : The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/4105 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu IZA DP No. 2900 The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties Marika Karanassou Hector Sala Dennis J.
    [Show full text]
  • How Real Is the Threat of Deflation to the Banking Industry?
    An Update on Emerging Issues in Banking How Real is the Threat of Deflation to the Banking Industry? February 27, 2003 Overview The recession that began in March 2001 has had a generally benign effect on the banking industry, which remains highly profitable and well capitalized. The current financial strength of the industry is an important buffer against the effects of economic shocks. Nevertheless, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) routinely considers a number of economic scenarios that could develop over the next several quarters to evaluate factors that could result in the erosion in the financial health of individual banks or the industry. One such scenario that could present a major challenge to the banking industry involves deflation. This paper outlines the current debate over deflation, focusing on its potential effect on the banking industry. What is Deflation and How Does It Affect the Economy? Deflation refers to a decline in the general price level, usually caused by a sharp decline in money or credit supply or a severe contraction in the economy.1 Although sometimes used interchangeably, deflation differs from disinflation -- a falling rate of inflation. Although there have been sector-specific downward price adjustments, the U.S. economy has not experienced an outright decline in the aggregate price level since World War II, except for a brief and mild deflation in 1949.2 However, the inflation rate in the U.S. has fallen steadily since the early 1980s. In order to fully understand the effect of deflation on economic output, it is important to differentiate the concept of a "real" value from a "nominal" value.
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • Harvard Kennedy School Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business and Government Study Group, February 28, 2019
    1 Harvard Kennedy School Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business and Government Study Group, February 28, 2019 MMT (Modern Monetary Theory): What Is It and Can It Help? Paul Sheard, M-RCBG Senior Fellow, Harvard Kennedy School ([email protected]) What Is It? MMT is an approach to understanding/analyzing monetary and fiscal operations, and their economic and economic policy implications, that focuses on the fact that governments create money when they run a budget deficit (so they do not have to borrow in order to spend and cannot “run out” of money) and that pays close attention to the balance sheet mechanics of monetary and fiscal operations. Can It Help? Yes, because at a time in which the developed world appears to be “running out” of conventional monetary and fiscal policy ammunition, MMT casts a more optimistic and less constraining light on the ability of governments to stimulate aggregate demand and prevent deflation. Adopting an MMT lens, rather than being blinkered by the current conceptual and institutional orthodoxy, provides a much easier segue into the coordination of monetary and fiscal policy responses that will be needed in the next major economic downturn. Some context and background: - The current macroeconomic policy framework is based on a clear distinction between monetary and fiscal policy and assigns the primary role for “macroeconomic stabilization” (full employment and price stability and latterly usually financial stability) to an independent, technocratic central bank, which uses a “flexible inflation-targeting” framework. - Ten years after the Global Financial Crisis and Great Recession, major central banks are far from having been able to re-stock their monetary policy “ammunition,” government debt levels are high, and there is much hand- wringing about central banks being “the only game in town” and concern about how, from this starting point, central banks and fiscal authorities will be able to cope with another serious downturn.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation Or Disinflation?
    Focus No. 3 – 22 january 2009 Defl ation or disinfl ation? The rapid fall in infl ation in a context of a fi nancial crisis and a very sharp economic slowdown raises the spectre of defl ation, a situation where the decline in prices is associated with a prolonged and severe economic crisis. However, not all declines in prices are synonymous with defl ation; the distinction must be made between a defl ationary situation and the much more positive disinfl ationary situation. The aim of this Focus is to clarify these two concepts and to show that current dynamics in France and the euro area are characteristic of a disinfl ationary trend, resulting in particular from a temporary correction of certain prices, particularly energy prices. J Defl ation: defi nition and mechanisms Defi nitions Inflation means a sustained increase in the general price level in an economy. It is not an instantaneous shock, limited 1 to the prices of certain goods. It is a persistent and general process. Inflation is fuelled by expectations: when workers and companies expect prices to rise, they adjust upwards their prices and wages accordingly. Conversely, deflation means a sustained decrease in the general price level in an economy. If only certain prices fall, this is not deflation. For example, the price of laptop computers or hi-fi equipment may decrease due to technological progress, but this is not deflation. Disinflation means a reduction in the rate of inflation or a temporary decrease in the general price level in an economy. For example, if inflation falls from 3% per year to 1% per year, this is disinflation.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory
    2021 A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory Steven Globerman fraserinstitute.org Contents Executive Summary / i 1. Introducing Modern Monetary Theory / 1 2. Implementing MMT / 4 3. Has Canada Adopted MMT? / 10 4. Proposed Economic and Social Justifications for MMT / 17 5. MMT and Inflation / 23 Concluding Comments / 27 References / 29 About the author / 33 Acknowledgments / 33 Publishing information / 34 Supporting the Fraser Institute / 35 Purpose, funding, and independence / 35 About the Fraser Institute / 36 Editorial Advisory Board / 37 fraserinstitute.org fraserinstitute.org Executive Summary Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is a policy model for funding govern- ment spending. While MMT is not new, it has recently received wide- spread attention, particularly as government spending has increased dramatically in response to the ongoing COVID-19 crisis and concerns grow about how to pay for this increased spending. The essential message of MMT is that there is no financial constraint on government spending as long as a country is a sovereign issuer of cur- rency and does not tie the value of its currency to another currency. Both Canada and the US are examples of countries that are sovereign issuers of currency. In principle, being a sovereign issuer of currency endows the government with the ability to borrow money from the country’s cen- tral bank. The central bank can effectively credit the government’s bank account at the central bank for an unlimited amount of money without either charging the government interest or, indeed, demanding repayment of the government bonds the central bank has acquired. In 2020, the cen- tral banks in both Canada and the US bought a disproportionately large share of government bonds compared to previous years, which has led some observers to argue that the governments of Canada and the United States are practicing MMT.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: a Marxist Critique
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 7 Issue 1 Article 1 2019 Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Michael Roberts [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Roberts, Michael (2019) "Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 7 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.7.1.008316 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol7/iss1/1 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Abstract Compiled from a series of blog posts which can be found at "The Next Recession." Modern monetary theory (MMT) has become flavor of the time among many leftist economic views in recent years. MMT has some traction in the left as it appears to offer theoretical support for policies of fiscal spending funded yb central bank money and running up budget deficits and public debt without earf of crises – and thus backing policies of government spending on infrastructure projects, job creation and industry in direct contrast to neoliberal mainstream policies of austerity and minimal government intervention. Here I will offer my view on the worth of MMT and its policy implications for the labor movement. First, I’ll try and give broad outline to bring out the similarities and difference with Marx’s monetary theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: Who Let the Air Out? February 2011
    ® Economic Information Newsletter Liber8 Brought to You by the Research Library of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Deflation: Who Let the Air Out? February 2011 “Inflation that is ‘too low’ can be problematic, as the Japanese experience has shown.” —James Bullard, President and CEO, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, August 19, 2010 The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the Federal Reserve’s policy-setting committee, took further steps in early November 2010 to attempt to alleviate economic strains from a high unemployment rate and falling inflation rates. 1 While it is clear that a high unemployment rate and rapidly increasing prices (inflation) are undesirable for economies, it is less obvious why decreasing prices (deflation) can also restrain economic growth. At its November meeting, the FOMC discussed the potential of further slow growth in prices (disinflation). That month, the price level, as measured by the Consumer Price Index (CPI) , was 1 percent higher than it was the previous November. 2 However, less than a year earlier, in December 2009, the year-to-year change was 2.8 percent. While both rates are positive and indicate inflation, the downward trend indicates disinflation. Economists worry about disinfla - tion when the inflation rate is extremely low because it can potentially lead to deflation, a phenomenon that may be difficult for central bankers to combat and can have various negative implications on an economy. While the idea of lower prices may sound attractive, deflation is a real concern for several reasons. Deflation dis - cour ages spending and investment because consumers, expecting prices to fall further, delay purchases, preferring instead to save and wait for even lower prices.
    [Show full text]